US Financial System
US Financial System
US Financial System
htm
JFEP 2,3
196
Journal of Financial Economic Policy Vol. 2 No. 3, 2010 pp. 196-213 q Emerald Group Publishing Limited 1757-6385 DOI 10.1108/17576381011085421
1. Introduction Inuential policymakers emphasize that the nancial crisis was largely precipitated by a series of unforeseeable events that conspired to produce a bubble in the housing market. In particular, Bernanke (2009a, b), Greenspan (2010), Henry Paulson, Christina Romer (2009) and Rubin (2010) stress that large capital inows to the USA lowered interest rates, fueled a boom in mortgage lending, a reduction in loan standards, and nancial innovations that produced an unsustainable explosion of credit. This view characterizes the collapse of the nancial system as reecting accidents, such as the bursting of the housing bubble, and suicide, such the herding behavior of nanciers rushing to create and market increasingly complex and toxic nancial products[1]. Greenspan (2010), for example, depicts the nancial crisis as a once in a
hundred years ood and a classic euphoric bubble. From this perspective, policymakers responded to a crisis that happened to them. This view, however, is arguably incomplete and could impede the development of benecial nancial reforms. While large international capital ows to the USA fueled speculative investments in real estate and while nancial shenanigans helped destabilize the global nancial system, a different view holds that policies caused this crisis. According to this view, the Federal Reserve, Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), Congress, and other ofcial agencies implemented policies that spurred excessive risk taking and the eventual failure of the nancial system. Thus, when policymakers highlight the global savings glut and irrational exuberance, this deects attention from the potential policy determinants of the crisis. In this autopsy, I assess whether key nancial policies during the period from 1996 through 2006 contributed to the nancial systems demise. I analyze the decade before the cascade of nancial institution insolvencies and bailouts and hence before policymakers shifted into an emergency response mode. Thus, I examine a comparatively calm period during which the regulatory authorities could assess the evolving impact of their policies and make adjustments. Specically, I study ve important policies: (1) SEC policies toward credit rating agencies. (2) Federal Reserve policies that allowed banks to reduce their capital cushions through the use of credit default swaps (CDSs). (3) SEC and Federal Reserve policies concerning over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives. (4) SEC policies toward the consolidated supervision of major investment banks. (5) Government policies toward two housing-nance entities, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. From this examination, I draw tentative conclusions about the determinants of the crisis. The evidence indicates that senior policymakers repeatedly designed, implemented, and maintained policies that destabilized the global nancial system in the decade before the crisis. The policies incentivized nancial institutions to engage in activities that generated enormous short-run prots but dramatically increased long-run fragility. Moreover, the evidence suggests that the regulatory agencies were aware of the consequences of their policies and yet chose not to modify those policies. On the whole, these policy decisions reect neither a lack of information nor an absence of regulatory power. They represent the selection and most importantly the maintenance of policies that increased nancial fragility. The crisis did not just happen to policymakers. The evidence does not reject the impact of international capital ows, asset bubbles, herd behavior by nanciers, or excessively greedy nanciers on nancial instability, which have been carefully analyzed by, for example, Acharya and Richardson (2009), Jagannathan et al. (2009), Kamin and DeMarco (2010), Obstfeld and Rogoff (2009) and Rose and Spiegel (2010). Rather, this paper documents that nancial regulations and policies created incentives for excessive risk and the nancial regulatory apparatus maintained these policies even as information became available about the growing fragility of the nancial system. Since policymakers did not intend to destroy the nancial system, I refer to this policy view as negligent homicide, not as murder.
JFEP 2,3
198
Although I do not make policy recommendations here, the analyses are relevant for those designing reforms (Barth et al., 2010; Levine, 2010). Since technical glitches, regulatory gaps, and insufcient regulatory power played only a partial role in fostering the crisis, reforms that rectify these failures represent only a partial and thus incomplete step in establishing a stable nancial system that promotes growth and expands economic opportunities. There was also a systemic failure of the nancial regulatory system the system associated with evaluating, reforming, and implementing nancial policies: key authorities knew that policies were distorting the allocation of capital and did not reform those policies. It is worth highlighting three limitations with this paper. First, I draw on a wide array of insightful examinations of the crisis from newspaper articles, books, regulatory agency documents, and research papers. I do not provide new examples or data. Second, related, limitation is that I do not conduct a comprehensive examination of all policies related to the crisis. In particular, there was a massive failure of corporate governance, not just regulatory governance. The board of directors of many nancial institutions did not effectively induce management to act in the best interests of shareholders and others with nancial claims on the rms as shown by Bebchuk (2010a, b). Rather, in reexamining selective pieces of evidence, I show that an enduring breakdown of the nancial regulatory system was a primary factor in the nancial crisis. Third, nancial regulators and policymakers do not share a uniform view of the nancial crisis. Ofcials acknowledge that regulatory mistakes were made. While they tend to focus on an absence of regulatory power to cope with failing institutions and regulatory gaps in which shadow nancial institutions operated with little oversight, there are also cases in which the major agencies acknowledge decient supervisory and regulatory practices (Geithner, 2009). For example, the Federal Reserve noted that it failed to monitor Citibank adequately as far back as 2005 and did not correct this shortcoming even after Citibanks nancial condition deteriorated in 2008 (Chan and Dash, 2010). As other examples, the Inspector General of the Federal Reserve and Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) provided detailed evidence that regulators failed to implement their own rules to rein in the excessively risky behavior of banks (FDIC Ofce of Inspector General, 2009-2010; Ofce of Inspector General of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 2010; Chan, 2010b). Thus, my characterization of the view of policymakers could be criticized as an unhelpful caricature. However, my goal is to provide a simple, but relevant, summary of the public view of the most senior policymakers as a mechanism for framing and motivating my assessment of what went wrong. In the remainder of the paper, I discuss how the nancial crisis was shaped by policies toward credit rating agencies (Section 2), CDSs and commercial banks (Sections 3 and 4), investment banks (Section 5), and Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac (Section 6). Section 7 concludes. 2. The credit rating agencies
These errors make us look either incompetent at credit analysis or like we sold our soul to the devil for revenue, or a little bit of both. A Moodys managing director responding anonymously to an internal management survey, September 2007, as quoted in Morgenson (2008).
