Fiscal Policy
Fiscal Policy
Fiscal policy is carried out by the legislative and/or the executive branches of government. The
two main instruments of fiscal policy are government expenditures and taxes. The
government collects taxes in order to finance expenditures on a number of public goods and
Budget deficits and surpluses. When government expenditures exceed government tax
revenues in a given year, the government is running a budget deficit for that year. The budget
deficit, which is the difference between government expenditures and tax revenues, is financed
by government borrowing; the government issues long-term, interest-bearing bonds and uses
the proceeds to finance the deficit. The total stock of government bonds and interest payments
outstanding, from both the present and the past, is known as the national debt. Thus, when the
government expenditures are less than tax revenues in a given year, the government is running
a budget surplus for that year. The budget surplus is the difference between tax revenues and
government expenditures. The revenues from the budget surplus are typically used to reduce any
existing national debt. In the case where government expenditures are exactly equal to tax
revenues in a given year, the government is running a balanced budget for that year.
an increase in government expenditures and/or a decrease in taxes that causes the government's
budget deficit to increase or its budget surplus to decrease. Contractionary fiscal policy is
defined as a decrease in government expenditures and/or an increase in taxes that causes the
Classical and Keynesian views of fiscal policy. The belief that expansionary and
closely associated with Keynes and his followers. The classical view of expansionary or
contractionary fiscal policies is that such policies are unnecessary because there are market
mechanisms—for example, the flexible adjustment of prices and wages—which serve to keep the
economy at or near the natural level of real GDP at all times. Accordingly, classical economists
believe that the government should run a balanced budget each and every year.
Combating a recession using expansionary fiscal policy. Keynesian theories of output and
employment were developed in the midst of the Great Depression of the 1930s, when
unemployment rates in the U.S. and Europe exceeded 25% and the growth rate of real GDP
declined steadily for most of the decade. Keynes and his followers believed that the way to
combat the prevailing recessionary climate was not to wait for prices and wages to adjust but to
engage in expansionary fiscal policy instead. The Keynesians' argument in favor of expansionary
Assume that the economy is initially in a recession. The equilibrium level of real GDP, Y1 , lies
below the natural level, Y2, implying that there is less than full employment of the economy's
resources. Classical economists believe that the presence of unemployed resources causes wages
to fall, reducing costs to suppliers and causing the SAS curve to shift from SAS1 toSAS 2, thereby
restoring the economy to full employment. Keynesians, however, argue that wages are sticky
downward and will not adjust quickly enough to reflect the reality of unemployed resources.
Consequently, the recessionary climate may persist for a long time. The way out of this difficulty,
excess of current tax receipts. The increase in government expenditures should be sufficient to
cause the aggregate demand curve to shift to the right from AD 1 to AD 2, restoring the economy
to the natural level of real GDP. This increase in government expenditures need not, of course,
be equal to the difference between Y1 and Y2. Recall that any increase in autonomous aggregate
Hence, the government needs only to increase its expenditures by a small amount to cause
aggregate demand to increase by the amount necessary to achieve the natural level of real GDP.
Keynesians argue that expansionary fiscal policy provides a quick way out of a recession and is
to be preferred to waiting for wages and prices to adjust, which can take a long time. As Keynes
Combating inflation using contractionary fiscal policy. Keynesians also argue that fiscal
policy can be used to combat expected increases in the rate of inflation. Suppose that the
economy is already at the natural level of real GDP and that aggregate demand is projected to
increase further, which will cause the AD curve in Figure 2 to shift from AD 1 to AD 2 .
As real GDP rises above its natural level, prices also rise, prompting an increase in wages and
other resource prices and causing the SAS curve to shift from SAS1 to SAS 2. The end result is
inflation of the price level from P 1 to P 3 , with no change in real GDP. The government can head
off this inflation by engaging in a contractionary fiscal policy designed to reduce aggregate
demand by enough to prevent the AD curve from shifting out to AD 2. Again, the government
needs only to decrease expenditures or increase taxes by a small amount because of the
Secondary effects of fiscal policy. Classical economists point out that the Keynesian view of
the effectiveness of fiscal policy tends to ignore the secondary effects that fiscal policy can
have on credit market conditions. When the government pursues an expansionary fiscal policy, it
finances its deficit spending by borrowing funds from the nation's credit market. Assuming that
the money supply remains constant, the government's borrowing of funds in the credit market
tends to reduce the amount of funds available and thereby drives up interest rates. Higher
interest rates, in turn, tend to reduce or “crowd out” aggregate investment expenditures and
consumer expenditures that are sensitive to interest rates. Hence, the effectiveness of
expansionary fiscal policy in stimulating aggregate demand will be mitigated to some degree by
The same holds true for contractionary fiscal policies designed to combat expected inflation. If
the government reduces its expenditures and thereby reduces its borrowing, the supply of
available funds in the credit market increases, causing the interest rate to fall. Aggregate
demand increases as the private sector increases its investment and interest-sensitive
the part of the private sector. This crowding-in effect mitigates the effectiveness of the
contractionary fiscal policy in counteracting rising aggregate demand and inflationary pressures.