The Microstructure Approach To Exchange Rates
The Microstructure Approach To Exchange Rates
MICROSTRUCTURE
APPROACH
TO EXCHANGE
RATES
RICHARD K.
LYONS
The Microstructure
Approach to Exchange
Rates
The Microstructure
Approach to Exchange
Rates
Richard K. Lyons
Contents
Preface
ix
19
37
Theoretical Frameworks
63
Empirical Frameworks
10 Looking Forward
Notes
279
References
305
Index
325
263
113
151
171
221
243
Preface
Preface
Preface
xi
xii
Preface
Overview of the
Microstructure Approach
Ten years ago, a friend of mine who trades spot foreign exchange for
a large bank invited me to spend a few days at his side. At the time, I
considered myself an expert, having written my thesis on exchange
rates. I thought I had a handle on how it worked. I thought wrong.
As I sat there, my friend traded furiously, all day long, racking up
over $1 billion in trades each day (USD). This was a world where the
standard trade was $10 million, and a $1 million trade was a ``skinny
one.'' Despite my belief that exchange rates depend on macroeconomics, only rarely was news of this type his primary concern. Most
of the time my friend was reading tea leaves that were, at least to me,
not so clear. The pace was furiousa quote every ve or ten seconds, a trade every minute or two, and continual decisions about
what position to hold. Needless to say, there was little time for chat.
It was clear my understanding was incomplete when he looked
over in the midst of his fury and asked me, ``What should I do?'' I
laughed. Nervously.
This book is an outgrowth of my subsequent interest in this area. It
is principally concerned with the gap between what I knew before I
sat down with my friend and what I saw when I got there. In effect,
this gap is the space between two elds of scholarship: exchange rate
economics on the one hand, and microstructure nance on the other.
Exchange rate economists use models of exchange rate determination that are macroeconomic (i.e., rates are determined as a function of macro variables such as ination, output, interest rates, etc.).
These same exchange rate economists are largely unfamiliar with
microstructure models. Most microstructure scholars, in contrast,
view foreign exchange as the purview of international economists,
and are unfamiliar with macroeconomic exchange rate models. Their
Chapter 1
traditional focus is the microeconomics of equity markets, particularly the New York Stock Exchange.
Though this book has several objectives, two deserve mention at
the outset. The rst is to lower entry barriers faced by scholars
interested in this burgeoning area. Lowering barriers on both sides
exchange rate economics and microstructure nancewill help this
research domain realize its potential. A second objective is to channel
past work into a more unied approacha microstructure approach.
In the 1990s, many authors applied microstructure tools to foreign
exchange (FX) markets, but existing work is still largely fragmented.
Does exchange rate economics need a new approach? Yes. It is
in crisis. It is in crisis in the sense that current macroeconomic approaches to exchange rates are empirical failures. In their recent survey in the Handbook of International Economics, Jeffrey Frankel and
Andrew Rose (1995, 1709) put it this way: ``To repeat a central fact
of life, there is remarkably little evidence that macroeconomic variables have consistent strong effects on oating exchange rates, except
during extraordinary circumstances such as hyperinations. Such
negative ndings have led the profession to a certain degree of pessimism vis-a-vis exchange rate research.''
In the end, it is my hope that this book might rouse a little
optimism.
1.1
Before the 1970s, the dominant approach to exchange rate determination was the goods market approach. According to this approach,
demand for currencies comes primarily from purchases and sales of
goods. For example, an increase in exports increases foreign demand
for domestic currency to pay for those exported goods. In this simple form, the implication is rather intuitive: countries with trade
surpluses experience appreciation (which comes from the currency
demand created by the surplus). Despite the approach's intuitive
appeal, however, it fails miserably when one looks at the data: trade
balances are virtually uncorrelated with exchange rate movements in
major-currency FX markets. This negative result is perhaps not surprising given that trade in goods and services accounts for only a
small fraction of currency tradingless than 5 percent of the average
$1.5 trillion of FX traded daily.
Chapter 1
This book presents a new approach to exchange rates, the microstructure approach. Under this approach, like the asset market
approach, the demand for currencies comes from purchases and
sales of assets. In this sense these approaches are complementary,
not competing. What distinguishes the microstructure approach is
that it relaxes three of the asset approach's most uncomfortable
assumptions:2
1. Information: microstructure models recognize that some information relevant to exchange rates is not publicly available.
2. Players: microstructure models recognize that market participants
differ in ways that affect prices.
3. Institutions: microstructure models recognize that trading mechanisms differ in ways that affect prices.
People unfamiliar with microstructure believe its focus is on the
third of thesethe consequences of different trading mechanisms.
The focus of this book is resolutely on the rstthe information economics.
(In keeping with this focus, the next chapter moves immediately to
the economics of nancial information; material on trader heterogeneity and trading mechanismspoints 2 and 3is in chapter 3.)3
Empirically, it is simply not true that all information used to determine market-clearing exchange rates is publicly available. We can
analyze the consequences of thistheoretically and empirically
using tools within the microstructure approach. The resulting analysis shows that the public-information assumption is not a good one:
it misses much of exchange rate determination.
Consider some examples that suggest that the microstructure
approach is on target with respect to these three assumptions. Regarding non-public information, FX traders at banks regularly see
trades that are not publicly observable. As I show in later chapters,
this information forecasts subsequent exchange rates (e.g., seeing
the demands of private participants or central banks before the rest
of the market). Regarding differences across market participants,
traders with common information regularly interpret it differently.
Another example of differences across participants is motives for
trade: some traders are primarily hedgers, whereas others are primarily speculators (and even among the latter, speculative horizons
can differ dramatically). Regarding trading mechanisms that affect
prices, consider a market where transparency is low (e.g., where in-
1.2
Chapter 1
Chapter 1
Figure 1.1
Two stages of information processing.
Overarching Themes
10
Chapter 1
practitioner worldviews differ. The example is the timeworn reasoning used by practitioners to account for price movements. In the case
of a price increase, practitioners will assert that ``there were more
buyers than sellers.'' Like other economists, I smile when I hear this. I
smile because in my mind the expression is tantamount to ``price had
to rise to balance demand and supply.'' These phrases may not be
equivalent, however. For economists, the phrase ``price had to rise to
balance demand and supply'' calls to mind the Walrasian auctioneer,
which is an abstract way to think about how price adjusts to a
market-clearing level. The Walrasian auctioneer collects ``preliminary'' orders, which he uses to nd the market-clearing price. All actual
trades occur at this priceno trading occurs in the process of nding
it. (Readers familiar with the rational expectations model of trading
will recognize that in that model, this property is manifested by all
orders being conditioned on a market-clearing price.8)
Practitioners seem to have a different model in mind. In the practitioners' model there is a dealer instead of an abstract auctioneer.
The dealer acts as a buffer between buyers and sellers. The orders the
dealer collects are actual orders, rather than preliminary orders, so
trading does occur in the transition to the new price.9 Crucially, the
dealer then determines new prices from information about demand
and supply that is embedded in the order ow (as suggested in the
``two-stage processing'' diagram above).
Can the practitioner model be rationalized? Not at rst blush, because it appears that trades are occurring at disequilibrium prices
(prices at which the Walrasian auctioneer would not allow trading).
This suggests irrational behavior. But this interpretation misses an
important piece of the puzzle: Whether these trades are out of equilibrium depends on the information available to the dealer. If the
dealer knows at the outset that there are more buyers than sellers,
eventually pushing price up, then it is unclear why that dealer would
sell at a low interim price. If the buyer/seller imbalance is not
known, however, then rational trades can occur through the transition. (Put differently, in setting prices the dealer cannot condition on
all the information available to the Walrasian auctioneer.) This is
precisely the story developed in standard microstructure models.
Trading that would be irrational if the dealer knew as much as
the Walrasian auctioneer can be rationalized in models with more
limitedand more realisticconditioning information.
Theme 2:
11
12
Chapter 1
13
14
Chapter 1
15
1:1
where DPt is the change in the nominal exchange rate over the
period, typically one month. The driving variables in the function
f i; m; z include current and past values of home and foreign nominal interest rates i, money supply m, and other macro determinants,
denoted here by z.14 Changes in these public-information variables
are presumed to drive price without any role for order ow (though
there is of course a role for demand; recall the distinction between
order ow and demand in section 1.2). If any price effects from
order ow should arise, they would be subsumed in the residual et .
Though logically coherent and intuitively appealing, a long literature
documents that these macro determinants account for only a small
portion (less than 10 percent) of the variation in oating exchange
rates (see the surveys by Frankel and Rose 1995; Isard 1995; Taylor
1995).
Structural Models: Microstructure Approach
Within the microstructure approach, equations of exchange rate
determination are derived from the optimization problem faced by
the actual price setters (the dealers).15 These models are variations on
16
Chapter 1
1:2
where now DPt is the change in the nominal exchange rate between
two transactions, versus the monthly frequency of the macro model
in equation (1.1). The driving variables in the function gX; I; Z include order ow X (signed so as to indicate direction), a measure of
dealer net positions (or inventory) I, and other micro determinants,
denoted by Z. It is interesting to note that the residual in this case is
the mirror image of the residual in equation (1.1) in that it subsumes
any price changes due to the public-information variables of the
asset approach.
The key to spanning the micro-macro divide is the role of signed
order ow X. Microstructure models predict a positive relation between signed order ow and price because order ow communicates
nonpublic information, which can then be impounded in price. Empirical estimates of this relation between DP and X are uniformly
positive and signicant in securities markets generally (including
stocks, bonds, and foreign exchange). It is noteworthy that these
empirical estimates have been possible only a relatively short time:
the switch to electronic trading means that we now have detailed
records of order ows. What used to be a black box is no longer.
A Hybrid Approach
To establish the link between the micro and macro approaches, I
investigate in chapter 7 equations with components from both
approaches:
DPt f i; m; z gX; I; Z et :
1:3
17
Figure 1.2
Four months of exchange rates (solid) and order ow (dashed). May 1August 31,
1996.
against the dollar over the four-month sample of the Evans (1997)
dataset (described in chapter 5). The dashed lines represent cumulative order ow for the respective currencies over the same period.
Order ow, denoted by X, is the sum of signed trades over the sample period between foreign exchange dealers worldwide.17 Cumulative order ow and nominal exchange rate levels are strongly
positively correlated (price increases with buying pressure). This result is intriguing. Order ow appears to matter for exchange rate
determination, and the effect appears to be persistent (otherwise the
exchange rate's level would reect only concurrent or very recent
order ow and not cumulative order ow). This persistence is an important property, one that I examine more closely in later chapters.
For order ow to be helpful in resolving big exchange rate puzzles,
its effects have to persist over horizons that match those puzzles
(monthly, at a minimum).18
That order ow matters for exchange rate determination does not
imply that order ow is the underlying cause of exchange rate
movements. Order ow is a proximate cause. The underlying cause
is information. How, specically, can one identify the information
that determines order ow? The notion of order ow as an intermediate link between information and price suggests several strategies
for answering this question, which I touch on now and address further in later chapters (particularly in chapters 7 and 9; readers may
nd a quick look at gure 7.1 helpful at this juncture).
18
Chapter 1
1:4
20
2.1
Chapter 2
Background
To many macroeconomists, the idea that order ow conveys incremental information relevant to exchange rates is controversial. In
traditional models, macroeconomic news is announced publicly, and
can therefore be impounded in price directly, without any role for
order ow.1 In light of this common belief, let me provide a bit more
background before examining evidence that order ow does indeed
play an information role.
As noted in chapter 1, models of exchange rate determination
within the asset approach take the form:
DPt f i; m; z et ;
where DPt is the change in the nominal exchange rate over the
period, typically one month. The driving variables in the function
f i; m; z include current and past values of home and foreign nominal interest rates i, money supplies m, and other macro determinants
(e.g., home and foreign real output), denoted here by z.
Now consider the possibility of private information. It is difcult
to imagine circumstances in which agents would have private information about interest rates. Perhaps somebody had an enlightening
conversation with the chairman of the Federal Reserve Board (Fed)
that morning. Doubtful. Maybe somebody has inside information
about the next Fed vote regarding monetary policy. Again, doubtful.2 The natural presumption is that all agents have the same information about currentand futureinterest rates. How about
private information on money supplies, or real output? For these
variables, too, it is natural to presume that agents are symmetrically informed. When money supply or real-output data are publicly
announced, all agents learn new information at the same time. This is
not a recipe for speculative activity based on information advantage.
With a slight shift in perspective, however, an information role for
order ow emerges. This shift in perspective is perfectly consistent
with the ideas of the last paragraph: even if exchange rate determination is based wholly on public information, this is not sufcient
to rule out an information role for order ow. To understand why,
recognize that there are in fact two crucial assumptions in these
macro-asset models that disconnect order ow from price. These two
assumptions are as follows:
21
This fact has important implications for the role that order ow plays
in mapping information to price.
Relaxing the all-agents-know-the-mapping assumption is not, however, the only way to restore a role for order ow. There are many
types of information that do not conform to the rst of the two
macro-asset model assumptionsthat all information relevant for
exchange rates is publicly known. Section 2.3 reviews these types of
information. In anticipation of that material, I offer a recent quotation from Rubinstein (2000, 17) that presages some of these information types: ``Perhaps the most important missing generalization in
almost all work on asset prices thus far has been uncertainty about
the demand curves (via uncertainty about endowments or preferences) of other investors. This injects a form of endogenous
uncertainty into the economy that may be on a par with exogenous
uncertainty about fundamentals.'' Before reviewing these informa-
22
Chapter 2
One methodology used to show that order ow is informative focuses on order ow's price effects and their persistence. It is common in the literature to distinguish between order ow that has
transitory effects on price and order ow that has permanent effects
on price. When order ow has transitory effects on pricesometimes
called ``indigestion'' or ``inventory'' effectsthese effects are often
referred to as pricing errors. When order ow has permanent effects
on price, however, these effects are taken to reect underlying fundamental information. (French and Roll 1986 use this identication
scheme, for example, in their celebrated paper on information arrival
and stock return volatility.)
In empirical microstructure, the standard way to implement this
idea is to estimate vector auto-regression models (VAR) and test
whether innovations in order ow have long-run effects on price
(Hasbrouck 1991a, b). When applied to data from major FX markets,
one nds that order ow innovations do indeed have long-run
effects on price, indicating that they convey bona de information.
Examples of ndings along these lines include Evans 2001 and Payne
1999.
23
A second method for testing whether order ow effects are persistent uses time-aggregated order ow to explain price movements in
FX markets. That is, rather than asking whether a single trade has an
impact on price, this asks whether trades aggregated over time (say a
day) have an impact on price. The idea is that if single trades have
only eeting effects on price, then order ow aggregated over the
day will not be closely related to daily price movements. When applied to the FX market, one nds that daily order ow does remain
strongly positively related to daily price changes. Examples of ndings along these lines include Evans and Lyons 1999 and Rime 2000.4
Methodology 2:
24
Chapter 2
25
26
Chapter 2
customers' orders, and they can base their speculative trades on this
information (see, e.g., Yao 1998b).
Other authors report results from discussions with dealers that are
similar, though these results are less formal than the above-noted
surveys. For example, Goodhart (1988, 456) writes, ``A further
source of informational advantage to the traders is their access to,
and trained interpretation of, the information contained in the order
ow.'' Similarly, based on interviews with nine FX dealers in London, Heere (1999) reports that the dealers emphasize the importance
of asymmetric information. The dealers she interviews state that information asymmetry is based on both order ows and the identities
of the institutions behind those order ows.
2.3
27
28
Chapter 2
who believe that private information does not exist in the FX market
typically have in mind only the rst of the two typesprivate information about the payoff, V (which in the FX market translates to
private information about future monetary fundamentals like interest differentials). Highlighting the second of the two information types
broadens that perspective. Third, previous literature tends to neglect
this category of private information. Information-theoretic models
of trading are specied with private information about terminal
payoffs. Empirical models follow suit. But this makes interpretation
of empirical results difcult: should one interpret evidence of private information as reecting the rst type or the second type? The
answer is not clear.
A Comment on the Term ``Fundamentals''
The term fundamental means different things to different people.
For example, one might be tempted to consider the second of my
two private-information types as nonfundamental. The quote from
Rubinstein (2000) that closed section 2.1 is suggestive of this narrower denition of fundamentals. In that quote, he distinguishes
uncertainty about fundamentals (i.e., payoffs) from uncertainty
about agents' preferences and endowments. But all of these factors
are fundamental to asset pricing. My choice to put the two broad
types of private information on equal footing recognizes the joint,
complementary nature of these two categories of fundamentals. The
issue is more than semantic; it affects the way we frame our thinking
about price determination.
My use of the term ``fundamental'' to refer to information of both
types is not so broad that it is no longer meaningful. The examples of
private information above are all bona de determinants of price in
optimizing, well-specied models. None of the examples presented
here require ``bubbles,'' ``greater fool'' behavior, or irrationality.10
2.4
29
EV
;
1d
2:1
30
Chapter 2
1. Payoff information
2. Discount-rate informationinventory effects
3. Discount-rate informationportfolio balance effects
For a stock, payoff information refers to information about future
dividendsthe numerator EV in our dividend discount model. For
a bond, payoffs take the form of coupons and principal (which are
publicly known as long as the bond is default free). For foreign exchange, payoffs include future short-term interest differentials (foreign
minus domestic; see section 6.1 for more detail). These represent the
net cash ows that accrue to holders of money market instruments
denominated in foreign exchangeakin to the dividends that accrue
to holders of a stock. (FX speculators who buy foreign exchange do
not hold actual currency, which bears no interest, but instead invest
their holdings in short-term, interest-bearing instruments.) We will
see that private information about payoffs is the basis for a class of
microstructure models known as information models (reviewed in
chapter 4).
Let me provide examples of how order ow, per se, might convey
private information about payoffs. The simplest examplethough
not so common in the major FX marketsis information about
future interest rates conveyed in the orders of a central bank (intervention). A second example likely to operate on a more regular basis
is information about people's expectations of future interest differentials (as noted in chapter 1).11 To understand this example, recognize that in reality, people do not all share the same EV. Instead,
each of us has our own expectation about the direction of future interest rates, based on the millions of bits of information we use to
form this view. This can be described by expressing the numerator as
EV j Wi , where Wi denotes the information that market participant i
uses to form expectations. Because participant i's orders depend on
EV j Wi , observing his or her orders conveys information about that
expectation. Thus, order ow serves as a proxy for people's expectations about future payoffs, and the information embedded therein.