2.1 Background Credit rating agencies were indispensable to the crisis. To appreciate their role, consider the following sequence of transactions underlying the vast misallocation of global credit. Mortgage companies routinely provided loans to borrowers with little ability to repay those debts because: . they earned fees for each loan; and . they could sell those loans to investment banks and other nancial institutions. Investment banks and other nancial institutions gobbled-up those mortgages because: . they earned fees for packaging the mortgages into new securities; and . they could sell those new mortgage-backed securities (MBSs) to other nancial institutions, including banks, insurance companies, and pension funds around the world. These other nancial institutions bought the MBSs because credit rating agencies said they were safe. By fueling the demand for MBS and related securities, credit rating agencies encouraged a broad array of nancial institutions to make the poor investments that ultimately toppled the global nancial system. Thus, an informed postmortem of the nancial system requires a dissection of why nancial institutions relied unquestionably on the assessments of credit rating agencies. How did they become so pivotal? Until the 1970s, credit rating agencies were comparatively insignicant, moribund institutions that sold their assessments of credit risk to subscribers. Given the poor predictive performance of these agencies, the demand for their services was limited for much of the twentieth century (Partnoy, 1999). Indeed, academic researchers found that credit rating agencies produce little additional information about the rms they rate; rather, their ratings lag stock price movements by about 18 months (Pinches and Singleton, 1978). Now, it is virtually impossible for a rm to issue a security without rst purchasing a rating. 2.2 The creation of NRSROs In 1975, the SEC created the Nationally Recognized Statistical Rating Organization (NRSRO) designation, which it granted to the largest credit rating agencies. The SEC then relied on the NRSROs credit risk assessment in establishing capital requirements on SEC-regulated nancial institutions. The creation of and reliance on NRSROs by the SEC triggered a cascade of regulatory decisions that increased the demand for their credit ratings. Bank regulators, insurance regulators, federal, state, and local agencies, foundations, endowments, and numerous entities around the world all started using NRSRO ratings to establish capital adequacy and portfolio guidelines. Furthermore, given the reliance by prominent regulatory agencies on NRSRO ratings, private endowments, foundations, and mutual funds also used their ratings in setting asset allocation guidelines for their investment managers. NRSRO ratings shaped the investment opportunities, capital requirements, and hence the prots of insurance companies, mutual funds, pension funds, and a dizzying array of other nancial institutions. Unsurprisingly, NRSROs shifted from selling their credit ratings to subscribers to selling their ratings to the issuers of securities. Since regulators, ofcial agencies,
JFEP 2,3
and private institutions around the world relied on NRSRO ratings, virtually every issuer of securities was compelled to purchase an NRSRO rating if it wanted a large market for its securities. Indeed, Partnoy (1999) argues that NRSROs essentially sell licenses to issue securities; they do not primarily provide assessments of credit risk[2]. 2.3 Conicts of interest in credit rating agencies There are clear conicts of interest associated with credit rating agencies selling their ratings to the issuers of securities. Issuers have an interest in paying rating agencies more for higher ratings since those ratings inuence the demand for and hence the pricing of securities. And, rating agencies can promote repeat business by providing high ratings. Interestingly, the vice president of Moodys explained in 1957 that:
[ W ]e obviously cannot ask payment for rating a bond. To do so would attach a price to the process, and we could not escape the charge, which would undoubtedly come, that our ratings are for sale (Morgenson, 2008).
200
Nevertheless, credit rating agencies convinced regulators that reputational capital reduces the pernicious incentive to sell better ratings. If a rating agency does not provide sound, objective assessments of a security, the agency will experience damage to its reputation with consequential ramications on its long-run prots. Purchasers of securities will reduce their reliance on this agency, which will reduce demand for all securities rated by the agency. As a result, issuers will reduce their demand for the services provide by that agency, reducing the agencys future prots. From this perspective, reputational capital is vital for the long-run protability of credit rating agencies and will therefore contain any short-run conicts of interest associated with selling a superior rating on any particular security. Reputational capital will reduce conicts of interest, however, only under particular conditions. First, the demand for securities must respond to poor rating agency performance, so that decision makers at rating agencies are punished for issuing bloated ratings on even a few securities. Second, decision makers at rating agencies must have a sufciently long-run prot horizon, so that the long-run costs to the decision maker from harming the agencies reputation outweigh the short-run benets from selling a bloated rating. These conditions do not hold, however. First, regulations weaken the degree to which a decline in the reputation of a credit rating agency reduces demand for its services. Specically, regulations induce the vast majority of the buyers of securities to use NRSRO rating in selecting assets. These regulations hold regardless of NRSRO performance, which moderates the degree to which poor ratings performance reduces the demand for NRSRO services. Such regulations mitigate the positive relation between rating agency performance and protability. Second, nancial innovation in the form of securitization dramatically changed the incentives of decision makers at credit rating agencies, inducing them to sell bloated ratings at the expense of a loss in the long-run reputation of the agency. 2.4 Securitization and the intensication of conicts of interest The explosive growth of securitized and structured nancial products from the late 1990s onward materially intensied the conicts of interest problem. Securitization and structuring involved the packaging and rating of trillions of dollars worth of new nancial instruments. Huge fees associated with processing these securities owed to
banks and NRSROs. Impediments to this securitization and structuring process, such as the issuance of low credit rating on the securities, would gum-up the system, reducing rating agency prots. In fact, the NRSROs started selling ancillary consulting services to facilitate the processing of securitized instruments, increasing NRSRO incentives to exaggerate ratings on structured products. Besides purchasing ratings from the NRSROs, the banks associated with creating structured nancial products would rst pay the rating agencies for guidance on how to package the securities to get high ratings and then pay the rating agencies to rate the resultant products. Other evidence also indicates that rating agencies adjusted their behavior to capture the prots made available by securitization and the design of new structured nancial products. Lowensteins (2008) excellent description of the rating of a MBS by Moodys demonstrates the speed with which complex products had to be rated, the poor assumptions on which these ratings were based, and the prots generated by rating structured products. Other information indicates that if the rating agencies issued a lower rating than countrywide (a major purchaser of NRSRO ratings) wanted, a few phone calls would get this changed (Morgenson, 2008). Indeed, internal e-mails indicate that the rating agencies lowered their rating standards to expand the business and boost revenues. A Standard and Poors employee noted in 2004:
We are meeting with your group this week to discuss adjusting criteria for rating C.D.O.s of real estate assets this week because of the ongoing threat of losing deals. Lose the C.D.O. and lose the base business a self reinforcing loop (Chan, 2010a).
A collection of documents released by the US Senate suggests that NRSROs consciously adjusted their ratings to maintain clients and attract new ones. The short-run prots from these activities were mind bogglingly large and made the future losses from the inevitable loss of reputational capital irrelevant. For example, the operating margin at Moodys between 2000 and 2007 averaged 53 percent. This compares to operating margins of 36 and 30 percent at Microsoft and Google, or 17 percent at Exxon. It is true that the performance of the rating agencies played a central role in the crisis. Thus, rating agencies faced little market discipline, had no signicant regulatory oversight, were protected from competition by regulators and legislators, and enjoyed a burgeoning market for their services. Indeed, the 2006 Credit Rating Agency Reform Act specically prohibited the SEC from regulating an NRSROs rating methodologies. It was good to be an NRSRO. The regulatory community did not adapt to these well-known developments. Distressingly, the intensication of conicts of interest through the selling of consulting services by rating agencies closely resembles the amplication of conicts of interest when accounting rms increased their sales of consulting services to the rms they were auditing. This facilitated the corporate scandals that emerged less than a decade ago, motivating the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002. Yet, still, regulators did not respond as rating agencies pursued these increasingly protable lines of business. 2.5 Conclusions While the crisis does not have a single cause, the behavior of the credit rating agencies is a dening characteristic. It is impossible to imagine the current crisis without the activities of the NRSROs. And, it is difcult to imagine the behavior of the NRSROs without the regulations that permitted, protected, and encouraged their activities.
JFEP 2,3
202
In terms of the postmortem, the role of NRSROs is not an example of accidental death or suicide. The conicts of interest within NRSROs have been known for decades and the further perversion of incentives due to securitization was predicted over a decade before the crisis. Similarly, it is difcult to view the NRSROs as suicidal. The decision makers at NRSROs made enormous amounts of money. It was a logical, rational, and legal decision. As noted in an internal e-mail by an S&P employee, Lets hope we are all wealthy and retired by the time this house of cards falters (Chan, 2010a). Rather, the evidence is most consistent with the view that regulatory policies and Congressional laws protected and encouraged the behavior of NRSROs. 3. CDSs and bank capital 3.1 Background Next, consider the role of complex derivative contracts, including CDSs. According to this view, nanciers used newly designed nancial instruments to boost prots, with the systemic risks of these nancial innovations largely unknown. When the housing market faltered, triggering a devastating reduction in the price of derivative securities, this shocked both markets and regulators. But, is this an accurate, complete characterization? A CDS is an insurance-like contract written on the performance of a security or bundle of securities. For example, purchaser A buys a CDS from issuer B on security C. If security C has a predened credit related event, such as missing an interest payment, receiving a credit downgrade, or ling for bankruptcy, then issuer B pays purchaser A. While having insurance-like qualities, CDSs are not formally insurance contracts. Neither the purchaser nor the issuer of the CDS needs to hold the underlying security, leading to the frequently used analogy that CDSs are like buying re insurance on your neighbors house. Moreover, since CDSs are not insurance contracts, they are not regulated as tightly as insurance products. CDSs are nancial derivatives that are transacted in unregulated, OTC markets. In principle, banks can use CDSs to reduce both their exposure to credit risk and the amount of capital held against potential losses. For example, if a bank purchases a CDS on a loan, this can reduce its credit risk: if the loan defaults, the counterparty to the CDS will compensate the bank for the loss. If the banks regulator concludes that the counterparty to the CDS will actually pay the bank if the loan defaults, then the regulator typically allows the bank to reallocate capital to higher expected return, higher risk assets. 3.2 The Fed, CDSs, and bank capital The Fed made a momentous decision in 1996: it permitted banks to use CDSs to reduce capital reserves (Tett, 2009, p. 49). Regulators treated securities guaranteed by a seller of CDSs as having the risk level of the seller or more accurately, the counterparty of the CDS. For example, a bank purchasing full CDS protection from American International Group (AIG) on collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) linked to sub-prime loans would have those CDOs treated as AAA securities for capital regulatory purposes because AIG had an AAA rating from a NRSRO, i.e. from a SEC-approved credit rating agency. Consequently, banks used CDSs to reduce capital and invest in more lucrative, albeit more risky, assets. For example, a bank with a typical portfolio of $10 billion of
commercial loans could reduce its capital reserves against these assets from about $800 million to under $200 million by purchasing CDSs for a small fee (Tett, 2009, p. 64). The CDS market boomed following the Feds decision. By 2007, the largest US commercial banks had purchased $7.9 trillion in CDS protection and the overall CDS market reached a notional value of $62 trillion (Barth et al., 2009). There were, however, serious problems associated with allowing banks to reduce their capital via CDSs. Given the active trading of CDSs, it was sometimes difcult to indentify the actual counterparty legally responsible for compensating a bank if an insured security failed. Furthermore, some bank counterparties developed massive exposures to CDS risk. For example, AIG had a notional exposure of about $500 billion to CDSs (and related derivatives) in 2007, while having a capital base of about $100 billion to cover all its traditional insurance activities as well as its nancial derivatives business. The growing exposure of AIG and other issuers of CDSs should have and did raise concerns about their ability to satisfy their obligations in times of economic stress. 