These orders are the backed-by-money expectational votes that the
market ``counts'' when determining price.12
Turning to discount-rate information, microstructure theory emphasizes two distinct causes of time variation in discount rates.13
Both causes involve changing risk premia and rely on order ow to
31
play the central role. The rst of these causes is inventory effects.
(These arise in the class of microstructure models known as inventory models; see chapters 4 and 5 for details.) The idea here is that
risk-averse dealers will require compensation for absorbing transitory mismatches in supply and demand over time. The larger the
mismatch, the greater the risk the dealer must assume and the
greater the compensation the dealer requires. Suppose, for example,
that the mismatch is such that the dealer needs to absorb market sell
orders (i.e., the dealer needs to buy). The dealer may be willing to
absorb a small amount at only a slightly lowered price, but he would
require a signicantly lowered price to absorb a large amount.
Dealers thus earn a transitory risk premium for providing liquidity.
These effects on price last only as long, on average, as the mismatches in market supply and demand. Once the supply-demand
mismatch is remedied, the dealer no longer holds a position (inventory), so the effect on price dissipatesthe risk is diversiable. (In
terms of equation 2.1, the inventory effect would alter the discount
rate d that establishes p0 , but not the discount rate that later establishes p1 .) This type of order ow effect on price is what people have
in mind when they assert that ``microstructure effects zzle quickly.''
To summarize, these effects arise because risk is not perfectly and
instantaneously spread throughout the whole market; instead, dealers
bear disproportionate risk in the short run, and this affects price in
the short run.14
The second cause of time variation in discount ratesthe third of
our three information categories aboveis what macroeconomists
call portfolio balance effects. To distinguish these effects from inventory effects, the idea in this case is that even after risky positions are
spread through the economy as a whole, order ow's effect on price
will not disappear completely. (In terms of equation 2.1, the discount
rates that establish both p0 and p1 are affected. With an innite
number of periods, all discount rates will in general be affected.) In
other words, the risk that drives the portfolio balance effect is undiversiable (unlike the risk that drives the inventory effect). Of course,
to distinguish this from the rst of our information typesinformation about payoffsit must be shown that order ow is not conveying information about EV.
Let me offer two types of FX order ow that are unrelated to
EV, but may be large enough to have persistent portfolio balance
32
Chapter 2
33
Figure 2.1
Supply curves with only transitory inventory effects. The dotted region represents the
transitory inventory effects. The effective spread faced by a customer for a 10-unit
order is the difference in price along the short-run net supply curve S SR between 10
and 10. If a customer wants to buy 10 British pounds from the dealeran order of
10then he must pay the higher dollar price. If the customer wants to sell 10 pounds
to the dealeran order of 10then he will receive the lower dollar price. Over the
longer run, however, the dealer unloads his position on the rest of the market at a price
that does not include the transitory inventory effects. The market's net supply is perfectly elastic, by assumption, which corresponds to a longer-run supply curve S LR
slope of zero. The linear relationship shown along S SR is a special case, which I adopt
for simplicity.
34
Chapter 2
Figure 2.2
Supply curves with inventory and portfolio balance effects. The light-gray region represents the transitory inventory effects. The darker gray region represents persistent
portfolio balance effects. Due to inventory effects, the short-run price impact of an incoming order is larger than the long-run impact. But the long-run impact is nonzero,
due to imperfect substitutability; that is, the long-run net supply curve S LR now slopes
upward. The linear relationships shown are a special case, which I adopt for simplicity.
35
Figure 2.3
Supply curves when order ow conveys information about payoffs and discount rates.
The light-gray region represents the transitory inventory effects. The dark-gray region
represents persistent payoff-information effects. The medium-gray region represents
persistent portfolio balance effects. The gure therefore reects all three of the infor
mation types that arise in microstructure theory. The long-run supply curve S LR
LR
reects the long-run effects from portfolio balance (S ), plus an additional long-run
effect due to the payoff information conveyed by order ow. The linear relationships
shown are a special case, which I adopt for simplicity.
in doing the trade initially with the customer. The dealer, knowing
this cost of laying off his inventory has increased, will pass this on to
the customer in his initial quotes.
Now I will allow order ow to convey information about expected
future payoffs. Like in the case of portfolio balance effects, order ow
effects on price from this channel will persist (see, e.g., French and
Roll 1986; Hasbrouck 1991a, b). Mapped into the market supply
curve, this channel adds additional slope to the long-run schedule
shown in gure 2.2. Figure 2.3 provides an illustration of these longrun supply curves. Note that the short-run supply curve is more
steeply sloped than either of the two long-run curves.
In gure 2.3 there is now a new long-run supply curve, SLR . This
new long-run supply curve reects both the long-run portfolio balance effects S LR , as in gure 2.2, plus an additional long-run effect
due to the payoff information conveyed by order ow.
In later chapters, I address the slopes of these net supply curves
empirically. At this stage, it is worth bearing one point in mind:
order ows in the FX market are enormous relative to other asset
markets. In the gures, this corresponds to being far to the left or far
to the right of the order-ow-equals-zero point. Thus, even if the
slopes of these supply curves are nearly zero, large order ow can
still produce substantial price impact.
36
Chapter 2
Concluding Thoughts
To conclude this chapter, it is worth stepping back to reect on an
important, overarching point. The microstructure tools applied in
this chapter are useful for addressing a rather deep question:
What is the nature of the information this market is processing?
By focusing attention on order ow, these tools help to characterize
which types of information are relevant, and how this information is
aggregated.
In terms of nancial markets' economic role, the aggregation of
dispersed information is of profound conceptual importance. Nobel
laureate Friedrich Hayek (1945, 519) provides an early and powerful
articulation of this point. He writes:
The ``data'' from which the economic calculus starts are never for the whole
society ``given'' to a single mind which could work out the implications, and
can never be so given. The peculiar character of the problem of rational economic order is determined precisely by the fact that the knowledge of the
circumstances of which we must make use never exists in concentrated or
integrated form, but solely as dispersed bits of incomplete and frequently
contradictory knowledge which all the separate individuals possess. The
economic problem of society is thus . . . a problem of the utilization of
knowledge not given to anyone in its totality.
Relative to traditional exchange rate approaches, the informationtheoretic perspective offered here is qualitatively different. As we
shall see in chapter 6 (where I survey macro exchange rate models),
exchange rate economics may warrant a richer information-theoretic
perspective.
38
Chapter 3
One should be more careful than I have been thus far when referring to ``the'' FX market. Many people understand this term to mean
spot markets in the major oating exchange rates, such as $/euro
and $/yen, the two largest spot markets. In its broadest sense,
though, the term includes markets other than spot and rates other
than the major oaters. FX markets other than spot include the
full array of derivative instruments (forwards, futures, options, and
swaps). Rates other than the major oaters include those in smaller
markets, such as emerging markets, and those in pegged regimes,
such as Western Europe before the euro. When people quote the
daily trading volume in FX at $1.5 trillion, that statistic applies to the
broadest denition of the market.1
Nevertheless, the essence of the FX market is the spot market. In
1998, the spot market accounted for 40 percent of total turnover
across all FX instrument categories ($600 billion out of $1.5 trillion).
Though this share has been trending downwardit was 59 percent
in the BIS survey of 1989the falling spot share is not due to lower
spot turnover in absolute terms; rather, the derivatives markets have
grown up around the spot market.
For the purposes of this book, however, a vital point must be
understood about the previous paragraph's market share gures: Of
the $900 billion of daily volume that is not from the spot market,
$734 billion of this is FX swaps,2 and FX swaps have no order ow
consequences in the FX market. To understand why, one rst needs to
know what these swaps are. An FX swap bundles two FX transactions that go in opposing directions. For example, I agree to buy
100 million euros today for dollars (spot), and at the same time I
agree to sell 100 million euros for dollars for settlement in one month
(forward). This example is called a spot-forward swap. (One can also
do forward-forward swaps, in which case the rst of the two transactions is a nearer dated forward transaction than the other.) Note
that the two orders in this example are of equal size, but opposite
sign, so the net order ow impact is zero. Readers familiar with
covered interest parity will recognize that this contract is a means of
locking in an interest differential, and market participants use them
for this purpose (whether hedging or speculating).3 The net demand
impact is therefore mainly on relative short-term interest rates, not
on the FX market. This point is borne out in the behavior of banks:
bankers tell me that when they design in-house models for forecasting exchange rates using order ow, they exclude FX-swap trans-
39
actions from their order ow measures. The bottom line is that the
spot market accounts for about $600 billion of $766 billion, or 78
percent, of the transaction activity that corresponds to the order ow
models of this book.
Nevertheless, 78 percent is not 100 percent, so these statistics still
highlight a tension in dening the scope of this book. On the one
hand, dening the FX market broadly to include derivative instruments is consistent with ofcial denitions like that of the BIS;
moreover, arbitrage relationships link these submarkets tightly, suggestive of one market rather than many. On the other hand, these
submarkets do not share the same market structure, particularly in
the case of futures, which are often traded in physical pits using faceto-face open outcry.
To avoid these difculties, henceforth I focus attention explicitly
on the spot market, in particular the major oating-rate spot markets. (Fixed-rate spot markets are much smaller in terms of trading
volume than oating-rate spot markets.) Unless otherwise noted, my
use of the term ``the FX market'' corresponds to spot markets like
$/euro and $/yen. Work thus far on FX microstructure is heavily
concentrated on spot markets; broadening the scope to derivatives
would bring us into uncharted terrain. I do not, however, completely
exclude work on the derivatives segmentthere are many notes and
references to these related areas.4
3.1
40
Chapter 3
41
The spot foreign exchange market is best described as a decentralized multiple-dealer market. (This is also true of forwards, options,
and swaps markets in major currencies worldwide.) There is no physical locationor exchangewhere dealers meet with customers, nor
is there a screen that consolidates all executable dealer quotes in the
market.7 In this way, it is quite different from most equity and futures
markets. In its structure, the spot FX market is perhaps most similar to
the U.S. government bond market (bond markets have only recently
attracted attention in the microstructure literature).8
Three characteristics in particular distinguish trading in FX from
that in other markets:
1. trading volume is enormous;
2. trades between dealers account for most of this volume;
3. trade transparency is low.
Volume in the spot $/euro market alone is about $150 billion per
day, dwarng that of any other single nancial instrument. Remarkably, interdealer trading currently accounts for roughly two-thirds
of this volume, a much higher share than in other multiple-dealer
markets (the remaining one-third is between dealers and nondealer
customers).9 Finally, the FX market has an uncommon information
structure. Specically, order ow in FX is not as transparent as in
other multiple-dealer markets: in most national marketswhether
equity or bondsby law, trades must be disclosed within minutes.
FX trades have no disclosure requirement, so trades in this market are not generally observable. From a theoretical perspective, this
feature is quite important because order ow can convey information
about fundamentals. If order ow is not generally observed, then the
trading process will be less informative and the information reected
in prices will be reduced.
Let me clarify the players in the spot foreign exchange market. In
addition to providing context, this will help to classify trades into
types depending on who the counterparties are. (The classication of
trades into types is relevant to the material in later chapters.) The
three main categories are
1. dealers
2. customers
3. brokers (strictly interdealer)
42
Chapter 3
43
at a price of 12. If these are the best prices the broker has received on
either side, then the broker will advertise a two-way price of 1012,
and will do so without identifying the dealers posting those prices. A
third dealer can choose to trade at one of those prices through the
broker. (If so, after the transaction the broker reveals the counterparty, and settlement occurs directly between the counterparties;
both pay the broker a small commission.) Thus, brokers are pure
matchmakersthey do not take positions of their own, they only
connect dealers that might not otherwise nd each other. In the parlance of the three basic market structures above, brokers are running
an interdealer auction market that operates concurrently with the
multiple-dealer market. In this way, brokers provide a degree of
centralization in an otherwise decentralized FX market.10
These three categories of market participants give rise to three
basic types of trades. We can illustrate these trade types using three
concentric rings, shown in gure 3.1.
The inner ring represents direct interdealer trading, the most liquid part of the market. In the $/euro market, current spreads in this
Figure 3.1
Three types of trades.
44
Chapter 3
inner ring are one to two basis points (one basis point equals one
one-hundredth of 1 percent) for $10 million trades (the standard size)
between large banks during active trading hours (the full London
trading day plus the morning hours in New York). Historically,
dealers have chosen direct trading for larger interdealer trades
(above $10 million). The second ring represents brokered interdealer
trading. The effective spread for a $10 million trade in this ring is
roughly 23 basis points during active trading, though this continues
to fall as brokers take market share away from direct dealing. I add
the word ``effective'' here because the insidethat is, the lowest
spread in the brokered part of the market can be less than 23 basis
points, but that inside spread may apply to trade sizes less than $10
million; any remainder must be executed at less attractive prices,
such that a $10 million trade will have price impact beyond the initial inside spread. The third ring represents customer-dealer trading.
Dealers tell me that current spreads for a $10 million trade are in the
37 basis point range for ``good'' customers. (``Good'' to most dealers
means high volume.)
Visually, gure 3.1 reects a common metaphor used for the foreign exchange market, namely that the market is like a pool of water,
with stones being thrown in the center, where the action is most intense. The stones are the customer orders. Direct interdealer trading
lies at the center. Stones landing in that center send ripple effects
through the brokered interdealer trading, and, ultimately, back to
the customers themselves. Why back to customers themselves? Because dealers tend not to hold positions for very long in this market,
as we shall see below. This metaphor also claries the typical order's
``life cycle.''11
One might ask why a dealer would use a broker if direct prices are
tighter (brokers also charge a commission). Part of the answer is that
smaller banks often do not have access to the tighter direct spreads
that large banks extend to one another. Large banks, too, have
incentives to use brokers. From the large bank perspective, providing
a broker with a limit order provides a wider advertisement of a
willingness to trade than bilateral direct quoting provides. (Keep in
mind that a large bank that provides a broker with a limit order to
buy, for example, is still buying at the bid price, which is below the
offer price. If a second, smaller bank hits that bid, it is the second
bank that sells at this lower price.) Another reason bankslarge and
small alikemay choose to trade via brokers is that they provide
pretrade anonymity (as noted above). In a direct interdealer trade,
45
the dealer providing the quote knows the identity of the other dealer.
(For more detail on incentives to use particular FX trading systems,
see Luca 2000.)
Features for Modeling
With this more complete picture of FX market institutions, let us now
consider other features of FX microstructure that inuence modeling
strategies. Among many cited in the literature, three in particular
deserve note:
Dealers Receive Information from Their Customer Orders
As Citibank's head of FX in Europe said, ``if you don't have access
to the end user, your view of the market will be severely limited''
(Financial Times, 29 April 1991). In a similar spirit, Goodhart (1988,
456) writes: ``A further source of informational advantage to the
traders is their access to, and trained interpretation of, the information contained in the order ow. . . . Each bank will also know what
their own customer enquiries and orders have been in the course of
the day, and will try to deduce from that the positions of others in
the market, and overall market developments as they unfold.'' Note
that banks have little information regarding the customer orders of
other banks. Consequently, insofar as this order ow information
helps forecast prices, it is private information (by the denition of
chapter 2).
Dealers Learn about Marketwide Order Flow Largely from
Brokered Interdealer Trades
Because dealers do not observe one another's customer orders, they
need to gather order ow information from interdealer trading. As
noted above, though, direct interdealer trading does not provide
order ow information to anyone other than the counterparties.
Brokered interdealer trading, on the other hand, does provide order
ow information beyond the counterparties. This is important: of the
three trade types (customer-dealer, direct interdealer, and brokered
interdealer), the brokered interdealer trades are the only order ow
information communicated to all dealers. The broker systems, which
are now electronic, typically communicate this information by indicating whether incoming market orders are executed at the bid or
offer side (indicated with the words ``given'' for a trade at the bid and
``paid'' for a trade at the offer) and by providing information on how
46
Chapter 3
the incoming market order has changed the quantity available on the
bid or offer side (information on the size of the order ow). Though
there is noise in this order ow measure, on a marketwide basis it is
the best measure that is available to dealers.12
Large Dealer Positions are Frequent and Nontrivial
They are a natural consequence of marketmaking in a fast-paced
market with tight spreads (less than 2 basis points in the interdealer
$/euro market).13 FX dealers manage these large positions intensively. The large bank dealer in the $/DM market that I tracked in
1992 (see Lyons 1995) nished his trading day with no net position
each of the ve days in the sample, despite trading over $1 billion
each day. Within the day, the half-life of the gap between his current
position and zero was only ten minutes (Lyons 1998). From the plot
of that dealer's net position in gure 3.2, the strong reversion toward
zero is readily apparent.14
Though the three features noted above are the most important
from a modeling strategy perspective, let me provide a bit more
perspective on what the life of a dealer in a major FX market is like.15
Figure 3.2
Dealer's net position (in $ millions) over one trading week. The vertical lines represent
the overnight periods over which this dealer was not trading. The horizontal distance
between those vertical lines is scaled by the number of transactions made by this
dealer each trading day.
47
48
Chapter 3
Table 3.1
Diagram of Position Sheet Structure
Trade date: 8/3
Value date: 8/5
Position
Position
rate
Trade
rate
Source
Time
1
2
1.4794
1.4797
r
r
8:30
1.4796
28
1.4795
10
1.4797
10
1.4797
10
1.4797
1.4797
1.4797
1.4791
1.4797
1.4797
Trade
0.5
1.4794
0.75
1.4790
1.4791
10
1.4797
1.4799
1.4805
1.4810
8:38
1.4808
The ``Position'' column accumulates the individual trades in the ``Trade'' column.
Quantities are in millions of dollars. A positive quantity in the Trade column corresponds to a purchase of dollars. A positive quantity in the Position column corresponds to a net long dollar position. The ``Trade Rate'' column records the exchange
rate for the trade, in deutschemarks per dollar. The ``Position Rate'' column records the
dealer's estimate of the average rate at which he acquired his position. The Position
and Position Rate are not calculated after every trade due to time constraints. The
``Source'' column reports whether the trade is direct over the Reuters Dealing 2000-1
system (r Reuters) or brokered (b Broker). All trades on this position sheet are
interdealer. First fourteen trades on Monday, August 3, 1992.
49
50
Chapter 3
dealer has no net position, and quotes bid and offer prices of 1.4750
and 1.4753 DM/$, respectively (quotes apply to a standardized
amount in this market, at the time $10 million). If the counterparty
chooses to sell $10 million at 1.4750, then the dealer is long $10
million after the transaction. If the market has not moved, and
another potential counterparty calls for a quote, this particular dealer
will typically shade the price to induce the counterparty to buy
relieving the dealer of his or her long position. For example, this
dealer would probably quote bid and offer prices to the next potential counterparty of 1.4749 and 1.4752 DM/$ (versus the original
1.4750 and 1.4753). Relative to the rst pair of quotes, the new quote
is attractive on the offer sidethe 1.4752but unattractive on the
bid side. If the caller goes for the attractive offer quote and buys, then
the dealer will have sold the $10 million position at 1.4752 DM/$.