3.3 The Fed maintains its policy despite growing risks The Fed was aware of the growing danger to the safety and soundness of the banking system from CDSs[3]. For instance, Tett (2009, p. 157-63) recounts how Timothy Geithner, then President of the New York Federal Reserve Bank, became concerned in 2004 about the lack of information on CDSs and the growing counterparty risk facing banks. Barth et al. (2009, p. 184-93) demonstrate through the use of internal Fed documents that it knew by 2004 of the growing problems associated with subprime mortgage related assets, on which many CDSs were written. Indeed, the FBI publicly warned in 2004 of an epidemic of fraud in subprime lending. In terms of the sellers of CDSs, detailed accounts by Lewis (2009) and McDonald and Robinson (2009) illustrate the Feds awareness by 2006 of AIGs growing fragility and the corresponding exposure of commercial banks to CDS counterparty risk[4]. Yet, even more momentously than the original decision allowing banks to reduce their capital reserves through the use of CDSs, the Fed did not adjust its policies as it learned of the growing fragility of the banking system due to the mushrooming use of increasingly suspect CDSs. The key question is why the Fed maintained its capital regulations. Bank purchases of CDSs boomed immediately after the 1996 regulatory decision allowing a reduction in bank capital from the purchase of CDSs. Why did not the Fed respond by demanding greater transparency before granting capital relief and conducting its own assessment of the counterparty risks facing the systemically important banks under its supervision? Why did not the Fed adjust in 2004 as it learned of the opaque nature of the CDS market and as the FBI warned of the fraudulent practices associated with the issuance of the sub-prime mortgages underlying many CDS securities, or in 2006 as information became available about the fragility of AIG, or in 2007 when hedge funds warned the Fed, the Treasury, and G8 delegates about the growing fragility of commercial banks (Tett, 2009, p. 160-3)? Why did not the Fed prohibit banks from reducing regulatory capital via CDSs until the Fed had condence in the nancial viability of those selling CDSs to banks? The Feds decision to maintain its regulatory stance toward CDSs was neither a failure of information, nor a shortage of regulatory power. Based on a review of internal Fed documents, Barth et al. (2009, p. 184) note:
JFEP 2,3
[. . .] even if the top ofcials from these regulatory agencies did not appreciate or wish to act earlier on the information they had, their subordinates apparently fully understood and appreciated the growing magnitude of the problem.
204
And, even in 2004, the Fed issued Interpretive Letter No. 998 that reiterated its capital regulatory policy with respect to CDSs. It was a choice; it was a failure of regulatory governance. The Fed could have modied its capital regulations based on two simple, prudent premises. First, the Fed is responsible for the safely and soundness of the nancial system, which relies on the largest banks holding capital commensurate with their risks. Second, the Fed did not have reliable methods for assessing the credit risk of those selling CDSs to banks, nor could it rely on the credit rating agencies to assess that counterparty risk. Based on these principles, the Fed could have prohibited banks from reducing regulatory capital via CDSs until the Fed had condence in the nancial viability of those selling CDSs to banks. It is true that the Fed did not have regulatory authority over CDSs, the credit rating agencies, AIG, or many other sellers of CDSs, so it could not have directly improved the counterparty risk associated with CDS. But, the Fed was and is responsible for overseeing the safely and soundness of the major banks. If it had refused to allow banks to reduce their capital reserves via CDSs, the Fed could have both enhanced the stability of the major banks and indirectly created incentives for improvements in the CDS market. 3.4 Postmortem I am not suggesting that the Feds decision to allow banks to reduce their regulatory capital through the purchase of CDSs was the major cause of the global nancial crisis. It is quite difcult to quantify the degree to which this policy increased risk-taking at any individual bank or the fragility of the nancial system as a whole. I am suggesting that the evolution of the CDS market, the fragility of the banks, and the Feds capital rules illustrate key features of the nancial crisis that are frequently ignored in current discussions of regulatory reform. First, the problems with CDSs and bank capital were not a surprise in 2008; there was ample warning that things were going awry. Second, senior government policymakers created policies that encouraged reckless behavior by nanciers and adhered to those policies over many years even as they learned about the ramications of their policies. 4. Transparency vs the Fed, SEC, and Treasury Powerful regulators and policymakers thwarted efforts to make the CDS market more transparent. The Fed (under Alan Greenspan), the Treasury (under Robert Rubin and then Larry Summers), and the SEC (under Arthur Levitt) squashed attempts by Brooksley Born of the Commodity Future Trading Commission (CFTC) to shed light on the multi-hundred-trillion dollar OTC derivatives market, which included CDSs, at the end of the 1990s. Incidents of fraud, manipulation, and failure in the OTC derivatives market began as early as 1994, with the sensational bankruptcy of Orange County and court cases involving Gibson Greeting Cards and Proctor & Gamble against Bankers Trust. Numerous problems, associated with bankers exploiting unsophisticated school districts and municipalities, plagued the market. Further, OTC derivates played a dominant role in the dramatic failure of long-term capital management (LTCM) in the
Summer of 1998. Indeed, no regulatory agency had any warning of LTCMs demise, or the potential systemic implications of its failure, because it traded primarily in this opaque market. In light of these problems and the lack of information on the OTC derivatives market, the CFTC issued a concept release report in 1998 calling for greater transparency of OTC derivatives. The CFTC sought greater information disclosure, improvements in record keeping, and controls on fraud. The CFTC did not call for draconian controls on the derivatives market; it called for more transparency. The response by the Fed, the Treasury, and the SEC was swift: They stopped the CFTC. First, they obtained a six month moratorium on the CFTCs ability to implement the strategies outlined in its concept release. Second, the Presidents Working Group on Financial Markets, which consists of the Secretary of the Treasury, the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, the Chairman of the SEC, and the Chairman of the CFTC, initiated a study of the OTC derivatives market. Finally, they helped convince Congress to pass the Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, which exempted the OTC derivates market and hence the CDS market from government oversight. Senior regulators and policymakers lobbied hard to keep CDSs and other derivatives in opaque markets. This policy was not an accident; it was a choice. The point of this addendum is to emphasize that senior regulators and policymakers lobbied hard to keep CDSs and other derivatives in opaque markets. Thus, a comprehensive assessment of the causes of the crisis must evaluate why policymakers made choices like this. Indeed, Timiraos and Hagerty (2010) argue:
Nearly, a year and half after the outbreak of the global economic crisis, many of the problems that contributed to it havent been tamed. The U.S. has no system in place to tackle a failure of its largest nancial institutions. Derivatives contracts of the kind that crippled AIG Inc. still trade in the shadows. And investors remain heavily reliant on the same credit-ratings rms that gave AAA ratings to lousy mortgage securities.
5.1 Total failure All ve major investment banks supervised by the SEC experienced major transformations in 2008. Only three days after the SEC Chairman expressed condence in the nancial soundness of the investment banks on March 11, 2008, the New York Federal Reserve provided an emergency $25 billion loan to Bear Stearns in a vain attempt to avert Bears failure. A few days later, with additional nancial assistance from the Fed, a failed Bear Stearns merged with the commercial bank JP Morgan Chase & Co. Six months later, Lehman Brothers went bankrupt, and a few months later, at the brink of insolvency, Merrill Lynch merged with Bank of America. In the Autumn of 2008, Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley were pressured into becoming bank holding companies by the Federal Reserve and arguably rescued from failure through an assortment of public programs.
JFEP 2,3
206
5.2 Three coordinated SEC policies The SECs ngerprints are indelibly imprinted on this debacle. First, the SEC in 2004 exempted the ve largest investment banks from the net capital rule, which was a 1975 rule for computing minimum capital standards at broker-dealers[5]. The investment banks were permitted to use their own mathematical models of asset and portfolio risk to compute appropriate capital levels. The investment banks responded by issuing more debt to purchase more risky securities without putting commensurately more of their own capital at risk. Leverage ratios soared from their 2004 levels, as the banks models indicated that they had sufcient capital cushions. Second, in a related, coordinated 2004 policy change, the SEC enacted a rule that induced the ve investment banks to become consolidated supervised entities (CSEs): The SEC would oversee the entire nancial rm. Specically, the SEC now had responsibility for supervising the holding company, broker-dealer afliates, and all other afliates on a consolidated basis. These other afliates include other regulated entities, such as foreign-registered broker-dealers and banks, as well as unregulated entities such as derivatives dealers (Colby, 2007). The SEC was charged with evaluating the models employed by the broker-dealers in computing appropriate capital levels and assessing the overall stability of the consolidated investment bank. Given the size and complexity of these nancial conglomerates, overseeing the CSEs was a systemically important and difcult responsibility. Third, the SEC neutered its ability to conduct consolidated supervision of major investment banks. With the elimination of the net capital rule and the added complexity of consolidated supervision, the SECs head of market regulation, Annette Nazareth, promised to hire high-skilled supervisors to assess the riskiness of investment banking activities. But, the SEC did not. In fact, the SEC had only seven people to examine the parent companies of the investment banks, which controlled over $4 trillion in assets. Under Christopher Cox, who became chairman in 2005, the SEC eliminated the risk management ofce and failed to complete a single inspection of a major investment bank in the year and a half before the collapse of those banks (Labaton, 2008a). Cox also weakened the Enforcement Divisions freedom to impose nes on nancial rms under its jurisdiction. 5.3 The effects of these decisions With these three policies, the SEC became willfully blind to excessive risk taking, contributing to the onset, magnitude, and breadth of the nancial crisis. The SEC has correctly argued that the net capital rule never applied to the holding company in defending the 2004 net capital rule. But, this defense is narrowly focused on the net capital rule alone. It is the combination of SEC policies that helped trigger the crisis, not only the change in the net capital rule[6]. In easing the net capital rule, adopting a system of consolidated supervision, but failing to develop the capabilities to supervise large nancial conglomerates, the SEC became willfully blind to excessive risk-taking. The evidence points inexorably toward the SEC as an accomplice in creating a fragile nancial system. Indeed, the current Chairwomen of the SEC, Mary Schapiro, and a court appointed investigator agree with this assessment. Ms Schapiro noted:
I think everybody a few years ago got caught up in the idea that the markets are self-correcting and self-disciplined, and that the people in Wall Street will do a better job
protecting the nancial system than the regulators would. I do think the SEC got diverted by that philosophy (Wyatt, 2010).
Valukass (2010) 2,200-page report on the causes of the Lehman Brothers failure to the bankruptcy court is even more pointed. It notes that: . Lehman regularly exceeded its own risk limits; and . the SEC knew about these excesses and did nothing. To conclude, consider the testimony of The SECs Deputy Director, Robert Colby (2007), before the US House of Representatives Financial Services Committee on April 25:
[. . .] the bill as introduced would subject the CSEs that already are highly regulated under the Commissions consolidated supervision program to an additional layer of duplicative and burdensome holding company oversight. The bill should be amended to recognize the unique ability of the Commission to comprehensively supervise the consolidated groups [. . .] Because the Commission has established a successful consolidated supervision program based on its unique expertise [. . .]