The net result of both transactions is that the dealer cleared twothirds of the spread (two ticks) on two transactionsor one-third of
the spread on each transaction.
From the last line of table 3.2 we can see that, under this assumption, this dealer makes most all of his prot from the spread. Of the
$507,929 he made over the week, our estimate of the amount that
came from intermediation is $472,496. (If I had assumed that the
dealer makes half his spread from intermediation, then the prot
from intermediation would have been higher than his total prot,
Table 3.2
Summary of DM/$ Dealer's Trading and Prots
Transactions
Volume
(mil)
Prot:
Actual
Prot:
Spread
Monday
333
$1,403
$124,253
$ 95,101
Tuesday
301
$1,105
$ 39,273
$ 74,933
Wednesday
300
$1,157
$ 78,575
$ 78,447
Thursday
Friday
328
458
$1,338
$1,966
$ 67,316
$198,512
$ 90,717
$133,298
1,720
$6,969
$507,929
$472,496
Total
The ``Prot: Spread'' column reports the prot the dealer would have realized if he
had cleared one-third of his spread on every transaction. It is calculated as the dollar
volume times one-third the median spread he quoted in the sample (median spread
0.0003 DM/$), divided by the average DM/$ rate over the sample (1.475 DM/$)
from Monday, August 3, to Friday, August 7, 1992.
51
indicating that he suffered speculative losses.) This is broadly consistent with the idea that, in terms of speculative prots, this market
is a zero-sum game. However, the market need not be a zero-sum
game in terms of intermediation prots. In that case, customers in
this market are paying the dealers, on average, for the liquidity that
the dealers provide.19 Is that compensation inordinate? The data in
table 3.2 do not allow us to answer that question because these
trades are mostly interdealer trades. A hundred thousand dollars per
day is not a bad day's work, though, at least not where I come
from.20
3.2
52
Chapter 3
Table 3.3
Foreign Exchange Market Turnover
Category
April
1989
April
1992
April
1995
April
1998
Spot transactions1
350
400
520
600
240
590
420
820
670
1,190
900
1,500
Memorandum item:
Turnover at April 1998 exchange rates
600
800
1,030
1,500
53
54
Chapter 3
Table 3.4
Reported Foreign Exchange Market Turnover by Currency Pair
April 1998
April 1995
Percentage share
Percentage share
Total
amount
Spot
Outright
forwards
Foreign
exchange
swaps
Total
amount
Spot
Outright
forwards
Foreign
exchange
swaps
USD/DEM
USD/JPY
253.9
242.0
56
36
7
9
37
55
USD/DEM
USD/JPY
290.5
266.6
49
45
8
10
43
44
USD/othEMS
104.3
19
73
USD/othEMS
175.8
14
79
USD/GBP
77.6
33
60
USD/GBP
117.7
33
59
USD/CHF
60.5
37
55
USD/CHF
78.6
30
62
USD/FRF
60.0
17
74
USD/FRF
57.9
16
76
DEM/othEMS
38.2
74
17
USD/CAD
50.0
25
68
USD/CAD
38.2
32
11
57
USD/AUD
42.2
33
59
DEM/FRF
USD/AUD
34.4
28.7
86
31
4
7
9
63
DEM/othEMS
DEM/GBP
35.1
30.7
75
79
12
10
13
11
9
DEM/JPY
24.0
79
12
DEM/JPY
24.2
77
14
DEM/GBP
21.3
84
10
DEM/CHF
18.4
85
DEM/CHF
18.4
86
USD/XEU
16.6
89
USD/XEU
17.9
11
82
USD/SGD
17.2
71
27
1,136.9
43
48
1,441.5
40
51
USD U.S. dollar, DEM Deutsche mark, JPY Japanese yen, othEMS other EMS (European Monetary System) currencies, GBP British
pound, CHF Swiss franc, FRF French franc, CAD Canadian dollar, AUD Australian dollar, XEU European currency unit (a basket
currency that includes all European Union members), and SGD Singapore dollar.
Source: BIS, 1999a, table B-4. Daily averages in billions of U.S. dollars and percentage shares.
55
are strictly interdealer, though, so these trades belong in the interdealer category. It is difcult to know how much this biases the
survey-measured interdealer share downward; my adjustment from
60 percent to two-thirds is an educated guesstimate.
Section 7 of the BIS (1999a) report provides some information on
the share of interdealer trading that is brokered and the degree to
which these brokered trades are handled by electronic brokers,
rather than the traditional voice-based brokers.26 Because this section
is not linked to specic tables, one needs to be cautious in interpreting the data. For example, one needs to take care to distinguish statistics that apply to total FX turnover, as opposed to spot turnover.
(This is important throughout the BIS report.) One particularly useful sentence in that section is the following: ``Electronic brokers
now handle almost one quarter of total spot transactions in the UK
market.''27 That represents nearly one-half of all interdealer spot
transactions (because, per above, the survey nds that interdealer
transactions are roughly 60 percent of total spot transactions). To
arrive at a more complete picture of the share and type of brokered
tradingelectronic versus voice-basedone needs to piece together
data from the individual central bank reports.
3.3
56
Chapter 3
ow information is the most relevant because it is the main communicator of shifts in asset demand. When interpreting this information
as shifts in asset demand, however, one needs to be precise. One
cannot infer the sign of a shift in demand from the information that,
say, ten units just traded. One needs to know whether the trade
represents buying or selling pressure. The trade needs to be signed
it needs to be converted from trading volume to order ow.
Actual markets differ radically in terms of order ow transparency. In equity markets, the transparency regime is typically imposed (e.g., regimes are imposed on the London Stock Exchange, the
NYSE, and NASDAQ). On the London Stock Exchange, for example,
the price and size of smaller trades must be disclosed within three
minutes, whereas disclosure of the largest trades can be delayed up
to ve business days. FX markets, in contrast, have no disclosure
requirements. For this reason, FX is particularly interesting because
its degree of transparency has arisen without regulatory inuence. 29
With no disclosure requirements, it is perhaps not surprising that
most FX trades do not generate public order ow information. But,
as described earlier in this chapter, some trades do generate widely
available order ow information. Interestingly, these tradesthe
brokered interdealer tradesproduce a level of transparency that
arises as a by-product of dealer's selective use of this trading
method. The FX market is therefore not an example of purposeful
transparency regime design, as is true for most equity markets.
The only other nancial markets similar to FX in terms of low
transparency are other nonequity OTC markets. (OTC, or over-thecounter, simply means not traded on a centralized exchange.) These
include the U.S. bond markets and much of trading in derivatives.
With the advent of centralized electronic trading in these other markets, however, they are on the way to becoming more transparent
than the FX market.30
Now that we have a better sense from section 3.1 for how transparency arises in the FX market, we can examine the impact of
this transparency on price determination. In markets that are highly
transparent, all participants observe order ow, thereby affecting
expectationsand pricesrapidly and precisely. In opaque markets, order ow is not widely observed, so the information it conveys
may be impounded in price more slowly.31 The FX market is opaque
with respect to customer-dealer order ow. As noted, however,
interdealer FX transactions are not completely opaque. One of the
57
58
Chapter 3
59
60
Chapter 3
Figure 3.3
Microstructure effects question: Does trading process affect mapping?
61
Figure 3.4
Accelerationist view of order ow information. The solid line shows a hypothetical
price path for a stock under the assumption that price responds to a higher than
expected public earnings announcement at time t. The dotted line shows the price path
under the assumption that insider trading (buying) in advance of the announcement is
pushing price up.
tration. The solid line is the price path under the assumption that the
market responds to the (positive) public earnings announcement
only. The dotted line shows how the price path would look if, in
addition, the market were to respond to informative order ow
occurring prior to the public announcement. The difference in the
two paths is only temporary here because the announcement reveals
all the information contained in the prior order ow (and then some).
If, as an empirical matter, order ow were conveying only information that is on the verge of public announcement, then one would
be justied in treating its effects as temporary, in the sense portrayed
in gure 3.4. However, this is certainly not the case for the FX market. Order ow's important role in determining exchange rates
documented in later chaptersis virtually unrelated to macroeconomic news that arrives within the subsequent year. The tight relation
between order ow and exchange rates is not, therefore, simply the
result of short-run acceleration of public information ow. Over the
longer run, whether order ow conveys information about more
distant macro policies has yet to be determined. This is an active
topic of ongoing research, one that I return to in chapter 7.
I raise the notion of microstructure effects because depicting
the eld of microstructure in this limited way can affect research
62
Chapter 3
strategies. Let me provide an example that is embedded in the discussion above about analyzing crashes and collapses. In that discussion, I made the point that although the crash occurred across several
different market structure types, microstructure analysis was still
fruitful for specifying information problems that can lead to a crash.
More generally, people less familiar with microstructure are prone to
assert that microstructure cannot resolve any puzzle that (1) is common to markets with different structures or (2) is not common to
markets with the same structure. As an example of the former, it
might be argued that although (apparent) excess volatility is a property of both equity and FX markets, because the NYSE and FX markets have different structures, microstructure cannot help to resolve
the excess volatility puzzle. This reasoning, in my judgment, is too
oriented toward the institutions pole of microstructure. Effective use
of information models within microstructure may indeed help to resolve puzzles in the FX market, even if the same puzzles occur in
other, differently structured markets. Chapters 7 through 9 make this
case.
Theoretical Frameworks
64
Chapter 4
Figure 4.1
A bird's-eye view of microstructure models.
Theoretical Frameworks
65
66
Chapter 4
I should be clear from the outset that all four of the models I
present below qualify as information models. Information models
constitute one of two broad modeling approaches within microstructure theory. The other is inventory models. The purpose of information models is to explain permanent price adjustment toward a
changed expected future payoff (payoff information was dened in
chapter 2). Order ow is what induces this price adjustmentit
conveys information about these future payoffs. The focus of inventory models, on the other hand, is transitory price variation around a
xed expected future payoff (chapter two's inventory effects). Order
ow is central to inventory models as well, though in this case it
affects price by inuencing dealer inventories.4 Maintaining inventories in these models is costly because it exposes the dealer to risk;
the need to compensate dealers for these costs is what drives price
adjustment.
Though all four models I present are information models, two are
pure information models and two have both information-model and
inventory-model features. The common thread, the information component, is in my judgment integral to the link between microstructure
and exchange rate economics. Though both approaches are relevant,
if pure inventory models were all there were to the microstructure
approachthat is, transitory price variation due to changing dealer
inventoriesthen there would be little hope of resolving the big
exchange rate puzzles.5 Consider, for example, the puzzle of what
determines exchange rates at lower frequencies. Lower frequency
exchange rates, by their nature, are a function of persistent variation,
not transitory variation, so inventory effects alone are not sufcient
for resolving this puzzle.
4.1
Theoretical Frameworks
67
68
Chapter 4
consistency: the equilibrium price would reect everybody's information, but individuals are acting as though price is uninformative.
Neglecting the information in price this way would be patently irrational. By bringing the information role of prices to center stage, the
rational expectations model provides a valuable framework for analyzing price as an information aggregator.
Insights (2) and (3) are related. They are often called the two
``paradoxes'' of the rational expectations model. Insight (2) is a consequence of each individual's private signal being redundant when
price is fully revealing. The paradox arises when one recognizes that,
although the equilibrium price fully aggregates all private information, individual demands are conditioned wholly on that equilibrium
priceindividuals neglect their own private information. But private information cannot get into price if individuals are not using
their private information in determining their demands. In a partially revealing equilibrium, this paradox does not arise because individual demands are conditioned on price and private information.
The second paradox, associated with insight (3), is that in a fully
revealing equilibrium there is no incentive for individuals to acquire
their own private informationit would be reected in price before
a protable position could be opened. So if private information can
only be acquired at a cost (e.g., by investing in better research), then
nobody will acquire it, and there will be no private information
to aggregate. This paradox, too, does not arise in a partially revealing equilibrium because when one acquires private information, a
protable position can be opened before price can fully reect that
information.
The Model
The following Grossman-Stiglitz (1980) version of the rational
expectations auction model is widely used. Because it includes both
private information and noise in asset supply, its equilibrium only
partially reveals private information. The model has two traders,
both of whom are risk averse and nonstrategic (nonstrategic meaning that they act as perfect competitors and take market prices as
given). There is a single risky asset and a single trading period. 8
Within the single trading period, there are three events, shown in
gure 4.2.
The value of the risky asset's end-of-period payoff is denoted here
as V, a Normally distributed random variable with mean zero and
Theoretical Frameworks
69
Figure 4.2
Timing of rational expectations model.
4:1
This utility function has two convenient properties. First, the riskyasset demands that it implies do not depend on wealth, so realloca-
70
Chapter 4
Figure 4.3
Summary of rational expectations auction model.
tion of wealth in the trading process does not affect equilibrium. This
obviates the need to keep track of individuals' trading gains/losses.
Second, when coupled with the assumption that returns are Normally distributed, this exponential utility function produces a demand function for the risky asset that takes a simple linear form.
At the center of rational expectations models is the pricing rule,
which describes how the model's random variables determine equilibrium price. All traders know the pricing rule. (An implication
of knowing the rule is that the uninformed trader can use the rule,
together with the market price, to back out information about the
informed trader's signal.) In rational expectations equilibrium, the
pricing rule must meet two conditions: the rst is the ``rational
expectations'' part and the second is the ``equilibrium'' part:
Conditions for Rational Expectations Equilibrium
1. Expectations of the payoff V are consistent with the equilibrium
pricing rule.
2. Markets always clear, that is, excess demand equals zero for all
random variable realizations.
When solving for equilibrium below, I will show that the proposed
equilibrium conforms to these rational expectations conditions. (See
gure 4.3 for a summary of the model's key features.)
Solving for Equilibrium
We solve for equilibrium in this type of model ``by construction,''
that is, by proposing a pricing rule and then verifying that it meets
Theoretical Frameworks
71
the two conditions above. Our assumptions about utility and Normal
distributions give us a basis for proposing a linear pricing rule. As
usual, though, it is not a priori clear what the content of that linear
rule should be (or that an equilibrium rule need even be linear). The
initial conjecture is a matter of judgment and experience. The following conjectured rule does in the end meet the two equilibrium
conditions, but this is far from obvious at this stage:
P aS bX
4:2
The key components are the realized signal S and the realized riskyasset supply X. These are natural choices for the proposed rule: they
are the random variables on which asset demands are based. The
remaining random variable V is not a candidate because the payoff V
is not observable at the time of trading. Values for the constants a
and b are determined at the end of the solution process in a manner
that makes them consistent with optimizing behavior of both traders.
There are three additional steps to solving for equilibrium. First,
we need expressions for each trader's expectation of the payoff V;
these must be consistent with the equilibrium pricing rule. Second,
based on these expectations of V from step one, we need expressions
for each trader's risky-asset demand. Finally, we use those demands
to nd a market-clearing price that matches the proposed pricing
rule in equation (4.2). Then we will have our rational expectations
equilibrium, because it conforms to equilibrium condition (2). In that
equilibrium, expectations are formed using the correct pricing rule,
conforming to condition (1).
Expectations
Expressions for traders' expectations are not difcult to produce in
this setting. This is particularly true in the case of the informed
trader because the informed trader learns only from his own signal
he knows the other trader is uninformed. In the appendix to this
chapter, I show why we can write the informed trader's posterior
beliefs about the payoff V conditional on his signal S as Normally
distributed with
sS2
1
S and VarV j S
:
EV j S
sS2 sV2
sS2 sV2
These expressions make intuitive sense. As sS2 the variance of the
signal S about Vgoes to innity (a weaker signal), EV j S goes to
72
Chapter 4
Theoretical Frameworks
73
EV j S P
VarV j S
EV j P; a; b P
:
D
VarV j P; a; b
4:3
Note the information role that price plays in the demand of the
uninformed trader (it enters in the conditional expectation and conditional variance).
Inserting the values above for EV j S and VarV j S into this expression for D I and D U yields the following:
D I sS2 S sS2 sV2 P
D U sZ2 Z sZ2 sV2 P:
4:4
Market-Clearing Price
Market-clearing price is determined by equating demand with supply so that excess demand is zero:
D I D U X:
Inserting our expressions from equation (4.4) for D I and D U in this
market-clearing condition yields a price of
P aS bX;
where
4:5
74
Chapter 4
sZ2 sS2
a
sZ2 sS2 2sV2
1
:
b
sZ2 1 a1 sS2 2sV2
(Recall that sZ2 was dened above as sS2 2b=a 2 sX2 .) These values
for a and b insure that excess demand equals zero for all randomvariable realizations, which fullls condition (2) above for rational
expectations equilibrium. Further, we imposed in our derivation of
these coefcient values that the pricing rule used to form expectations is the actual rule used to determine price. This fullls equilibrium condition (1) above. Thus, we have veried what we set out to
verify: that the conjectured pricing rule in equation (4.2) describes a
rational expectations equilibrium.
This equilibrium is partially revealing, a fact evident from the
uninformed trader's expectation. Specically, the uninformed trader
does not know as much in equilibrium as the informed trader, as
shown by the distributions of posterior expectations. Recall that the
variance of the informed trader's posterior expectation is
1
;
VarV j S
sS2 sV2
and the variance of the uninformed trader's posterior expectation is
1
:
VarV j P; a; b
sZ2 sV2
The only difference is the replacement of sS2 with sZ2 , where sZ2 has a
value of sS2 2b=a 2 sX2 . Because 2b=a 2 sX2 must be positive, sZ2 must
be larger than sS2 , so the variance of the uninformed trader's posterior expectation is larger.
The Implicit Auctioneer
I began this chapter by framing the two auction-market models
rational expectations and Kyleas the difference between an implicit auctioneer and an explicit auctioneer. Yet the model description above makes no reference to an implicit auctioneer, so let me
clarify. Strictly speaking, the rational expectations model does not
require an auctioneer, which is why the specication above contains
no reference to one. Nevertheless, the ction of an implicit, Walra-
Theoretical Frameworks
75
76
Chapter 4
The Kyle (1985) model and the rational expectations model are close
cousins. Both have an auction market structure, and at the heart of
both is an expectations-consistent pricing rule. The key conceptual
difference is that the Kyle model includes an explicit auctioneer
rather than an implicit one. This changes the nature of the pricing
rule because the act of price setting is now assigned to a player
within the model. Introducing an explicit auctioneer also introduces
Theoretical Frameworks
77
78
Chapter 4
Figure 4.4
Two stages of information processing.