About 18 months after the SEC argued that it was successfully supervising the ve major investment banks, they had either gone bankrupt, failed and merged with other rms, or were forced to convert to bank holding companies, with billions of taxpayer dollars spent on facilitating these arrangements. The purposeful elimination of supervisory guardrails supports a charge of gross negligence, without malice, in facilitating the nancial crisis. 6. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac 6.1 Background The government, through the Federal Housing Finance Agency, placed into conservatorship both the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae) and the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac) on September 7, 2008. Together, these two regulated housing-nance giants owned or guaranteed almost $7 trillion worth of mortgages. Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac are Congressionally chartered, stockholder-owned corporations. These government-sponsored entities (GSEs) were designed to facilitate housing nance. They purchase mortgages from banks and mortgages companies that lend directly to homeowners, package the mortgages into MBSs, guarantee timely payment of interest and principal, and sell the MBSs to investors. Besides this core securitization activity, the GSEs also buy and hold mortgages and MBSs. By increasing the demand for, and hence the price of, mortgages in the secondary market, the GSEs can reduce the interest rates the homebuyers pay on mortgages in the primary market, fostering home ownership. While facilitating housing is a raison detre, the GSEs also used their privileged positions to earn substantial prots. The GSEs borrowed cheaply: the debt issued by these two nancial institutions enjoyed an implicit government guarantee, which was made explicit when the government placed them into conservatorship. Thus, the GSEs could borrow at low interest rates and buy mortgages with higher interest rates. Over time, the GSEs increased the degree to which they bought and held mortgages relative to their securitization role, in which they bought, packaged, guaranteed, and sold MBSs. As long as there were not too many defaults, the GSEs made enormous prots. Indeed,
JFEP 2,3
prots were limited primarily by the size of the mortgage market and threatened by regulatory interventions that might force GSEs to funnel more of their earnings into lowering primary mortgage rates, with a concomitant lowering of GSE prots. Fortunately, for the GSEs, Congress and other policymakers helped expand the mortgage market and kept regulatory interventions to a minimum. 6.2 Policy changes and effects Two policies combined to expand the mortgage market for GSEs: the expansion of the affordable housing mission of GSEs and the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) as discussed in Barth et al. (2009), Joint Center for Housing Studies (2008), and Wallison and Calomiris (2009). Enacted in 1977, the CRA was designed to boost lending to disadvantaged areas by prohibiting discrimination. In the mid-1990s, under the CRA, regulators started using quantitative guidelines to induce greater lending to low- and moderate-income (LMI) areas and borrowers. The Department of Housing and Urban Development in the mid-1990s put corresponding pressure on the GSEs to adjust their nancing standards to facilitate the ow of credit to LMI borrowers, encouraging the GSEs to nance lower quality mortgages. Furthermore, Congress also added an affordable housing mission to the GSEs. In 1991, Fannie Mae announced a $1 trillion affordable housing initiative, and in 1994, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac initiated an additional $2 trillion program for LMI borrowers. These policies permitted and encouraged the GSEs to accept lower quality mortgages and hence spurred primary market lenders to lend more to more suspect borrowers. For example, by 2001, the GSEs were purchasing mortgages that had no down payment; between 2005 and 2007, they bought approximately $1 trillion of mortgages with subprime characteristics; which accounted for about 45 percent of their mortgage purchases (Wallison and Calomiris, 2009 and Fannie Mae, 2008). By signaling to mortgage lenders that they would purchase mortgages with subprime characteristics such as mortgages with low FICO credit scores, high loan-to-value ratios, negative amortization, low documentation Fannie and Freddie triggered a massive movement into the issuance of lower quality mortgages. Mortgage companies were more willing to accept the fees for making loans to questionable borrowers if they knew that the GSEs would purchase the loan. The push into lower quality mortgages created a complex mutual dependency between Congress and the GSEs, fueling their increasingly risky investments (Wallison and Calomiris, 2009). Congress relied on the GSEs to both promote housing policies and to provide campaign donations. The GSEs relied on Congress to protect their protable privileges and refrain from regulatory interventions. Each satised its side of the bargain. The GSEs provided generous campaign contributions and greatly expanded their funding of LMI borrowers. Prots and bonuses soared. In turn, policymakers limited regulatory oversight of the GSEs. Indeed, even after the House Banking Subcommittee and the GSEs regulator (Ofce of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight) accused them of serious accounting fraud in 2000, 2003, and 2004 and even as evidence emerged of their nancial fragility, Congress did not pass a proposed bill that would have strengthened supervision of the GSEs and prohibited the GSEs from buying and holding MBSs. Such a policy shift would have limited GSE exposure to low-quality mortgages, which ultimately led to their bankruptcy.
208
6.3 Postmortem Deterioration in the nancial condition of the GSEs was not a surprise. The New York Times warned in 1999 that Fannie Mae was taking on so much risk that an economic downturn could trigger a rescue similar to that of the savings and loan industry in the 1980s, and again emphasized this point in 2003 (Holmes, 1999). From 2003 through 2007, the GSEs regulator warned of excessive risk taking; the Treasury acknowledged ineffective oversight of the GSEs; Congress discussed the fragility of GSEs and their illusory prots; Alan Greenspan testied before the Senate Banking Committee in 2004 that the increasingly large and risky GSE portfolios could have enormously adverse ramications; and Taleb (2007) warned that the GSEs seem to be sitting on a barrel of dynamite, vulnerable to the slightest hiccup (Berenson, 2003; Goldfarb, 2008; Labaton, 2003; Greenspan, 2004). But, Congress did not respond and allowed increasingly fragile GSEs to endanger the entire nancial system. It is difcult to discern why. Some did not want to jeopardize the increased provision of affordable housing. Many received generous nancial support from the GSEs in return for their protection. For the purposes of this paper, the critical issue is that policymakers did not respond as the GSEs became systemically fragile. Again, I am not arguing that the timing, extent, and full nature of the housing bubble were perfectly known. I am arguing that policymakers created incentives for massive risk-taking by the GSEs and then did not respond to information that this risk taking threatened the nancial system. 7. Conclusion Finance is powerful. As the last few years demonstrate, the malfunctioning of the nancial system can trigger economic crises, harming the welfare of many. As the last few centuries demonstrate, the functioning of the nancial system affects long-run economic growth. If nancial systems funnel societys savings to those with the best projects, this helps promote and sustain economic progress (Levine, 2005). Getting nancial policies right is a rst-order priority in creating an environment conducive to economic prosperity. This paper has examined the determinants of the recent crisis. Without denying the importance of capital account imbalances and herd behavior, my analyses suggest that this is not the entire story. Similarly, while a conuence of surprises helped trigger the crisis, the evidence is inconsistent with the view that poor information about nancial institutions was the sole cause of the crisis. Thus, the evidence is inconsistent with testimonies before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission by Robert Rubin (former Treasury secretary and former director of Citigroup), Charles O. Prince III (former CEO of Citigroup), and Alan Greenspan (former Chairman of the Fed), who claim that the crisis was an unprecedented and unpredictable accident. The crisis did not just happen. Policymakers and regulators, along with private sector coconspirators, helped cause it. The evidence indicates that nancial sector policies during the period from 1996 through 2006 precipitated the crisis. Either by becoming willfully blind to excessive risk taking or by maintaining policies that encouraged destabilizing behaviors, policymakers, and regulatory agencies contributed to the nancial systems collapse. As noted by Senator Carl Levin, The recent nancial crisis was not a natural disaster; it was a manmade economic assault. It will happen again unless we change the rules.