Order ow communicates information about fundamentals because it contains the trades of those who analyze/observe fundamentals. Naturally, though, these informative trades are mixed
with uninformative trades, making the task of ``vote counting'' more
complex than the term might suggest. Note too that in the Kyle
model the marketmaker can only learn about fundamentals from
order ow. This is clearly too strong. This complete dependence on
learning from order ow arises in the model because the information
being learned is not public information (by public information I
mean information that is shared by everyone, and whose implication
for the exchange rate is agreed upon by everyone).16 In the case of
public information, marketmakers obviously do not need to learn
from order ow. Though some information relevant to FX is public,
much is not, so learning from order ow is important.
Insight (2) introduces strategic behavior that is not present in the
rational expectations model. There is room for informed traders to be
strategic because marketmakers cannot separate informative and
uninformative orders. The strategic behavior of the informed traders
takes the form of camouaging their trades using the uninformed
order ow. This hides their information from the marketmaker,
thereby reducing the degree to which price moves against them (e.g.,
price rises less as a result of their trying to buy).
Insight (3)that there is a deep relation between liquidity and
market efciencyis a fascinating message. The basic idea is that in
efcient markets there are forces pushing to keep liquidity from
moving predictably over time. Although dened inconsistently in
the literature, liquidity refers here to an order's price impact
what Kyle (and practitioners) calls depth. To understand the stableliquidity insight, let us suppose that liquidity is not constant, and
that we can predict how it will change. A simple example shows that
Theoretical Frameworks
79
Figure 4.5
Timing of Kyle Model.
80
Chapter 4
4:6
Price depends on the sum because the marketmaker does not observe
D I and D U individually. The D U component of that sum is exogenous in this simple version of the model, which simplies inference.
The complication comes from the D I component, which depends on
the trading strategy of the informed trader.
An important feature of the Kyle model is that the informed trader
trades strategically, meaning that he takes into account the effect of
his orders on price. This involves conditioning on the behavior of
both other player typesuninformed traders, whose trades are exogenous, and the marketmaker. Recall that in the rational expectations model the informed trader does not trade strategically. In that
model the demand of the informed trader, D I in equation (4.3), takes
the market price P as given, and thus does not consider the effect that
D I has on equilibrium price. Because the informed trader in the Kyle
model is risk neutral (recall the discussion in the introduction to this
chapter), he will choose a trading strategy that maximizes his expected prot. That is, he chooses a demand D I that maximizes the
following:
ED I V P j V ;
4:7
Theoretical Frameworks
81
Figure 4.6
Summary of Kyle Auction Model.
for each possible realization of V. The interaction between the marketmaker's problem and the informed trader's problem is clear from
these last two equations. The marketmaker's pricing rule depends on
the contribution of D I to order ow, but the informed trader's choice
of D I depends on the impact orders have on the marketmaker's price
P. In equilibrium, this circularity is resolved. (See gure 4.6 for a
summary of the model's key features.)
The pricing and trading rules that produce equilibrium convey the
model's essential lessons. The equilibrium analyzed by Kyle is the
unique linear equilibrium, with a marketmaker pricing rule
P lD I D U ;
4:8
4:9
with strictly positive parameters l and b that take the following form
(not derived here):
l 12 sV2 =sU2 1=2
b sU2 =sV2 1=2 :
4:10
Notice that the pricing and trading rules depend on the same
two parametersthe variance of the uninformed order sU2 and the
variance of the payoff sV2 . This is a natural consequence of being determined jointly and is analogous to the consistency criterion that
82
Chapter 4
4:11
Theoretical Frameworks
83
84
Chapter 4
Theoretical Frameworks
85
Discussion
The Kyle (1985) model has been extended in many directions (e.g.,
allowing the informed trader to be risk averse, allowing uninformed
traders to be strategic, and allowing multiple informed traders).21 It
is designed to capture the strategic trading of traders with superior
information, and it does that very well. Naturally, though, there are
aspects of markets about which it has less to say. For analyzing the
FX market (and most other asset markets for that matter), three features of the Kyle model limit its applicability.
No Marketmaker Risk-Aversion
The Kyle model is a pure information model. It has none of the features that can produce price effects from marketmaker inventory or
imperfect substitutability (per chapter 2).22 Because the marketmaker
is risk neutral, he always sets price at his conditional expectation of
V (i.e., this story is purely about expected future payoffs). Not only
does this preclude inventory or portfolio balance effects on price, it
also precludes any interaction between information effects and these
other effects. Empirically, there is evidence that FX dealers manage
inventory intensively. One consequence is that this can alter the
composition of order ow: if a greater share of order ow is unrelated to expectations of Vdue to intensive inventory management
then the order ow's signal-to-noise ratio is lowered.
No Spread
Because all orders in the batch auction are executed at the single
auction-clearing price, the Kyle model does not generate a bid-ask
spread. The major FX markets are dealership markets, which do
generate spreads, so the Kyle model is not directly useful for analyzing those spreads. One way researchers have used the model for
spread analysis is by calculating an ``implicit'' spread (e.g., Madhavan 1996). The implicit spread is calculated from the marginal price
impact of a single-unit trade, captured in the model by the parameter
l (equation 4.8). If the one-way price impact is l, then the roundtrip
price impactthe implicit spreadcan be measured as 2l. This estimate raises its own issues, however, because the equilibrium value
of l is not derived under the possibility that additional trades can be
executed.
86
Chapter 4
No Individual Trades
Another consequence of the batch auction format of this model is
that the impact of individual orders cannot be analyzed. This is
unfortunate because the trade data available for major FX markets
include individual orders. One might apply the insights of the Kyle
model by attempting to ``batch'' the individual orders by aggregating
over time. However, the economics of aggregating orders over time
is potentially different from the batching of orders at a point in time.
4.3
The Kyle model and the sequential-trade model share many features, primarily involving the specication of dealers. First, both
models include a single optimizing dealer whose prices are conditioned on information available specically to him or her.23 Second,
in both models the dealer is risk-neutral. Third, in both models the
dealer learns from order ow and has no other source of fundamental information.
The Kyle and sequential-trade models also have several important
differences that primarily involve the trading protocol. Unlike the
auction market of the Kyle model, the sequential-trade model describes a dealership market. All trades in a pure dealership market
have a dealer on one side of the transaction. In the sequential-trade
model, this takes the form of individual traders who, sequentially,
are selected from a ``pool'' and given a chance to trade at the dealer's
posted bid and offer. This protocol implies three important differences from the Kyle model. First, an explicit bid-offer spread arises in
the sequential-trade model, as opposed to the single market-clearing
price of the Kyle model. This is an attractive feature, particularly for
empirical implementation, because the spread is readily measured in
most markets. Second, the information content of individual orders
can be analyzed in a way not possible with the Kyle model because
in the Kyle model, all orders clear in a single batch. Third, and not
so attractive, the process of selecting traders from a pool in the
sequential-trade model is random. Random selection means that informed traders have no ability to adjust their trading intensity the
way the informed trader does in the Kyle model. Indeed, incorporation of strategic trading was an important advantage of the Kyle
model.
Theoretical Frameworks
87
Insights
The sequential-trade model presented below generates many insights. Relative to the single-auction version of the Kyle model
above, three of the most important include:24
1. Spreads arise even with competitive risk-neutral dealers
2. Price discovery is a gradual process by which price adjusts over
time to impound all private information (i.e., to become strong-form
efcient)
3. Dealers learn about private information from the sequential
arrival of distinct orders.
Insight (1) is truly fundamental. The equilibrium spread in this
model is such that when the dealer happens to trade with an informed trader he loses money (as in the Kyle model, here the informed trader knows the true value exactly). To prevent overall
losses, the dealer must offset these losses with gains from trading
with uninformed traders. The equilibrium spread balances these
losses and gains exactly so that expected prot is zero. Information
alone is thus sufcient to induce spreads; it is not necessary that the
dealer be risk-averse, face other dealing costs, or have monopoly
power in order to generate positive spreads.
The term ``price discovery'' used in insight (2) is not common outside microstructure; this model is a nice illustration of its meaning.
(The Kyle model in its multiple-auction version also generates this
insight.) In macro exchange rate models, it is traditional to use the
term ``price determination.'' All information is public in these models
so price is not really discoveredit is determined by a consensus
linear combination of fundamentals. In contrast, when a dealer is
trading with individuals with private information, the task is indeed
one of discoverydiscovery of the private information. These models capture the process by which this private information is embedded in price. (Recall that strong-form efciency means that all
information, including private information, is embedded in price.)
Dealers' learning about private information from individual
ordersinsight (3)is at the center of this model. Though the Kyle
auction model also focused on learning from order ow, it could
not address the link between learning and individual orders. In most
nancial markets, this individual-order process is much closer to
88
Chapter 4
reality than the batch trading described in the Kyle model. If a trader
wants to sell, the reason could be that the trader knows something
negative that the dealer does not. However, it could also be that the
trader is selling for reasons unrelated to fundamentals (such as when
the trader is a pension fund selling to meet pension obligations). The
dealer cannot identify which is the case for any individual trade. But
if a preponderance of sales occurs over time, the dealer adjusts his or
her beliefs and prices downwardit is unlikely so many sales could
occur for non-fundamental reasons. In this way the dealer's price
gradually embeds the private information in order ow.
The Model
The following simple version of the Glosten and Milgrom (1985)
model islike the Kyle modela workhorse within the microstructure literature. The model has three familiar trader types: riskneutral informed traders, a risk-neutral dealer, and uninformed
traders. There is a single risky asset, whose terminal payoff is either
high V H or low V L . All informed traders initially observe whether
the terminal payoff is high or low. Initially, the dealer knows only
the unconditional probability of V H and V L , which we denote as p
and 1 p, respectively.
The model organizes trading as a sequence of bilateral trading
opportunities. Each trading opportunity involves a single potential
trader selected at random from an unchanging pool of potential
traders. The dealer knows that q percent of the traders in the pool are
informed, and 1 q percent are uninformed. The dealer then presents the selected trader with bid and offer prices that are good for
a single transaction of one unit. The selected trader can buy at
the offer, sell at the bid, or choose not to trade (gure 4.7 presents
the model's time line). For simplicity, I will assume that when an
uninformed trader is selected, the probability of buying and selling
are equal at 0.5 (arising, for example, from idiosyncratic hedging
demands).
Figure 4.7
Timing of a single trade in sequential-trade model.
Theoretical Frameworks
89
This trading protocol is more elaborate than that for the previous
two models. The sequential-trade model's more explicit dealership setting requires more structure (in much the same way that the
Kyle model's explicit auctioneer required more structure than the
rational expectations model). This sequential protocol is what allows
us to analyze trades individually. It also prevents the informed
traders from trading aggressively when prices do not yet reect all
information.
The dealer's pricing rule is the essence of the model. Two key features pin it downrisk neutrality and zero prots. (The zero prot
condition can be supported by incipient entry of competing dealers,
as in the Kyle model.) These features mean the dealer will provide
bid and offer prices to the next trader that conform to
Bid EV j next trader sells
Offer EV j next trader buys:
4:12
Figure 4.8
Summary of sequential-trade model.
90
Chapter 4
Figure 4.9
Probability of different trade types: Sequential-trade model. There are eight possible
trade types. The probability of each occurring appears in the far right column (the sum
of the eight probabilities equals 1). Each of these probabilities has three components.
First, nature produces either a high payoff value V H or a low payoff value V L , with
probabilities p and 1 p respectively. Then a trader is selected from a pool who is
either informed or uninformed, with probabilities q and 1 q respectively. Informed
traders know whether the realized value is V H or V L . Finally, the selected trader
chooses to buy or sell. If the selected trader is uninformed he buys with probability 12
and sells with probability 12. If the selected trader is informed he buys with probability
1 if payoff value is high and sells with probability 1 if payoff value is low.
ture to make this easy. There are eight possible trade types, which
are the product of two different states of the world, two different
trader types, and two different transaction directions 2 2 2. The
far right column shows the probability of each trade type occurring.
Because these eight types span all possibilities, the sum of the eight
probabilities must equal one. Each of these probabilities has three
components. First, nature produces either a high payoff value V H or
a low payoff value V L , with probabilities p and 1 p, respectively.
Then a trader is selected from the pool who is either informed or
uninformed, with probabilities q and 1 q, respectively. Informed
traders know whether the realized value is V H or V L . Finally, the
Theoretical Frameworks
91
selected trader chooses to buy or sell. If the selected trader is uninformed he buys with probability 12 and sells with probability 12 (one
can think of the uninformed in this model as trading for idiosyncratic
hedging purposes). If the selected trader is informed he buys with
probability 1 if the realized value is high and sells with probability 1
if the realized value is low.
Setting Bid and Offer Prices
Let us walk through an example of how the dealer would set the
offer price shown in equation (4.12). We can expand that equation to
Offer EV j buy V L ProbfV L j buygV H ProbfV H j buyg;
4:13
where ProbfV L j buyg denotes the probability that V V L conditional on the next trader choosing to buy. The dealer knows the values of V L and V H ; he just does not know which nature has selected.
We need expressions for ProbfV L j buyg and ProbfV H j buyg. These
two probabilities are calculated using the same method. Going
through the rst only, ProbfV L j buyg, is therefore sufcient for understanding the complete solution.
To calculate the probability ProbfV L j buyg, we need to use a
handy rule called Bayes Rule. The appendix to this chapter provides
a review of Bayes Rule and its underlying intuition. Let me simply
assert here that applying Bayes Rule provides us with the following
expression:
ProbfV L j buyg
ProbfV L gProbfbuy j V L g
ProbfV L gProbfbuy j V L g ProbfV H gProbfbuy j V H g
4:14
The dealer knows ProbfV L g and ProbfV H g are p and 1 p respectively. The only other components to the dealer's problem are
Probfbuy j V L g and Probfbuy j V H g. These are easily determined
from the probabilities in the righthand column of the tree diagram.
For example, Probfbuy j V L g is the sum of the buy probabilities in the
fth and seventh cells, divided by 1 p. The 1 p comes from the
sum of the probabilities in the fth through eighth cellsthe probability of V L .
The determination of expectations and prices for subsequent periods follows the same procedure. The dealer uses all available infor-
92
Chapter 4
Theoretical Frameworks
93
This section of chapter 4 is more extensive than the previous three for
several reasons. First, the simultaneous-trade model, with its multiple-dealer structure, is a better proxy for FX market institutions than
the other models, so it provides perspective on FX trading that the
others cannot provide (see also Lyons 1997a). Second, many papers
in the literature extend the simple versions of the three models presented above. Readers therefore have ample references for these
models. Because the simultaneous-trade model is more recent, references are few. Indeed, the theory of multiple-dealer trading is, on the
whole, rather underdeveloped.27 Third, I employ variations on the
simultaneous-trade model to guide much of the empirical analysis
in later chapters; a solid introduction to how it works will provide
background for understanding those empirical models.
Of the FX market features reviewed in chapter 3, there are three in
particular that the preceding models do not address, but which the
simultaneous-trade model is designed to capture. The rst of these
is interdealer trading. Most trading in the foreign exchange market
is interdealerroughly two-thirds. Single-dealer (and dealerless)
models cannot address the causes and implications of such trades.
The second feature is the way in which private information arises.
Customer order ow in FX is an important source of information
advantage that accrues to dealers. That said, it is not the case that all
information about payoffs is revealed to the dealers who enjoy this
advantage. Dealers therefore have less information than the informed
traders in the preceding single-dealer frameworks. The third feature
94
Chapter 4
Theoretical Frameworks
95
96
Chapter 4
Theoretical Frameworks
97
Figure 4.10
Timing in the simultaneous-trade model.
98
Chapter 4
Figure 4.11
Summary of simultaneous-trade model.
Theoretical Frameworks
99
4:15
4:16
where W Ti1 and W Ti2 denote dealer i's information sets at the time of
trading in periods one and two, respectively. From equation (4.15) it
is clear that customer purchases (sales) must be repurchased (resold)
in interdealer trading to establish the desired position Di1 (we assume an initial position of zero). In addition, to establish Dit , dealers
must factor the expected value of the interdealer orders received Tit0
into each period's trade. Turning to equation (4.16), in period two,
the realized period-one position must be reversed, which has the
three components: Di1 , Ti10 , and ETi10 j W ti1 (recall that Ti10 > 0 corresponds to a dealer i sale in period one). The term Ti10 ETi10 j W ti1 is
the unexpected incoming orderthe inventory shock.
At the close of period one, dealers observe period-one interdealer
order ow:
X1
N
X
Ti1 :
4:17
i1
This summation over the signed interdealer trades Ti1 measures the
difference between buy and sell orders (i.e., net buying) because Ti1 is
negative in the case of a sale. The empirical analogue of X is the
signed order ow information communicated by interdealer brokers,
a statistic common to all dealers. Specifying this order ow statistic
X as an exact measure (i.e., without noise) maximizes the transparency difference across trade types because the model's customerdealer trades are unobservable to noncounterparties. As noted in
chapter 3, trades between dealers and their customers do indeed
have zero transparency. However, the actual transparency of interdealer trades is not complete. I address the role of noise in this
equation in Lyons 1996a, a paper that examines the effects of changing transparency.
Before proceeding, recall that one of the objectives of this model is
to capture the effect of different transparency levels across trade
types, customer-dealer versus interdealer. Because customer-dealer
trades are not generally observable, they are not aggregated in price
until they are later reected in interdealer tradeswhich are observable. The result is a ``two-stage'' process of information aggregation, with interdealer trading as the second, crucial stage (see also
Gersbach and Vogler 1998).
100
Chapter 4
EexpyWi2 j Wi
4:18
s.t.