JFEP 2,3
Notes 1. Citigroups former CEO, Charles O. Prince, noted to the Financial Times (Nakamoto and Wighton, 2007), When the music stops [. . .] things will be complicated. But as long as the music is playing, you have got to get up and dance. We are still dancing. 2. See Hill (2010a, b) for insight examinations of credit-ratings rms. 3. There is a longer history. In 1992, the President of the NY Federal Reserve Bank, Jerry Corrigan, expressed grave concerns that derivatives, primarily interest rates swaps, threatened the stability of banks and threatened the banks with tighter regulations (Tett, 2009, pp. 17-18). But, Alan Greenspan, the Chairman of the entire Federal Reserve System, supported the International Swaps and Derivatives Association and successfully convinced Congress in 1994 to keep derivatives largely unregulated (Tett, 2009, pp. 39-40). 4. Furthermore, although the demise and government conservatorship of AIG in the September of 2008 is sometimes discussed as a complete surprise, it was not a surprise to the Fed or to (The) Time magazine, which ran an article on March 17, 2008 titled, Credit default swaps: the next crisis. The article reported that AIG had recently taken an $11 billion write-down on its CDS holdings and that loses on CDS holdings severely damaged Swiss Reinsurance Co. and monoline bond insurance companies, including MBIA and Ambac Financial Group Inc. The article noted explicitly that these developments could be devastating for the nancial institutions that purchased credit protection from these insurers. Yet, on March 16, 2008 on CNN, Treasury Secretary Paulson noted that, I have great, great condence in our capital markets and in our nancial institutions. Our nancial institutions, banks, and investment banks, are strong. (Quoted from Barth et al., 2009, p. 1). Why did not the Fed prepare for the potential failure of AIG or other major sellers of CDSs in the spring of 2008? So far, US taxpayers have handed over about $180 billion to AIG. 5. As the SEC Commissioners debated the policy, they noted that it could lead to a potential catastrophe and questioned whether we really will have investor protection. Yet, they ultimately voted for it, with one commissioner noting that he would keep my ngers crossed for the future. For an illuminating video of the actual meeting, see Labaton (2008b). 6. The SEC also correctly notes that leverage ratios at the CSE holding companies were higher during some years in the 1990s than in 2006. But, the nature of nancial markets and risk-taking shifted markedly from the 1990s to the mid-2000s due to the explosion of structured products and the increased use of OTC derivatives. Thus, comparing leverage ratios in the 1990s to those in 2006 is much less informative than comparing leverage ratios from 2004 to 2006, when leverage ratios boomed after the SEC changed its policies. References Acharya, V.V. and Richardson, M. (2009), Restoring Financial Stability: How to Repair a Failed System, Wiley, New York, NY. Barth, J.R., Caprio, G. Jr and Levine, R. (2010), Guardians of Finance: How to Make Them Work for Us, MIT Press (in press). Barth, J.R., Li, T., Lu, W., Phumiwasana, T. and Yago, G. (2009), The Rise and Fall of the US Mortgage and Credit Markets, Wiley, Hoboken, NJ. Bebchuk, L.A. (2010a), Regulating bankers pay, Georgetown Law Journal, Vol. 98 No. 2, pp. 247-87. Bebchuk, L.A. (2010b), The wages of failure: executive compensation at bear STEARNS and Lehman 2000-2008, Yale Journal on Regulation, Vol. 27, Summer, pp. 257-82. Berenson, A. (2003), Fannie Maes loss risk is larger, computer models show, The New York Times, August 7.