Wi2 Wi0 C i Pi1 Pi10 Di1 ETi10 j W Ti1 Pi20 Pi10
Di2 ETi20 j W Ti2 V Pi20 Ti10 Pi20 Pi1 Ti20 V Pi2 ;
where Pi1 is dealer i's period-one quote, a prime ( 0 ) denotes a quote
or trade received by dealer i, and V is the payoff value of the risky
asset at the end of period two. The second term in nal wealth is the
dealer's roundtrip prot on his customer orderif C i is positive,
then the dealer sold to the customer at Pi1 , and bought the same
amount back from other dealers at Pi10 . The third term in nal wealth
is the capital gain on the dealer's period-one speculative and hedging demands (recall that ETi10 j W ti1 is the dealer's hedge against incoming orders). The fourth term in nal wealth is the same as the
third term, but dened for the second period. The last two terms in
nal wealth capture the position disturbances that arise due to the
simultaneous trade feature: dealer i does not know the value of
the order he receives Ti10 when he chooses his trade Ti1 (similarly for
period two). The conditioning information Wi at each decision node
(two quotes and two trades) is as follows:
Quoting Pi1 : fC i ; Si ; Sg
Trading Ti1 : fC i ; Si ; S; P11 ; . . . ; PN1 g
Quoting Pi2 : fC i ; Si ; S; P11 ; . . . ; PN1 ; Ti1 ; Ti10 ; Xg
Trading Ti2 : fC i ; Si ; S; P11 ; . . . ; PN1 ; Ti1 ; Ti10 ; X; P12 ; . . . ; PN2 g
Equilibrium Quoting Strategies
In this model, rational quotes must be the same across dealers at any
given time. If not common across dealers, arbitrage opportunities
would exist (quotes are single prices, are available to all dealers, and
Theoretical Frameworks
101
are good for any size). Further, given that quotes are common, then
they must be based on common information. Because there is only
one piece of common informationthe signal Sthis yields a linear
quoting strategy:
P1 L s S
4:19
4:20
102
Chapter 4
4:21
Theoretical Frameworks
103
dilutes the information content of order ow, which reduces the information in the period-two price (insight 3 from this model). This
is true even if dealers behave competitively. To see why, recall that
information is aggregated on the basis of signal extraction applied to
X, the interdealer order ow. The greater the noise relative to signal,
the less effective the signal extraction. Passing hot potato liquidity
trades increases the noise in the interdealer order ow.
On top of this hot potato effect, strategic dealer behavior causes a
further reduction of information in period-two price (insight 2). This
result comes from dealers recognizing that their own orders will
have a subsequent price impact. This induces each to alter speculative demand to prot from the forecastable effect on price. These
altered speculative demands exacerbate the reduced efciency of
signal extraction due to hot potato trading.
Let me return to the earlier example I used to illustrate these
insights (2) and (3), using the model's specics to make it more concrete. Suppose that dealer i receives a combination of signals and
customer order ow fS; Si ; C i g f0; 0; 1g, where S is the public signal, Si is the private signal, and C i is dealer i's customer order (the
latter being uncorrelated with the payoff V ). Because the value of the
public signal S pins down the rst period price P1 at L s S, that S 0
implies that P1 0. Further, because both signals S and Si are zero,
the expected value of the payoff EV j S; Si ; C i 0 and the incoming
interdealer trade that dealer i expects ETi10 j S; Si ; C i 0. (The latter
relation holds because the customer orders C i each dealer receives
are uncorrelated across dealers; thus, using equation (4.21), dealer i's
realization of fS; Si ; C i g gives him no information useful for forecasting the incoming interdealer trade.) Despite the realization
f0; 0; 1g, however, dealer i's speculative demand is not zero. To see
this, note that dealer i's interdealer trade Ti1 includes his customer
order C i one-for-one due to inventory control. Note alsofrom the
pricing rule in equation (4.20)that P2 will move in the same direction as the sign of interdealer ow X, one component of which is Ti1 .
Dealer i can therefore forecast the effect that the passing along of his
customer order C i will have on the price P2 . This induces him to take
a positive (long) position in order to prot from the forecastable
market move. Part of what dealer i is able to forecast is the market's
misinterpretation of dealer i's interdealer trade Ti1 : The market can
only presume that a positive Ti1 partly reects a positive Si , which, in
this example, it does not. Note that the added weight that dealer i
104
Chapter 4
Theoretical Frameworks
105
ow signal that drives the model parallels most closely that provided
by brokered trading. How individuals choose a particular trading
mechanism in markets where there is choice is a burgeoning area of
research (for empirical work in FX, see Bjonnes and Rime 2000; for
theoretical work on modeling brokers, see for example Werner 1997.)
Direct versus brokered interdealer trading in FX has particularly
interesting implications given the difference in transparency across
trading mechanisms.
4.5
There are many standard results useful for working with microstructure models. In this appendix I present three of the most useful.
Before launching into details, however, I begin at a more general
level by providing some perspective on the so-called CARA-Normal
framework, a norm within microstructure. In this framework, utility
exhibits constant absolute risk aversion (CARA) and random variables are Normally distributed. Then I turn to the three specic
results: the rst is that in the standard CARA-Normal framework,
preferences are mean-variance, which makes them particularly easy
to work with; the second is that in the CARA-Normal setting, demands for risky assets take a particularly simple form; third, I show
that in the CARA-Normal setting, conditional expectations, too, take
a particularly simple form. For each of the last three results I provide
derivations, with the intention to alert readers that the techniques
used in the derivations are themselves quite useful for solving more
complex models. Another good reference for useful tools used in
microstructure analysis is O'Hara 1995, in particular the appendix to
chapter 3, where she addresses Bayesian learning with discretely
distributed random variables.
The CARA-Normal Setting: Exponential Utility and Normal Returns
The negative exponential utility function I introduce in equation (4.1)
of this chapter is a standard feature of trading models. It produces
simple expressions for risky asset demand as long as returns are
conditionally Normally distributed. The word conditionally is important: it is not enough that all random variables in the model are
Normally distributed. There are many cases in which Normally distributed random variables do not produce conditionally Normal
106
Chapter 4
returns. Examples of non-Normal returns include products of (discrete) Normal random variables and mixtures of Normal random
variables. (An example of a mixture of Normals X1 and X2 is pX1
1 pX2 , where p is a probability between zero and one. Specications with a mixture of Normals are intuitively appealing, but technically more complex.) Trading model specications rely heavily on
the fact that the sum of two Normally distributed variables is itself
Normally distributed.
It may be helpful to review the denition of the coefcient of absolute risk aversion, y:
yW
U 00 W
;
U 0 W
Theoretical Frameworks
107
Figure 4.12
Negative exponential utility.
Result 1:
Mean-Variance Preferences
m PR
;
ys 2
108
Chapter 4
Conditional Expectations
With Normally distributed random variables, conditional expectations are Normally distributed and take a convenient form. Specically, dene the following:
y y e0
x i y ei
i 1; . . . ; n;
where the variable y is the variable of interest and the variables xi are
signals of y. Let each ei , i 0; . . . ; n, be distributed independently
and Normally N0; si2 . Then
Ey j x1 ; . . . ; xn
and
V y j x1 ; . . . ; xn
1
;
s02 s12 sn2
and these two moments fully characterize the conditional expectation because the conditional distribution is Normal. Note the simplicity: The mean of the posterior distribution is the sum of the prior
and signals, each weighted by its own precision (the inverse of its
own variance), divided by the sum of the precisions. The conditional
variance is just one over the sum of the precisions.
Derivation of Result 1:
Mean-Variance Preferences
Theoretical Frameworks
109
The trick to solving this is to factor the integral into two parts, one
part that depends on the random variable W and one part that does
not. Once factored, we will nd that maximizing EUW is as simple as maximizing the part that does not depend on W.
Now, substituting in the Normal density fW and rearranging
slightly, we get
y
z
1
p exp 2 dW;
EUW
2s
y 2ps 2
where
z W m 2 2yWs 2
and z can be rewritten as
z W m ys 2 2 yys 4 2ms 2 :
This is the key step in factoring the integral into two parts: the second of these two parts does not depend on random wealth W. We
can now write the problem as
ys 2
EUW exp y m
2
!
!
y
1
W m ys 2 2
p exp
dW ;
2s 2
y 2ps 2
where I have divided the term yys 4 2ms 2 by 2s 2 and multiplied
by 1 in order to bring this term outside the second exponential.
Notice that the integral on the right-hand side is just the integral over
a Normal density (with mean m ys 2 and variance s 2 ), and is therefore equal to one. This reduces the problem to maximizing the simple
exponential expression to the left of the integral. Given the behavior
of the negative exponential function illustrated in gure 4.12, it
should clear that this expression is maximized when m 12 ys 2 is
maximized.
Derivation of Result 2:
Risky-Asset Demand
Again, let us start from rst principles. We will nd that the solution
method is quite similar in spirit to the derivation of result 1. For
notation, recall that I dened V as the risky-asset payoff, with V @
110
Chapter 4
! !
1
V m 2
p exp
yDV dV :
2s 2
y 2ps 2
V m 2
yDV
2s 2
into one part that depends on V and another that does not. Simple
algebraic manipulation yields
!
Vm 2
1
V myDs 2 2
1
2myDy 2 D 2 s 2 :
yDV
2
2
2s 2
s2
The second of these two terms does not depend on the random payoff V. Accordingly, we can write the problem as
EUW1 expyRW0 DRP 1=22myD y 2 D 2 s 2
! !
y
1
V m yDs 2 2
p exp
dV :
2s 2
y 2ps 2
Theoretical Frameworks
111
As was the case for result 1, the integral on the right-hand side is just
the integral over a Normal density (with mean m-yDs 2 and variance
s 2 ), and is therefore equal to one. This reduces the problem to maximizing the following expression:
yRW0 DRP 1=22myD y 2 D 2 s 2 :
The rst order condition is
yRP my Dy 2 s 2 0;
or
DP
m PR
;
ys 2
Conditional Expectations
112
Chapter 4
f V j X y
1
2psV2 sx2 1
!
ms 2 Xsx2
V V2
sV sx2
!
:
msV2 Xsx2
sV2 sx2
and
Variance sV2 sx2 1 :
This is what we set out to show: the mean of the posterior distribution is the sum of the prior and signal, each weighted by its own
precision (the inverse of its own variance), divided by the sum of the
precisions. The conditional variance is just the inverse of the sum of
the precisions.
Empirical Frameworks
This chapter covers key topics of empirical interest in FX microstructure research. Order ow features prominently, as it does in
later chapters that cover work that is more macro-oriented. This is
because, as we have seen, order ow plays a crucial role in microstructure models. The chapter begins with a survey of data sets; recent advances in available FX datadue largely to the advent of
electronic tradinghave opened new doors for empiricists. Then I
introduce the main empirical approaches within the eld of microstructure and how they are applied in FX. The closing sections
review important empirical results. In particular, I present results
bearing on central questions from the previous theory chapter such
as ``Does FX order ow convey private information?'' Conrming
empirical evidence supports this book's continuing use of information models. Another key question is, ``Does incomplete risk sharing
affect exchange rates?'' Conrming evidence here supports the use of
inventory models as well.
For perspective, consider how the data available for research in FX
microstructure have evolved over the last twenty years. The earliest
work used futures data because those data are available at high frequencies (Grammatikos and Saunders 1986; Jorion 1996.) In FX,
however, the futures market is much smaller than the spot market; it
is unlikely that a signicant share of price determination occurs there
(Dumas 1996). Moreover, early futures data sets did not have sufcient granularity to capture agent heterogeneity, a hallmark of the
microstructure approach. Work on the spot market itself grew in the
early 1990s with the availability of quotes on an intraday basis (specically, the indicative quotes from Reuters called FXFX). 1 These
quotes provide a quite accurate picture of price dynamics. More importantly, they also speak to heterogeneity issues because the names
114
Chapter 5
FX Data Sets
Empirical Frameworks
115
116
Chapter 5
the voice-based system was rather spotty (e.g., Lyons 1995). More
recently, data sets have emerged from the records of the newer electronic brokers (e.g., Goodhart, Ito, and Payne 1996; Goodhart and
Payne 1996; Killeen, Lyons, and Moore 2000a). The main electronic
brokers in the major spot markets are EBS and Dealing 2000-2.
(Dealing 2000-2 is Reuters product for brokered interdealer trading;
Dealing 2000-1 is for direct interdealer trading.) These electronic
broker data have the advantage that they reect the activities of
multiple dealers who are trading simultaneously. At present, however, the available data sets do not span the full brokered interdealer
segment because they reect only the trading on either Dealing 20002 or EBS, but not both.
With this as background, gure 5.1 offers a model for organizing
one's thinking regarding available data.
The inner ring in gure 5.1 represents direct interdealer trading,
the most liquid part of the market. Dealing 2000-1 data is from this
inner ring. The middle ring contains brokered interdealer trading.
Figure 5.1
Three data groupings.
Empirical Frameworks
117
EBS and D2000-2 data are from this middle ring. The outer ring represents customer-dealer trading. Data from this ring come directly
from banks' own order ow records.3
The Inner Ring: Direct Interdealer Transactions and D2000-1
Data Set 1: Lyons 1995
The Lyons data set, like others from this inner ring of the market,
comes from Dealing 2000-1 trading records. For direct interdealer
trading in the major currencies, the Dealing 2000-1 system dominates
the market: it is believed to account for about 90 percent of the
world's direct interdealer volume.4 Trades on this system take the
form of electronic bilateral conversations initiated when one dealer
calls another dealer on the system, asking for a quote. Users of the
system are expected to provide a fast quote with a tight spread,
which is in turn accepted or declined quickly (i.e., within seconds).
Acceptance of a quote constitutes a trade.
The Lyons data set chronicles the activity of a dealer in the $/DM
market at a major New York investment bank. The sample spans
ve trading days over the week August 37, 1992 (from 8:30 a.m. to
on average 1:30 p.m., Eastern Standard Time). These data come from
the bank's own dealing records from the Dealing 2000-1 system. This
dealer uses Dealing 2000-1 for more than 99 percent of his nonbrokered interdealer trades.
Each record from the Dealing 2000-1 system includes the rst ve
of the following seven variables. The last two are included only if a
trade takes place:
1. a time stamp (to the minute)
2. which of the two dealers is requesting the quote
3. the quote quantity
4. the bid quote
5. the ask quote
6. the quantity traded
7. the transaction price
Note that these records provide rm bilateral quotes rather than
just transaction prices. They also identify which counterparty is the
aggressor. As such, they allow one to measure signed order ow
118
Chapter 5
Empirical Frameworks
119
Figure 5.2
Example of Dealing 2000-1 Communication. The opening word, ``From,'' establishes
this as an incoming quote request (outgoing quote requests begin with ``To''); this information is crucial for signing trades. The caller's four-digit code and institution
name follow; ``GMT'' denotes Greenwich Mean Time; the date follows, with the day
listed rst; the ``1080'' at the end of line one is simply a record number. ``SP DMK 10''
identies this as a request for a spot DM/$ quote for up to $10 million; ``8891'' denotes
a bid of 88 and an offer of 91. Only the last two digits are quoted because it involves
fewer keystrokes; dealers are well aware of the rst digits of the pricesometimes
called the ``handle.'' From the conrmation that follows, one can see that the earlier bid
quote was in fact 1.5888 DM/$ and the offer quote was 1.5891 DM/$. The conrmation
also provides the transaction price and veries the transaction quantity. ``THKS N
BIFN'' is shorthand for ``thanks and bye for now.''
though, that roughly three years separate these data, and the $/DM
spot market grew in dollar terms by about 50 percent over those
three years).
The more important difference between the two data sets is the
composition of these trades; in particular, the extent to which the
two dealers trade with non-dealer customers differs dramatically.
About 14 percent of the Yao dealer's volume comes from customer
trades, whereas less than 1 percent of the Lyons dealer's volume
comes from customers. In this respect, the mix of trades executed by
the Yao dealer is more representative of market averages (in 1995,
roughly 25 percent of total trading was customer-dealer). The fact
that the Yao dealer is from a commercial bank rather than an investment bank helps explain why his customer order ow is so much
120
Chapter 5
Empirical Frameworks
121
heavier: for spot FX, commercial banks have a more natural customer base than investment banks.
Data Set 3: Evans 1997
The data set introduced by Evans (1997) covers direct interdealer
trading over a four-month period (May 1August 31, 1996). It contains time-stamped tick-by-tick data on all transactions for nine currencies against the U.S. dollar. These data were collected from the
Dealing 2000-1 system via a customized feed at the Bank of England.
Reuters keeps a temporary archive of all conversations on the system
to settle disputes; this archive is the source of these data. For every
D2000-1 transaction, the data set includes
1. a time-stamp
2. the transaction price
3. a bought or sold indicator (for signing the trade)
For condentiality reasons, Reuters was unable to provide the identity of the trading partners. The following list shows the nine currencies covered and the number of transactions for each over the
four-month period:
German Mark
257,398
Japanese Yen
152,238
Swiss Franc
67,985
British Pound
52,318
French Franc
20,553
Italian Lira
8,466
Figure 5.3
Diagram of data structure. Denitions: Q o is an outgoing interdealer quote (i.e., a
quote made) and, if the quote is hit, T i is the incoming direct dealer trade. Q i is an
incoming interdealer quote (i.e., a quote received) and, if the quote is hit, T o is the
outgoing direct trade. T b is a brokered interdealer trade. Brokered trades do not align
vertically with a quote because the data for brokered trades in the Lyons (1995) data
set come from the dealer position sheets, and the broker-advertised quotes at the time
of the transaction are not recorded. ``jj '' appears whenever a trade occurs; ``jj '' appears
whenever a nondealt quote occurs. The disjoint segment below the top timeline presents a hypothetical path of the dealer's position over the same interval; it changes with
trades only. The timeline at the bottom claries the denition of ``periods'' within the
Lyons (1995) analysis: incoming trades dene an event, not all trades (that model is
presented in chapter 5).
122
Chapter 5
Belgian Franc
5,256
Dutch Guilder
3,646
Danish Krona
1,488.
Empirical Frameworks
123
124
Chapter 5
year of the sample includes order ow for $/DM, $/FF, and DM/FF.
The second year includes order ow for $/euro. These order ow
series are valuable for addressing hypotheses about the launch of the
new currency.
The Third Ring: Customer-Dealer Trades and Indicative Quotes
Data Set 6: Customer Orders (Fan and Lyons 2000)
This data set includes all the customer-dealer tradessigned according to the customer's directionreceived by Citibank over a period
of seven years (19931999). Citibank is among the top three banks in
the world in terms of trading volume (handling more than 10 percent
of worldwide customer order ow in the major FX markets).
Traditionally, banks have been reluctant to provide researchers
access to this kind of data, given its proprietary nature. One reason
Citibank was more accommodating is that the data are aggregated
to daily totals (i.e., individual transactions are not available). These
time-aggregated order ows are valuable for examining the link between order ows and lower frequency price dynamics.
Because these order ows come from underlying customers, they
provide a direct connection to the underlying sources of demand in
the economy. The data set includes the $/yen market and the $/euro
market (order ow for the euro before its launch is synthesized from
its constituent currencies). These data are the basis for the material I
present in chapter 9.6
Data Set 7: FXFX Quotes (Goodhart and Figliuoli 1991)
As noted above, FXFX is a second type of data that relates to customer-dealer trading. These data are indicative quotes that provide
customers (i.e., nondealers) with real-time information about current
prices. This source of data has many strengths. First, the data are
available over long periodsfrom the late 1980s to the present. Second, they are available for many currency pairs. Third, they are
available on a tick-by-tick basis (typically with thousands of ticks per
day in a major currency pair). Fourth, each quote is time-stamped to
the second. Fifth, the bank that input each quote can be identied.
These data also have several drawbacks. First, and most important, these data do not include order owthey are quotes only.
This precludes direct testing of models like those in chapter 4 because order ow is central to those models.7 (Some authors have
Empirical Frameworks
125
used the rate at which quotes arrive to proxy for trading volume
i.e., unsigned order owbut the proxy is rather loose; see Goodhart, Ito, and Payne 1996 and Evans 1997. Hartmann 1998a, on the
other hand, nds that quote arrival provides a good proxy for volume over longer horizons.) Second, the spreads in these indicative
quotes tend to be clustered at specic spread sizes, whereas rm
quotes in the market do not exhibit such clustering (see Goodhart,
Ito, and Payne 1996; Evans 1997). Third, a displayed indicative quote
cannot be replaced with a new quote until ve seconds have passed
(Evans 1997). Fourth, the raw data are rather noisy (Zhou 1996),
and even after applying the standard lter used in the literature
(Dacorogna et al. 1993), signicant outliers remain (Andersen, Bollerslev, and Das 2001).
Closing Thoughts
It is important to note that FX microstructure is evolving rapidly
in terms of available state of the art data. In the future, sample
lengths will surely be extended, and I anticipate further integration
of data from all three market segments (direct interdealer, brokered
interdealer, and customer-dealer).8 Thus, the data sets above are
perhaps best thought of as a guide to measurable variables and their
sources. At present, the customer-dealer segment is still thinly covered. This segment is important, though, because these trades represent the outside ``shocks'' to the interdealer trading at the market's
core.
I chose in this section to present FX data sets as they appear in the
literature. This provides easy reference to additional detail in the
corresponding papers. Another way to organize the data is according to information sets, that is, according to which participants observe which data in real time, and how data that are not available in
real time are disseminated. This would have been a more difcult
task. Consider, for example, the Evans 1997 data set that contains all
the direct interdealer trading from the 2000-1 system. In that case, it
is most appropriate to think of individual dealers as observing only
part of those data, the part that corresponds to their own trading
(both prices and order ow). But individual FX dealers do not observe these marketwide data in their entirety, and nondealer customers do not observe any of these data. Turning to the data sets on
brokered interdealer trading (EBS and D2000-2), to organize those
126
Chapter 5
This section presents the main empirical approaches within microstructure and relates them to the FX market. My objective is to introduce readers who are new to microstructure to some of the empirical
tools. It is, however, exactly thatan introduction. It is not possible
to cover these approaches in depth. Ample references to key papers
will help guide those who desire more detail.
There are two broad approaches to empirical microstructure: statistical models and structural models. Not surprisingly, the split
mirrors that in economics more generally. All of these models are
designed to characterize the joint behavior of order ow and price.
The statistical models have the benet of modest data requirements.
They also are more generally applicable across different market
structures (i.e., dealer versus auction markets). Their lack of structure makes their reduced form results more difcult to interpret,
however. Structural models are grounded more explicitly in the economic decisions that dealers face. Accordingly, they are most appropriate for dealer markets, including the FX market.
There are three specic approaches I will cover here, the rst two
statistical, and the third structural. They are
1. The Vector Auto-Regression (VAR) Approach
2. The Trade-Indicator (TI) Approach
3. The Dealer-Problem (DP) Approach
Naturally, summarizing empirical microstructure with these three
approaches runs the risk of oversimplication. Although micro-
Empirical Frameworks
127
structure empiricists are sure to feel that much has been left out, I
believe they would agree that these are the three most important of
the basic approaches.9 Each has been applied in the microstructure
literature for more than a decade now, across many different market
structures and asset types.
In essence, all three approaches are a means of relating changes
in price to order ow. The status awarded to order ow in these
approaches is in keeping with the leading role played by order ow
in microstructure theory (per the previous chapter). Naturally, then,
all three approaches depend crucially on having signed trade data.
(It is not enough to know the size of a trade; one must also know its
direction.) In dealer markets, the initiator of the trade establishes the
direction: a customer selling 10 units at a dealer's bid generates an
order ow observation of 10 (exactly analogous to the Bayesian
learning problem featured in the sequential-trade model of the previous chapter). In auction markets, trades are signed according to the
direction of the incoming market order (which is executed against
the most competitive limit order).
In some markets, access to signed trade data is difcult to obtain.
Instead, one might have access only to the sequence of trade sizes
and the transaction prices at which each trade is executed. Though
certainly less desirable than having signed order ow data, there are
techniques in the literature that are commonly used to convert
unsigned trade data into signed order ow data. The conversion can
be noisy, but for many empirical purposes it is adequate (see, e.g.,
Lee and Ready 1991).
All three of these empirical approaches are estimated at the transaction frequency (i.e., observations are the realizations of individual
trades, which are matched to the prices that correspond to those
trades). For work in empirical microstructure, this is the natural data
frequency. More recently, however, estimation of microstructureinspired models has been effected at much lower frequencies (e.g.,
daily, weekly, and monthly). We review these lower frequency applications in chapters 7 and 9.
Statistical Model 1:
128
Chapter 5
p
X
ai rti
i1
xt
p
X
i1
p
X
i0
gi rti
p
X
b i xti e1t
5:1
di xti e2t :
5:2
i1
Beyond the two assumptions described above, identication also requires the following restrictions on the innovations:
Empirical Frameworks
129
5:3
Et 0 s:
5:4
5:5
xt
e2t
cL dL
The coefcients of the lag polynomials in this moving average representation are the impulse response functions implied by the VAR
model (see, e.g., Hamilton 1994).
Most important among these lag polynomials is bL, which captures the impact of order ow information on subsequent prices. The
individual coefcient bi , for example, measures the effect of a unit
order ow innovation on the price change at the i period horizon. If
we sum these price effects over all horizons, we get a measure of the
cumulative impact of order ow on the level of price. Within this
approach, these cumulative (i.e., persistent) effects are identied as
information:
y
X
5:6
i0
5:7
130
Chapter 5
where
m t m t1 nt
5:8
i0
The second of the two statistical models I present here is the TradeIndicator (TI) approach, pioneered by Glosten and Harris (1988) and
recently generalized by Huang and Stoll (1997). This model, like the
other two approaches presented here, addresses the link between
order ow and prices. The focus in this case, however, is a bit
narrower than it is under either the VAR or DP approaches. It is
narrower in two ways. First, order ow is not measured from signed
trade size, but rather as a direction indicator variable, say Dt , that
takes on a value of 1 if the previous trade is a sell, and a value of 1
if the previous trade is a buy. This makes the approach less applicable
to questions that revolve around trade size.15 Second, the TI approach
is primarily concerned with decomposing the bid-ask spread.
In chapters 1 and 2, I hinted at the idea that spreads have different
components; now it is time to be explicit. There are three basic costs
Empirical Frameworks
131
132
Chapter 5
ponents, and, to the extent possible, to distinguish among them. Enter the TI approach. Perhaps the best way to communicate how the
TI approach accomplishes this is to do so graphically. Suppose the
only cost component that enters the spread is the order processing
cost. Consider how the sequence of transaction prices would look if
this were the only component. Panel 1 of gure 5.4 provides an
illustration. At is the ask price (often called the offer price in FX), Bt is
the bid price, and Mt is the spread midpoint. Because order ow
conveys no information in this case, nor is there any inventory cost,
the only connection between transaction prices and order ow is the
bouncing of transaction prices from bid to ask (so-called bid-ask
bounce).16
Now consider the case in which the spread arises because of inventory costs only. In this case, following the customer buy order,
the dealer's bid and offer prices change (panel 2 of gure 5.4). This is
the inventory effect described in chapter 2: after the customer sell
order, the dealer is long (or at least longer than before), so to restore
the previous position the dealer lowers his or her quotes. This induces subsequent customer purchases at those lower prices (not
shown with asterisks), which brings the dealer's position gradually
back to its previous level.17 Once the original position is restored, the
original prices are restored, illustrating the transitory nature of inventory effects.
Finally, consider the case in which the spread arises because of
adverse selection costs only. Now the customer sell order pushes
prices down, but the price adjustment is persistent (panel 3 of gure
5.4). This reects the information conveyed by the order ow. This
information can be either of the two types presented in chapter 2 that
have persistent effects: payoff information or information about persistent changes in discount rates (portfolio balance effects).
Equation (5.10) presents the basic Trade-Indicator specication.
The change in the midpoint of the spread, DMt , is the change between two transactions; St1 is the quoted bid-ask spread at the time
of the previous transaction at t 1; Dt1 is the indicator variable
introduced above, which takes values of 1 or 1, depending on the
direction of the previous trade.18 The residual et represents a random
(iid) public information shock at time t:
DMt a b
St1
Dt1 et
2
5:10
Empirical Frameworks
133
Figure 5.4
An illustration of the three spread components: order processing, inventory, and adverse selection. Transactions are marked with an asterisk. At , Mt , and Bt denote ask
price, midpoint, and bid price, respectively (at time t). The indicator variable Dt is 1 if
the trade is buyer-initiated and 1 if seller-initiated.
134
Chapter 5
Empirical Frameworks
135
T
X
Ri ;
i0
136
Chapter 5
5:11
Sjt Vt o jt
5:12
Bt Vt xt
5:13
Empirical Frameworks
137
Figure 5.5
Timing in each period of the DP model.
5:14
where m jt is the expectation of Vt conditional on information available to dealer j at t, and the value of Xjt is known only to dealer j.
Note that Xjt can be either positive or negative.
Figure 5.5 summarizes the timing of the model in each period.
Formation of Expectations
Dealer i's quote schedule is a function of his expectation of Vt , which
is denoted m it . This expectation, in turn, is conditioned on the signals
described above: St , Bt , and Xjt (the fourth variable described above,
Sjt , is the signal embedded in Xjt ).
The rst public signal, St , summarizes dealer i's prior belief regarding Vt . After observing the second public signal Bt , dealer i's
posterior belief, denoted m t , can be expressed as a weighted average
of St and Bt :
m t rSt 1 rBt ;
5:15
where r sx2 =sx2 sh2 . These posterior beliefs m t are Normally distributed with mean Vt and variance sm2 r 2 sh2 1 r 2 sx2 .
After observing Bt , dealer i then considers what he would learn
from various possible realizations of Xjt (and the schedule he quotes
internalizes what he would learn from each possible realization). In
particular, dealer i can form the statistic Zjt :
Xjt =y Pit lm t
1
Vt ojt
L jt ;
5:16
Zjt
y1 l
1l
where l so2 =sm2 so2 . This statistic is also Normally distributed, with mean Vt and variance equal to the variance of the last
2
two terms, both of which are orthogonal to Vt . Let sZj
denote this
138
Chapter 5
5:17
2
2
=sZj
sm2 . This expectation plays a central role in
where k sZj
determining dealer i's quote.
Quote Determination
Consider a prototypical inventory control model in which the transaction price Pit is linearly related to the dealer's current inventory:
Pit m it aIit Ii gDt ;
5:18
where m it is the expectation of Vt conditional on information available to dealer i at t, Iit is dealer i's current inventory position, Ii is i's
desired position,22 and Dt is a direction indicator that picks up bidoffer bounce in the model. The inventory control effect, governed by
a, will in general be a function of rm capital, relative interest rates,
and other inventory carrying costs. The direction indicator Dt equals
1 when the transaction price Pit is the offer price and 1 when Pit is
the bid price. For a given expectation m it , Dt picks up half the spread.
(Dt should be viewed as half the spread for quantities close to zero;
for other quantities, the quoted spread widens to protect against adverse selectionthrough the effects on m it .) This term measures the
catch-all order-processing costs described in the presentation of the
trade-indicator (TI) model.
Consistent with the regret-free property of quotes, I substitute
dealer i's expectation m it in equation (5.17) into equation (5.18),
yielding:
Pit km t 1 kZjt aIit Ii gDt
which is equivalent to
1f
a
g
Xjt
Iit Ii
Dt ;
Pit 1 rBt rSt
fy
f
f
5:19
5:20
Empirical Frameworks
139
An Estimable Equation
Equation (5.20) is not directly estimable because the public signal St
is not observable to the econometrician. Fortunately, though, the
assumptions about the model's signals and the evolution of Vt allow
one to express the period t prior as equal to the period t 1 posterior
from equation (5.18) lagged one period, plus an expectational error
term e it :
St m it1 e it Pit1 aIit1 Ii gDt1 e it :
5:21
Substituting this expression for St into equation (5.20) and taking the
rst difference yields:
a
1f
a
a Ii
Xjt
Iit aIit1
DPit
f
fy
f
g
5:22
Dt gDt1 1 rBt e it
f
This corresponds to a reduced-form estimating equation of: 23
DPit b0 b1 Xjt b 2 Iit b 3 Iit1 b4 Dt
b5 Dt1 b 6 Bt b7 nit1 nit :
5:23
140
Chapter 5
Figure 5.6
Dealer i's quote schedule in the DP model. The slope of the quoted price schedule is
determined by b1 and reects the information conveyed by order ow Xjt (Xjt is negative if the incoming order is a sell). Inventory is a shift variable: the larger Iit is relative to the desired position Ii , the lower the price schedule throughout (to induce
inventory decumulating purchases by counterparties). The bid-offer spread at quantities
near zero is pinned down by the parameter g, which multiplies the direction-indicator
variable Dt in the pricing rule of equation (5.18).
Table 5.1
Structural Model Estimates
DPit b 0 b 1 Xjt b2 Iit b 3 Iit1 b 4 Dt b 5 Dt1 b6 Bt b7 vit1 vit
b0
b1
b2
b3
b4
b5
b6
b7
R2
1.30
(0.96)
1.44
(3.10)
0.98
(3.59)
0.79
(3.00)
10.15
(4.73)
8.93
(6.12)
0.69
(2.21)
0.09
(2.55)
0.23
1.34
(0.99)
1.40
(3.03)
0.97
(3.56)
0.78
(2.95)
10.43
(4.86)
9.16
(6.28)
0.09
(2.61)
0.22
>0
<0
>0
>0
<0
>0
<0
T-statistics in parentheses. The last row indicates the signs predicted by the structural
model. DPit is the change in the incoming transaction price (DM/$) from t 1 to t. Xit
is the incoming order transacted at dealer i's quoted prices, positive for purchases (i.e.,
effected at the offer) and negative for sales (at the bid). The units of Xit are such that
b1 1 implies an information effect on price of DM0.0001 for every $10 million. It is
dealer i's inventory at the end of period t. Dt is an indicator variable with value 1 if the
incoming order is a purchase and value 1 if a sale. Bt is the net quantity of third-party
brokered trading over the previous two minutes, positive for buyer-initiated trades
and negative for seller-initiated trades. All quantity variables are in $ millions. All
coefcients are multiplied by 10 5 . Sample: August 37, 1992, 839 observations.
Empirical Frameworks
141
rst row presents estimates of the full reduced form, that is, including the information effects of brokered order ow. The second row
excludes the brokered order ow variable to make it directly comparable to results from work on the stock market (Madhavan and
Smidt 1991). Row three indicates the signs of the coefcients predicted by the structural model under the null that both information
and inventory control effects are present.
The main results from table 5.1 are the signicant and properly
signed coefcients on the information (order ow) variables Xjt and
Bt , and the inventory variables Iit and Iit1 . The size of b1 implies that
the dealer being tracked widens his spread about 2.8 pips (0.00028
DM, or 1.4 doubledadjusted for units) per $10 million to protect
against adverse selection. The size of the inventory control coefcient
b 3 (which equals a in equation 5.18) implies that the dealer motivates
inventory decumulation by shading his DM price of dollars by 0.8
pips for every $10 million of net open position.
The coefcients on the indicator variables Dt and Dt1 , which
measure the effective spread when Xjt close to zero, are signicant,
and have the predicted relative size as well, b4 > jb5 j. (Recall that
there is a one to one correspondence between Dt and the sign of Xjt ,
so Dt controls perfectly for whether Xjt is at the bid or the offer.) The
coefcient b 4 suggests that once one controls for the information and
inventory effects, the baseline spread for this dealer is about two pips
(2b4 =10 5 ). Note too that the moving average coefcient b7 is signicant and properly signed, providing further support for the model.
Finally, the levels of the R 2 's reect that Xjt and Bt together account
for only a small fraction of the trading activity in the wider market.
Qualitatively, the main difference in the results from those for
NYSE stocks (Madhavan and Smidt 1991) is the signicance of the
inventory effect on price, captured by b2 and b 3 . Despite a large theoretical literature on price effects from inventory, work on equity
marketmakers does not detect it. In this respect, the model ts better
in FX.24 From the perspective of exchange rate economics, however,
the more striking result is the nding of a signicant b1 the private
information conveyed by order ow. It is more striking because most
exchange rate economists are quite comfortable with the idea that
there is private information in stock markets. At the same time, they
were not taught to believe that private information is relevant in the
FX market.
142
Chapter 5
Trading volume in FX marketsat $1.5 trillion per dayis extremely high. It is high relative to other asset markets, high relative
to underlying trade in goods and services, and high relative to what
standard theories would predict (be they micro theories or macro
theories).
Why, some might ask, should we care? After all, it's not clear this
volume affects prices, and if it does not affect prices, it may not have
important welfare consequences. But there are several ways in which
Empirical Frameworks
143
144
Chapter 5
we do not yet know enough to be condent that we have a full accounting. In fact, as an empirical matter, there is very little work on
hot potato trading.26 The one paper that addresses hot potato trading
head on is Lyons 1996b. The remainder of this section reviews the
methodology and results from that paper.
Volume: Sound and Fury Signifying Nothing?
Lyons 1996b addresses hot potato trading by examining whenas
opposed to whethertrades are informative. Specically, I use
transaction data to test whether trades occurring when trading intensity is high are more informativedollar for dollarthan trades
occurring when trading intensity is low. Theory admits both possibilities, depending on the posited information structure. I present
what I call a hot potato model of currency trading, which explains
why low-intensity trades might be more informative. In the model,
the wave of inventory management trading among dealers following
innovations in order ow generates an inverse relationship between
intensity and information content. Empirically, I nd that lowintensity trades are more informative, supporting the hot potato
hypothesis.