210
Bernanke, B.S. (2009a), Financial reform to address systemic risk, Speech at the Council of Foreign Relations, Washington, DC, March 10. Bernanke, B.S. (2009b), Four questions about the nancial crisis, Speech at Morehouse College, Atlanta, GA, March 14. Chan, S. (2010a), Documents show internal qualms at rating agencies, The New York Times, April 23. Chan, S. (2010b), US faults regulators over a bank, The New York Times, April 12. Chan, S. and Dash, E. (2010), Fed reviews nd errors in oversight of cititgroup, The New York Times, April 8. Colby, R. (2007), Testimony concerning the consolidated supervision of US securities rms and afliated industrial loan corporations, The US House of Representatives Financial Services Committee, Washington, DC, April 25. Fannie Mae (2008), 2008 Q2 10-Q investor summary, available at: www.fanniemae.com/media/ pdf/newsreleases/2008_Q2_10Q_Investor_Sum mary.pdf (accessed August 8). FDIC Ofce of Inspector General (2009-2010), Material Loss Reviews, available at: www.fdicoig. gov/MLR.shtml Geithner, T. (2009), Written testimony, The US House of Representatives Financial Services and Agriculture Committees Joint Hearing on Regulation of OTC Derivatives, July 10. Goldfarb, Z.A. (2008), Affordable-housing goals scaled back, The Washington Post, September 24. Greenspan, A. (2004), Proposals for improving the regulation of the housing government sponsored enterprises, Testimony before the US Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, February 24. Greenspan, A. (2010), The Crisis, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Brookings Institution, Washington press, DC (in press). Hill, C.A. (2010a), Who were the villains in the sub prime crisis, and why it matters, 4 Entrepreneurial Business Law Journal, Vol. 14, pp. 323-50. Hill, C.A. (2010b), Why did the rating agencies do such a bad job rating subprime securities?, University of Pittsburgh Law Review, Vol. 71 (in press). Holmes, S.A. (1999), Fannie Mae Eases credit to aid mortgage lending, The New York Times, September 30. Jagannathan, R., Kapoor, M. and Schaumburg, E. (2009), Why are we in a recession? The nancial crisis is the symptom not the disease, Working Paper No. 15404, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Joint Center for Housing Studies (2008), The State of the Nations Housing, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Kamin, S.B. and DeMarco, L.P. (2010), How did a domestic housing slump turn into a global nancial crisis?, Working Paper No. 994, International Finance Discussion Papers, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Labaton, S. (2003), New agency proposed to oversee Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae, The New York Times, September 31. Labaton, S. (2008a), Agencys 04 rule let banks pile up new debt, The New York Times, October 3. Labaton, S. (2008b), The day the S.E.C. changed the game, The New York Times, video, September 28, available at: www.nytimes.com/interactive/2008/09/28/business/20080928SEC-multimedia/index.html
JFEP 2,3
212
Levine, R. (2005), Finance and growth: theory and evidence, in Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S.N. (Eds), Handbook of Economic Growth, Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp. 866-934. Levine, R. (2010), The sentinel: improving the governance of nancial policies, in Demirguc-Kunt, A., Evanoff, D.D. and Kaufman, G.G. (Eds), The International Financial Crisis: Have the Rules of Finance Changed?, World Scientic Publishing, Hackensack, NJ. Lewis, M. (2009), The man who crashed the world, Vanity Fair, August. Lowenstein, R. (2008), Triple-a failure, The New York Times, April 27. McDonald, L.G. and Robinson, P. (2009), A Colossal Failure of Common Sense: The Inside Story of the Collapse of Lehman Brothers, Crown Publishing, New York, NY. Morgenson, G. (2008), Debt watchdogs: tamed or caught napping?, The New York Times, December 7. Nakamoto, M. and Wighton, D. (2007), Citigroup chief stays bullish on buy-outs, Financial Times, July 9. Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (2009), Global imbalances and the nancial crisis: products of common causes, paper presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Asia Economic Policy Conference, October 18-20, Santa Barbara, CA, available at: www.frbsf.org/economics/ conferences/aepc/2009/09_Obstfeld.pdf Ofce of Inspector General of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2010), Reports, available at: www.federalreserve.gov/oig/default.htm Partnoy, F. (1999), The Siskel and Ebert of nancial markets: two thumbs down for the credit rating agencies, Washington University Law Quarterly, Vol. 77 No. 3, pp. 619-712. Pinches, G.E. and Singleton, J.C. (1978), The adjustment of stock prices to bond rating changes, Journal of Finance, Vol. 33 No. 1, pp. 29-44. Romer, C.D. (2009), Back from the brink, paper presented at Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Conference, The International Financial Crisis: Have the Rules of Finance Changed?, September 24-25, Chicago, IL, available at: www.whitehouse.gov/assets/documents/Back_ from_the_Brink2.pdf Rose, A. and Spiegel, M. (2010), The causes and consequences of the 2008 crisis: early warning, Global Journal of Economics, Vol. 1 No. 1 (in press). Rubin, R. (2010), Testimony Before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, April 9. Taleb, N.N. (2007), The Black Swan, Penguin, New York, NY. Tett, G. (2009), Fools Gold, The Free Press, New York, NY. Timiraos, N. and Hagerty, J.R. (2010), No exit in sight for US as Fannie, Freddie Flail, The Wall Street Journal, February 9. Valukas, A.R. (2010), Lehman Brothers Holdings Inc. Chapter 11 Proceedings examiners report, United States Bankruptcy Court Southern District, New York, NY, available at: http:// lehmanreport.jenner.com/ (accessed March 11). Wallison, P.J. and Calomiris, C.W. (2009), The last trillion-dollar commitment: the destruction of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, Journal of Structured Finance, Vol. 15 No. 1, pp. 71-80. Wyatt, E. (2010), SEC puts wall St. on notice, The New York Times, April 19.
Further reading Barth, J.R., Caprio, G. Jr and Levine, R. (2006), Rethinking Bank Regulation: Till Angels Govern, Cambridge University Press, New York, NY.
Bernanke, B.S. (2010), Monetary policy and the housing bubble, Speech at the Annual Meeting of the America Economic Association, Atlanta, GA, January 3. Brunnermeier, M.K. (2009), Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007-08, Journal Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23 No. 1, pp. 77-100. Caprio, G., Demirgiic-Kunt, A. and Kane, E. (2008), The 2007 meltdown in structured securitization: searching for lessons not scapegoats, World Bank mimeo, November 28. Cecchetti, S.G. (2009), Crisis and responses: the federal reserve in the early stages of the nancial crisis, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 23 No. 1, pp. 51-75. Coffee, J.C. (2008), Analyzing the credit crisis: was the SEC missing in action?, New York Law Journal, December 5. Demirgiic-Kunt, A. and Levine, R. (2009), Finance and inequality: theory and evidence, Annual Review of Financial Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 287-318. Greenspan, A. (2005), Economic exibility, Speech given to the National Association for Business Economics, Annual Meeting, Chicago, IL, September 27. Kane, E.J. (2009a), Incentive roots of the securitization crisis and its early mismanagement, Yale Journal of Regulation, Vol. 26 No. 2, pp. 405-16. Kane, E.J. (2009b), Regulation and supervision: an ethical perspective, in Berger, A.N., Molyneux, P. and Wilson, J. (Eds), Oxford Handbook of Banking, Oxford University Press, London, pp. 315-38. Levine, R. (1997), Financial development and economic growth: views and agenda, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35 No. 2, pp. 688-726. Corresponding author Ross Levine can be contacted at: [email protected]
To purchase reprints of this article please e-mail: [email protected] Or visit our web site for further details: www.emeraldinsight.com/reprints