To clarify the hot potato process, consider the following crude,
but not unrealistic example. Suppose there are ten dealers, all of
whom are risk averse, and each currently with a zero net position.
One dealer accommodates a customer sale of $10 million worth of
DM. Not wanting to carry the open position, the dealer calculates
his share of this inventory imbalanceor 1/10th of $10 million
calls another dealer, and unloads $9 million worth of DM. The
dealer receiving this trade then calculates his share of this inventory imbalanceor 1/10th of $9 millioncalls another dealer, and
unloads $8.1 million worth of DM. The hot potato process continues.
In the limit, the total interdealer volume generated from the $10
million customer trade is $9m/1 0:9 $90 million. The resulting
share of wholesale trading that is interdealer is therefore $90m/
$100m, or 90 percent. This is a bit high relative to an interdealer
share these days of about two-thirds, but 10 years ago, the total share
of interdealer FX trading was close to 90 percent.
Here are two possible reactions to the example above, neither of
which vitiates its message. Reaction one: Shouldn't the multiplier be
innite because risk-averse dealers would not choose to retain any of
Empirical Frameworks
145
146
Chapter 5
5:14
Empirical Frameworks
147
Table 5.2
Testing the Hot Potato Hypothesis: Is Order Flow Less Informative When Intertransaction Time Is Short?
DPit b0 b1 st Xjt b10 lt Xjt b 2 Iit b 3 Iit1 b 4 Dt b5 Dt1 eit
b 1 (short)
b10 (long)
Fraction short
b1 b 10
P-value
0.01
(0.01)
2.20
(3.84)
262/842
0.000
0.76
(1.63)
2.60
(3.40)
506/842
0.009
Results
Table 5.2 presents estimates of the information content of order ow,
distinguishing between short and long intertransaction times. This is
achieved via the introduction of dummy variables st and lt (see the
equation heading the table). The dummy st equals 1 if intertransaction time is short, 0 otherwise; the dummy lt equals 0 if intertransaction time is short, 1 otherwise. Short intertransaction times are
dened two ways: less than 1 minute from the previous transaction
and less than 2 minutes. (The time stamps on the Lyons 1995 data
are very precise, because they are assigned by the computer; however, they do not provide precision beyond the minute. Hence, less
than 1 minute includes trades with the same time stamp; less than
2 minutes includes trades with time stamps differing by 1 or 0
minutes.) These categories bracket the mean intertransaction time
148
Chapter 5
b 10 (short and
opposite)
b100
0.06
(0.11)
1.90
(3.01)
2.64
(3.46)
(long)
Fraction short
and same
Fraction short
and opposite
b 1 b10
P-value
276/842
230/842
0.009
Empirical Frameworks
149
There is an additional testable implication of the hot potato hypothesis that follows directly from inventories being repeatedly
bounced from dealer to dealer. These inventory management trades
will tend to be in the same direction (i.e., have the same sign). The test
presented in table 5.3 addresses this question: In periods of intense
trading, is order ow less informative when transactions follow the
same direction? Again, we introduce dummy variables, in this case
st , ot , and lt (see the equation heading the table). The dummy st
equals 1 if (1) intertransaction time is short and (2) the previous incoming trade has the same direction, 0 otherwise; the dummy ot
equals 1 if (1) intertransaction time is short and (2) the previous
incoming trade has the opposite direction, 0 otherwise; the dummy lt
equals 0 if intertransaction time is short, 1 otherwise. A short intertransaction time is dened as less than the median of 2 minutes.
Once again, the results are consistent with the hot potato hypothesis. The coefcient b1 short intertransaction times and same
directionis insignicant. In contrast, the coefcient b 0 1 short
intertransaction times and opposite directionis signicant. A test
of the restriction that b1 b 0 1 is rejected at the 1 percent level. To
summarize, in periods of intense trading, trades occurring in the
same direction are signicantly less informative than trades occurring in the opposite direction.
It should be noted, however, that although the hot potato and
event uncertainty hypotheses make opposite predictions regarding
the relation between information and trading intensity, they are not
necessarily exclusive hypotheses. That is, both effects could be operative: hot potato trading may simply dominate when trading is most
intense in this market. We will see in chapter 8 that both effects are
indeed operative in the data.
This chapter reviews the traditional models in exchange rate economics, all of which are macroeconomic in orientation. My objective
is to provide perspective for people working in mainstream nance
who are interested in FX markets, but do not feel they know enough
exchange rate economics to work in the area. (There remains, in my
judgment, much room for intellectual arbitrage, if working on the
world's largest and arguably most important nancial market is not
motivation enough.) Accordingly, presentation of individual models
is rather compact. Fuller treatment is available in the surveys of
Frankel and Rose (1995), Isard (1995), and Taylor (1995).
Before presenting the models, though, I include a section on dening the term ``fundamentals'' as used in exchange rate economics.
Reviewing how exchange rate economists think about fundamentals
should help readers whose perspective on asset valuation comes
primarily from equity markets. At the end of the chapter, I offer a
discussion designed to help loosen the dichotomy in exchange rate
economics between ``micro'' issues and ``macro'' issues. I provide
examples of the sweep of issuesmicro to macroto which one can
apply microstructure tools.
Sections 6.3 and 6.4 address microfoundations. Because traditional
exchange rate models are macroeconomic, to many people their
lack of microeconomic foundations is problematic. Shoring up these
microfoundations is the aim of much recent work in exchange rate
economics. The microstructure approach, too, is an effort to bring
microfoundations to exchange rate economics. However, it does so in
a qualitatively different way because it emphasizes a different set of
microfoundations. Recent work within the asset market approach
emphasizes microfoundations that mirror those emphasized in macroeconomics more generally. These microfoundations are rooted in
152
Chapter 6
153
6:1
where Pi; US is the dollar price of good i in the United States, Pi; UK is
the pound sterling price of good i in Britain, and P$= is the spot exchange rate (dollars per pound).1 PPP simply generalizes this onegood relation to a price index representing multiple goods, like the
consumer price index:
P US P$= P UK ;
6:2
6:3
This goods market view of fundamentals is an important conceptual anchor within exchange rate economics. The PPP relation is
simple and appealing: the exchange rate equals the ratio of the two
national price levels. Now, empirically this relation does not hold at
all times, and departures can be substantial (departures in excess of
30 percent in major U.S. dollar markets are not uncommon). Nevertheless, there is ample evidence that departures dissipate over time,
with a half-life on the order of ve years.2 Thus, in terms of providing a ``center of gravity'' for thinking about exchange rate fundamentals, the PPP relation remains quite valuable.3
FX Fundamentals: The Asset Market View and UIP
Though fundamentals as described by PPP are an important conceptual anchor, this notion of fundamentals is a far cry from the
dividend-discount valuations common in equity markets. The assetmarket approach to exchange rates provides a more comforting
analogue. Within the asset approach, a good way to illustrate fundamentals is with the relation Uncovered Interest Parity.
UIP describes the relationship between expected returns on shortterm, interest-bearing assets denominated in different currencies.
154
Chapter 6
6:4
155
Thus, in a manner similar to a dividend discount model, the exchange rate fundamental is a sum of expected future (one-period)
interest differentials, plus a ``long-run'' value of the exchange rate.5
These future interest differentials are the net cash ows that accrue to
holding foreign currency deposits. The second termthe long-run
valueis typically pinned down with PPP.
6.2
156
Chapter 6
models. Note too that PPP does not provide a direct link to policy, in
particular to monetary policy. By embedding PPP in a model that is
articulated in the monetary dimension, the monetary models provide
that direct link.
The rst of the two monetary models, the exible-price model,
starts with the assumption that PPP always holds (key references
include Mussa 1976 and Frenkel 1976). It is, in fact, a straightforward
extension of the PPP relation: It uses the PPP expression for the exchange rate and substitutes alternative expressions for the two price
levels P US and P UK . Recall that the PPP expression from equation
(6.3) is
P$= P US =P UK :
Taking logarithms of both sides yields an equivalent expression that
is a bit easier to work with:7
p $= p US p UK :
The substitute expressions for p US and p UK come from the heart of
macroeconomicsthe equation describing equilibrium in the money
market.8 The money market is in equilibrium when the supply of
money in real terms (i.e., price adjusted) equals the demand. Demand for money is modeled as a function of both real income
(transactions demand) and the nominal interest rate (an opportunity
cost of holding money). Equilibrium is typically expressed in loglinear form as
m US p US ay US bi $ ;
6:6
6:7
6:8
157
This is the simplest version of the model. The link to money supplies
and therefore monetary policyis clear. The link to the ``exibleprice'' title is less clear. Indeed, in a strict sense we have not used the
assumption of perfectly exible exchange rates and prices: It is not a
necessary condition for PPP, nor is it required for the price-level
expressions in equation (6.6). Instead, the name comes from the need
to distinguish this model from its sticky-price cousin (which we return to below).
Another link that is not yet clear is the model's connection to
expected future macro fundamentals, the hallmark of the asset approach. This link is introduced by adding the UIP relation described
in equation (6.4) above, which pins down expected returns on shortterm interest-bearing assets. Using the UIP relation that i US; t i UK; t
EDp $=; t1 j W t , and suppressing the $/ subscript, we can write
pt f t bEDpt1 j W t ;
6:9
6:10
y
X
i0
gi E f ti j W t ;
6:11
158
Chapter 6
6:12
The only difference is the additional term wt , a wedge term that does
not arise when prices are exible (see, e.g., Flood and Taylor 1996).
The wedge term captures the short-run departure from PPP caused
by sticky prices. Consider for example a shock that shifts the money
supply m, starting from a steady state in which wt 0. This shift can
have an immediate and substantial impact on the exchange rate pt
because that variable is perfectly exible. Because the price level p US
is not perfectly exible, however, this results in a departure from
PPPwt is no longer zero. This effect on wt is transitory, though,
because in the long run prices adjust fully. The difference between
the exible- and sticky-price models is therefore transitory as well.
The sticky-price model is appealing not only because it relaxes the
exible-price model's uncomfortable assumptions, but also because
it can amplify the effect of a change in fundamentals, referred to as
exchange rate overshooting. The appeal of this overshooting result is
that it squares with empirical ndings that exchange rates are excessively volatile when compared with the volatility of fundamentals as
specied in, say, the exible-price model. (Note that high volatility
relative to exible-price fundamentals should not be confused with
high absolute volatility; indeed, changes in major spot rates have
a standard deviation two-thirds that of equity returns: roughly 12
percent per annum, versus 18 percent for the S&P 500.)
The overshooting result is important enough in exchange rate
economics that it deserves attention. A simple experiment provides
some clear intuition. Consider the case of an unexpected, permanent
increase in the money supply, m US . First, in the exible-price model,
the effect is straightforward: a 10 percent increase in money induces
159
Figure 6.1
Illustration of overshooting.
an immediate 10 percent increase in the price level p US (price exibility) and an immediate 10 percent depreciation of the dollar (to restore PPP, which holds at all times). Thus, there is no overshooting,
nor undershooting, because the exchange rate jumps to its long-run
10 percent-depreciated level.
In the sticky-price model, overshooting is best understood using
the UIP relation (equation 6.4). Suppose that before the increase in
money, the economy is in steady state, so i $; t i ; t , EDpt1 j W t 0,
and the price level is not adjusting. Figure 6.1 shows this steady
state, before the time labeled t. Now, a key difference in the stickyprice model is that by assumption the increase in money has no immediate effect on the price level. Therefore, from equation (6.6), the
increase in money supply requires an immediate fall in i $ to clear the
money market, so that now i $ < i ; this is the usual liquidity effect of
an increase in the money supply (output y is xed in simple versions
of the model). Consider the immediate effect of the fall in i $ on the
exchange rate: the dollar should depreciate (an increase in p $= ), but
by how much? Recall that the exible-price model produces an immediate 10 percent dollar depreciation to its new long-run level
neither overshooting nor undershooting. Suppose the sticky-price
model is the samean immediate 10 percent dollar depreciation to
the same long-run level (pinned down by PPP), with EDpt1 j W t 0
thereafter, labeled as point A in gure 6.1. But point A cannot be an
160
Chapter 6
equilibrium: if i $ < i , then UIP, which holds by assumption, is violated (i.e., i $ < i and EDpt1 j W t 0 are incompatible). This rules
out equilibrium at point A. Either overshooting or undershooting
must occur.12
To see which is the right answer (overshooting or undershooting),
we need to determine which is consistent with UIP. Note from
equation (6.4) that with i $ < i , it must be that EDpt1 j W t < 0, that
is, the dollar must be expected to appreciate in the future (a lower
dollar price of the pounda negative Dpt1 is dollar appreciation).
Intuitively, this future dollar appreciation is needed to compensate
dollar depositors for a lower interest rate.13 But the only way that the
dollar can appreciate toward its long-run 10-percent-depreciated
level in the future is if the dollar depreciates today by more than 10
percent, making room for the necessary trend appreciation. No other
path is compatible with UIP. The dollar must overshoot.
An important reason I have included additional detail on this
model is that it provides some intuition for the impact of a change in
interest rates on the exchange rate. Understanding this interest rate/
exchange rate link is important for the following two macro-oriented
chapters. Note from gure 6.1 that the drop in i $ induces immediate
dollar depreciation (an increase in the dollar price of a pound). This
is consistent with most people's intuition: lower dollar interest
rates make dollar deposits less attractive, other things equal, causing
portfolios to shift out of the dollar.
Portfolio Balance Model
Though still squarely anchored in the asset approach, the portfolio
balance model departs from the monetary models in two essential
ways (key references include Kouri and Porter 1974 and the survey
by Branson and Henderson 1985). First, of the four asset-approach
models, this is the only one without PPP as an ingredient. This
means the long-run exchange rate must be pinned down some other
way. Second, this model does not impose UIP, and thus, expected
dollar returns on different-currency deposits need not be equal. This
leaves room for a currency risk premium, that is, an expected return
bonus for holding particular currencies. The macro literature refers
to this as imperfect substitutability between domestic and foreign
assets (the same term introduced in the micro material in chapter 2).
The portfolio balance model is, as its name suggests, a model
which balances demand for various asset classes against supply. The
161
exchange rate brings them into balance. The exchange rate achieves
this by affecting demand/supply in two ways. First, an expected
change in the exchange rate affects foreign-asset demand because it
has a direct effect on the expected dollar return on foreign assets (the
right side of equation 6.4). Second, the level of the exchange rate
affects foreign-asset supply. This works over time through a traditional macro channel, the trade balance: a lower value of the dollar
pushes the trade balance toward surplus, which, through the balance
of payments, increases foreign assets in domestic portfolios.14
A simple specication of this model includes three demand functions, one for each of three available asset classes: money (M), domestic bonds (B), and foreign bonds in foreign currency (B ). Each of
these demands depends on the same two variables: the domestic
nominal interest rate i and the expected dollar return on foreigncurrency bonds i E%DP, where i is the foreign nominal interest
rate and E%DP is the expected percent depreciation of the dollar. (It
is best to think of these as short-term bonds with no capital gains/
losses from interest rate changes.)
Money Demand M D i; i E%DP
M1D
< 0;
M2D
with
<0
6:13
B2D < 0
6:14
B1D < 0;
with
B2D > 0
with
6:15
162
Chapter 6
DB S TP i B D
6:16
with
T1 > 0:
6:17
163
164
6.3
Chapter 6
The terms ``microfoundations'' and ``tastes and technology'' are common in macroeconomics, but less familiar outside. Microfoundations refers to the grounding of analysis in well-dened decision
problems faced by individuals or groups. Grounding analysis this
way is standard within microeconomics, hence the prex micro. In
microeconomic analysis, individuals have a clear sense of both their
objectives and constraints, and they do their best to fulll their
objectives. These well-dened objectives are called ``tastes'' because
they embody the preferences of individuals for various outcomes.15
The constraints in macro models with microfoundations are called
``technology.'' Technology encompasses the production side of the
real economy (or the endowment process in a pure exchange economy) and denes the feasible choicesthe size of the pie.
Though the three macro models reviewed in the previous section
are not grounded in well-dened problems faced by individuals, the
fourth of our macro modelsthe general equilibrium (GE) model
is. The microfoundations of the GE exchange rate model are the same
as those adopted more generally in macroeconomicsthe ``two T's''
of tastes and technology. As one might imagine, though, a grounding in tastes and technology can still accommodate many different
specications. Here I review the specication of the GE model only
at a broad level. Though details are missing, a broad perspective is
sufcient for clarifying how the GE model's microfoundations differ
from the microfoundations of the microstructure approach.16
General Equilibrium Model
The GE model of exchange rate determination begins with maximization of a representative individual's utility.17 Specication of
utility as a function of various consumption opportunities has, naturally, important implications for equilibrium exchange rates. (The
microstructure approach also includes utility maximization, but as
we saw in chapter 4, utility is specied very simply, typically in
terms of terminal nominal wealth.) The rm grounding in utility is
the taste part of the model's microfoundations. The technology part
of the model's microfoundations lies in the models' tightly specied
production and transaction technologies. The production technology
summarizes all input-output relationships in the production of real
165
166
Chapter 6
167
Though the notion of microfoundations helps to organize thinking, the orientation can be misleading because issues in exchange
rate economicsas elsewhere in nancial economicsdo not divide
168
Chapter 6
Figure 6.2
Three approaches to exchange rates and their models. PPP denotes purchasing power parity model. FPM denotes exibleprice monetary model. SPM denotes sticky-price monetary model. PBM denotes portfolio balance model. GE denotes
general equilibrium model.
169
Figure 6.3
Issues spectrum.
neatly into ``micro'' issues and ``macro'' issues. Instead, issues fall
along a spectrum, as gure 6.3 shows.
The more micro end of the spectrum includes issues such as optimal market design, efcient regulation, and the determination of
transaction costs. These are bread and butter issues within microstructure research. The more macro end includes issues such as
medium/long-run exchange rate determination, forward-discount
bias, and home bias (the rst two of which I address in detail in
the next chapter). Between the extremes are issues such as volatility
determination, central bank intervention, and transaction taxes
(the rst of which I address in chapter 7 and the second in chapter
8).20
It is important, in my judgment, to distinguish between tools and
the issues to which they are applied. I introduce the issues spectrum
not only to frame the later chapters, but also because it helps explain
the gap between exchange rate economics on the one hand and
microstructure nance on the other. Within microstructure nance,
the tools have been applied to bread and butter microeconomic
issues that, for the most part, do not interest macro-oriented exchange rate economists. Though one might suppose that because
these tools were developed for micro issues they are not likely to
help with macro issues, they are actually quite useful. The analysis in
chapters 7 and 8 (on longer horizon exchange rate determination,
central bank intervention, etc.) will demonstrate this.
An example may clarify why exchange rate economists view
microstructure with skepticism. The example comes from the call
for papers that initiated a market microstructure research group
in the United States (the group is part of the National Bureau of
Economic Research). The call for papers came with a list of topics
a list that was important for dening the scope and spirit of
the group's agenda. Though all eleven topics are bread and butter
microstructure, macroeconomists might quickly dismiss them. The
topics include:
170
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
Chapter 6
172
Chapter 7
Exchange rate economics has been in crisis since Meese and Rogoff
(1983a) showed that our models are empirical failures: the proportion of monthly exchange rate changes our textbook models can
explain is essentially zero. In their survey, Frankel and Rose (1995,
1704, 1708) summarize as follows:
The Meese and Rogoff analysis at short horizons has never been convincingly overturned or explained. It continues to exert a pessimistic effect on the
eld of empirical exchange rate modeling in particular and international
nance in general. . . . Such results indicate that no model based on such
standard fundamentals like money supplies, real income, interest rates, ination rates, and current account balances will ever succeed in explaining or
predicting a high percentage of the variation in the exchange rate, at least at
short- or medium-term frequencies.1
Macro Puzzles
173
exchange rates may be determined, in part, from avoidable expectational errors (Dominguez 1986; Frankel and Froot 1987; Hau 1998).
On a priori grounds, many nancial economists nd this second alternative unappealing. Even if one is sympathetic, however, there is a
wide gulf between the presence of nonrational behavior and accounting for exchange rates empirically.3
This section addresses the determination puzzle using the microstructure approach, drawing heavily from work presented in Evans
and Lyons (1999). One advantage of the microstructure approach is
that it directs attention to variables that have escaped the attention of
macroeconomists. Meese (1990, 130) offers a telling quote along these
lines: ``Omitted variables is another possible explanation for the lack
of explanatory power in asset market models. However, empirical
researchers have shown considerable imagination in their specication searches, so it is not easy to think of variables that have escaped
consideration in an exchange-rate equation.'' Among the variables
escaping consideration, order ow may be the most important. As
we saw in chapter 4, order ow is the proximate determinant of price
in microstructure models, regardless of institutional structure. This
ensures that the causal role played by order ow is robust to different market structures.
A Hybrid Model with Both Macro and Micro Determinants
To establish a link between the micro and macro approaches, chapter
1 introduces models with components from both. The hybrid model I
suggest in that rst chapter takes the form:
DPt f i; m; z gX; I; Z et
where the function f i; m; z is the macro component of the model
and gX; I; Z is the microstructure component. Chapters 4, 5, and 6
provide explicit specications for how interest rates i, money supplies m, order ows X, and inventories I might enter these two functions. (Recall that z and Z denote unspecied other determinants.)
An important take-away from those chapters is that f i; m; z and
gX; I; Z depend on more than just current and past values of
their determinantsthey also depend, crucially, on expectations of
determinants' future values. This stands to reason: rational markets
are forward looking, so these expectations are important for setting
prices today.
174
Chapter 7
Though I have split this stylized hybrid model into two parts, the
two parts are not necessarily independent. This will depend on the
main micro determinantorder ow Xand the type of information it conveys. Per chapters 1 and 2, order ow conveys two main
information types: payoff information and discount rate information. In macro models, information about future payoffs translates to
information about future i; m; z. One way order ow can convey
information about future i; m; z is by aggregating the information
in individuals' expectations of i; m; z. (Recall that as a measure of
expectations, order ow reects people's willingness to back their
beliefs with money; and like actual expectations, this measure
evolves rapidly, in contrast to measures derived from macro data.)
When order ow conveys payoff information, macro and micro
determinants are interdependent: order ow acts as a proximate determinant of price, but standard macro fundamentals are the underlying determinant.4
If order ow X conveys discount rate information only, then the
two sets of determinants i; m; z and X; I; Z can indeed be independent. To understand why, suppose the discount rate information
conveyed by order ow X is about portfolio balance effects (e.g.,
persistent changes in discount rates, due to changing risk preferences, changing hedging demands, or changing liquidity demands
under imperfect substitutabilitysee chapter 2).5 Now, consider the
two monetary macro models (exible and sticky-price). Portfolio
balance effects from order ow X are unrelated to these models'
specications of f i; m; z. This is because the monetary models assume that different-currency assets are perfect substitutes (i.e., they
assume that Uncovered Interest Parity holds: assets differing only in
their currency denomination have the same expected return). Thus,
effects from imperfect substitutability are necessarily independent of
the f i; m; z of these monetary models. In the case of the macro
portfolio balance model, in contrast, portfolio balance effects from
order ow X are quite likely to be related to the determining variables i; m; z. Indeed, in that model, price effects from imperfect
substitutability are the focus of f i; m; z.6
Consider the hybrid model from a different perspectivea graphical perspective. The top panel of gure 7.1 illustrates the connection
between fundamentals and price under the traditional macro view
(i.e., as reected in the models of chapter 6). Information about
fundamentals is publicly known, and so is the mapping from that
Macro Puzzles
175
Figure 7.1
Spanning macro and microstructure graphically. The top panel illustrates the connection between fundamentals and price under the traditional macro view (i.e., as
reected in the models of chapter 6): information about fundamentals is public, and so
is the mapping to price, so price adjustment is direct and immediate. The middle panel
shows the traditional microstructure view (as reected in the models of chapter 4). The
focus in that case is fundamental information that is not publicly known. This type of
information is rst transformed into order ow, which becomes a signal to the price
setter (e.g., dealer) that price needs to be adjusted. Actual markets include both, which
is illustrated in the bottom panelthe hybrid view.
176
Chapter 7
Macro Puzzles
177
Figure 7.2
Daily timing in the Evans-Lyons model.
model in gure 7.3 (in the same manner that I use gures to summarize each of the models of chapter 4).
There are N dealers in the model, indexed by i, a continuum of
nondealer customers (the public), and an innite number of trading
days. Dealers and customers all have negative exponential utility.
Within each day, there are three rounds of trading:
Round 1: Dealers trade with the public
Round 2: Dealers trade among themselves to share risk
Round 3: Dealers trade with the public to share risk more broadly.
Figure 7.2 shows the timing within each day.
At the beginning of each day, the payoff to holding foreign exchange is Rt , which is composed of a series of increments DRt , so that
Rt
t
X
DRt :
7:1
t1
The payoff increments DRt are i.i.d. Normal0; sR2 and are observed
publicly at the beginning of each day. These realized increments
represent the ow of public macroeconomic informationthe macro
component of the model f i; m; z. For concreteness, one can think of
this abstract payoff increment DRt as changes in interest rates.
Per gure 7.2, after observing the payoff Rt , each dealer sets a
quote for his public customers. As in the simultaneous-trade model,
quotes are scalar two-way prices, set simultaneously and independently.7 Denote this dealer i quote in round 1 of day t as Pit1 . Evans
and Lyons show that in equilibrium, all dealers choose to quote the
same price, denoted Pt1 . Each dealer then receives a customer-order
realization Cit1 that is executed at his quoted price Pt1 , where Cit1 < 0 denotes a customer sale (dealer i purchase). Each of these N customer-
178
Chapter 7
Figure 7.3
Summary of the Evans-Lyons (1999) model.
N
X
i1
Cit1 :
Macro Puzzles
179
N
X
Tit :
7:2
i1
7:3
180
Chapter 7
7:4
t
X
t1
DRt b 2
t
X
t1
Xt :
7:5
Macro Puzzles
181
The change in price from the end of day t 1 to the end of day t can
therefore be written as:
DPt b 1 DRt b2 Xt :
7:6
N
X
i1
Tit aCt1 :
Xt z
t
X
t1
Ct1 :
182
Chapter 7
asset supply, in the sense that shifts out of FX are an increase in the
net supply that the remainder of the public must absorb. (I couch this
in terms of supply to connect with traditional portfolio balance intuition, as outlined in chapter 6.) The total increase in net supply is
the sum of past portfolio shifts out of FX:
Increase in net supply
t
X
t1
Ct1 :
Figure 7.4
Portfolio balance effects: one-period example. The market-clearing gap EV P0 is a
function of the risky asset's net supply. In traditional portfolio balance models, variation in gross supply is the driver. In the Evans-Lyons model, gross supply is xed, but
net supply is moving over time due to shifts in demand that are unrelated to EV P0 .
These demand shifts are the exogenous realizations of Cit1 . In contrast to the dissipation
of the portfolio balance effect on price in the one-period example, the price effects do
not dissipate in the Evans-Lyons model because payoff uncertainty is resolved
smoothly over time.
Macro Puzzles
183
184
Chapter 7
7:7
Macro Puzzles
185
where Dpt is the change in the log spot rate (DM/$ or yen/$) from
the end of day t 1 to the end of day t, Dit it is the change in the
overnight interest differential from day t 1 to day t ( denotes DM
or yen), and Xt is the interdealer order ow from the end of day t 1
to the end of day t (negative denotes net dollar sales).
There are two changes in this equation relative to equation (7.6).
First, the payoff increment DRt in equation (7.6) represents the macro
innovations in the model, or f i; m; z. For estimation, Evans and
Lyons have to take a stand on what to include in the regression for
DRt . They choose to include changes in the nominal interest differential; that is, they dene DRt Dit it , where it is the nominal
dollar interest rate and it is the nominal non-dollar interest rate (DM
or yen). As a measure of variation in macro fundamentals, the interest differential is obviously incomplete. The reason Evans and Lyons
do not specify a full-blown macro model is because other macro
variables (e.g., money supply, output, etc.) are not available at the
daily frequency. Accordingly, one should not view their model as
fully accommodating both the macro and micro approaches. At the
same time, if one were to choose a single macro determinant that
needs to be included, interest rates would be it: Innovations in interest differentials are the main engine of exchange rate variation in
macro models (e.g., the sticky-price monetary model).14 Moreover,
using the change in the interest differential rather than the level is
consistent with monetary macro models: in monetary models, shocks
to price are driven by unanticipated changes in the differential.15
The second difference in equation (7.7) relative to (7.6) is the replacement of the change in the level of price DPt with the change in
the log price Dpt . This difference makes their estimation more directly
comparable to previous macro specications, as those specications
use the log change (which is approximately equal to a percentage
change). As an empirical matter, using Dpt is inconsequential: the
two different measures for the change in price produce nearly identical results.
Table 7.1 presents estimates of the Evans-Lyons model (equation
7.7) using daily data for the DM/$ and yen/$ exchange rates. The
coefcient b2 on order ow Xt is correctly signed and signicant,
with t-statistics above ve in both equations. To see that the sign is
correct, recall from the model that net purchases of dollarsa positive Xt should lead to a higher DM price of dollars. The traditional
186
Chapter 7
Table 7.1
Estimates of the Evans-Lyons Model
Dpt b1 Dit it b 2 Xt ht
b1
b2
R2
DM
0.52
(1.5)
2.10
(10.5)
0.64
Yen
2.48
(2.7)
2.90
(6.3)
0.45
T-statistics are shown in parentheses. (In the case of the DM equation, the t-statistics
are corrected for heteroskedasticity; there is no evidence of heteroskedasticity in the
yen equation, and no evidence of serial correlation in either equation.) The dependent
variable Dpt is the change in the log spot exchange rate from 4 p.m. gmt on day t 1 to
4 p.m. gmt on day t (DM/$ or yen/$). The regressor Dit it is the change in the oneday interest differential from day t 1 to day t ( denotes DM or yen, annual basis).
The regressor Xt is interdealer order ow between 4 p.m. gmt on day t 1 and 4 p.m.
gmt on day t (negative for net dollar sales, in thousands of transactions). Estimated
using OLS. The sample spans four months (May 1 to August 31, 1996), which is 89
trading days. (Saturday and Sunday order owof which there is littleis included
in Monday.)
Macro Puzzles
187
188
Chapter 7
tions structurally. Fifth, Evans and Lyons decompose contemporaneous order ow into expected and unexpected components (by
projecting order ow on past ow). In their model, all order ow Xt
is unexpected, but this need not be the case in the data (in fact, daily
order ow is essentially unforecastable using past ow). They nd,
as one would expect, that order ow's explanatory power comes
from its unexpected component.
Isn't This Just Demand Increases Driving Price Increases?
At rst blush, it might appear that the Evans-Lyons results are right
out of Economics 101: of course when demand goes up, price goes
up. But this misses the most important lesson. A premise of textbook
exchange rate models (chapter 6) is that we don't need order ow to
push prices around. Rather, when public information arrives, rational markets adjust price instantaneously (i.e., excess demand from
new information causes price to adjust without trading needing to
take place). That order ow explains such a large percentage of price
moves underscores the inadequacy of this public information framework. The information the FX market is aggregating is much subtler
than textbook models assume. This we learn from our order ow
regressions.
But What Drives Order Flow?
An important challenge for the microstructure approach is determining what drives order ow, that is, the rst link in the fundamentals/
order ow/price chain (gure 7.1). Here are three promising strategies for shedding light on this question. Strategy one is to disaggregate order ow. For example, interdealer order ow can be
split into large banks versus small banks, or investment banks versus
commercial banks. Data sets on customer order ow can be split
into nonnancial corporations, leveraged nancial institutions (e.g.,
hedge funds), and unleveraged nancial institutions (e.g., mutual
and pension funds). Do all these trade types have the same price
impact? Someone believing that order ow is just undifferentiated
demand would predict that they do. In fact, they do not, as we shall
see in chapter 9. Certain types of orders (e.g., those from nancial
institutions) convey more information, and therefore have more
price impact. People who view order ow as undifferentiated de-
Macro Puzzles
189
190
Chapter 7
Macro Puzzles
191
192
Chapter 7
Price P X; BX; Z1 ; Z2 :
Price P depends both directly and indirectly on order ow X. The
indirect effect is through beliefs BX; Z1 , where Z1 and Z2 denote
other determinants. This is the information role ignored in early
attempts to analyze equilibrium with differentially informed traders.
Since the advent of rational expectations, models that ignore this information effect from order ow are viewed as less compelling.
7.3
This section addresses the second of the big three puzzles: the excess
volatility puzzle. By excess we mean that exchange rates are much
more volatile than our best measures of fundamentals. Though other
asset markets share this property (e.g., stock markets; see Shiller
1981), the puzzle in FX markets is in many ways distinctive.22 Consider, for example, the fact that most exchange rates are not allowed
to oat freely; many are managed through intervention by central
banks. This allows one to address the volatility puzzle in ways not
possible in other markets. To understand why, note rst that exchange rates are generally less volatile when managed. Given this,
one can compare regimes with different management intensities to
identify why volatility differs, thereby shedding light on the volatility's causes. This approach is common in the literature (e.g., Flood
and Rose 1995; Killeen, Lyons, and Moore 2000a). The analysis I
present here draws primarily on the empirical ndings of Killeen,
Lyons, and Moore (KLM).
Before reviewing the KLM ndings, let me provide more perspective on the ``cross-regime'' approach to exchange rate volatility.23
Why is it that similar macro environments produce more volatility
Macro Puzzles
193
when exchange rates oat freely? There are two main approaches
to this question, one theoretical and one empirical. The theoretical
approach was pioneered by Dornbusch (1976) in his sticky-price
monetary model (see chapter 6). Dornbusch shows that when goods
prices are sticky but the exchange rate is free to jump, then economic
shocks have a disproportionately large effect on the exchange rate
so-called overshooting. From the perspective of excess volatility, the
sticky-price monetary model generates the kind of ``amplication''
that might explain why oating rates are more volatile than fundamentals. This theoretical explanation is not borne out empirically,
however: the sticky-price model does not t the data.
The second main approach to why oating rates are more volatile
is empirical. A good example is Flood and Rose (1995, 5), who put
the cross-regime logic as follows:
Intuitively, if exchange rate stability arises across regimes without corresponding variation in macroeconomic volatility, then macroeconomic variables will be unable to explain much exchange rate volatility. Thus existing
models, such as monetary models, do not pass our test; indeed, this is also
true of any potential model that depends on standard macroeconomic variables. We are driven to the conclusion that the most critical determinants of
exchange rate volatility are not macroeconomic.
The central idea here starts with the Flood-Rose nding that managing rates does not change the volatility of fundamentals (fundamentals as described by the models of chapter 6). So if the volatility
reduction from managing rates is not coming from changed behavior
of these fundamentals, then it is unlikely these are critical fundamentals. In a sense, then, the Flood-Rose conclusion deepens the puzzle.
KLM take a different tackthey exploit a natural experiment,
using the switch from the European Monetary System (EMS) to
European Monetary Union (EMU), which in terms of regimes is a
switch from a target zone to a rigidly xed rate.24 Starting in January
1999, the euro country currencies have been rigidly xed to one
another. Before January 1999, howeverparticularly before May
1998there was still uncertainty about which countries would participate in EMU. There was also uncertainty about the timing of interest rate harmonization (which had to occur among the countries
adopting the euro).
KLM's analysis of this experiment leads them to the following
punchline: exchange rates are more volatile under exible rates because of order ow. Order ow conveys more information under
194
Chapter 7
exible rates, which increases volatility. Fixed exchange rates prevent order ow from conveying informationas a driver of returns,
it is ``turned off.'' The intuition for why this happens is tied to demand elasticity. Under oating, the elasticity of public demand is
(endogenously) low, due to higher volatility and aversion to the risk
this higher volatility entails. This makes room for the types of portfolio balance effects that arise in the Evans-Lyons model, and allows
order ow to convey information about those effects. Under (perfectly credible) xed rates, the elasticity of public demand is innite:
return volatility shrinks to zero, making the holding of foreign exchange effectively riskless. This eliminates portfolio balance effects
and precludes order ow from conveying this type of information.
Consequently, order ow as a return driver is shut down.25
Figure 7.5 provides an initial, suggestive illustration of the KLM
results. It shows the relationship between the FF/DM exchange rate
and cumulative order ow (interdealer order ow from EBSsee
below). The vertical line is May 4, 1998, the rst trading day after the
announcement of the conversion rates of the euro-participating currencies. The relationship between the two series before May 4 is
clearly positive: the correlation is 0.69. After May 4indeed, even a
bit before May 4there is a sharp unwinding of long DM positions
with no corresponding movement in the exchange rate. The effect of
order ow on the exchange rate appears to have changed from one of
clear impact to one of no impact. (Though total variation in the exchange rate is small, from a trading perspective the variation in the
January to May period is signicant.) The model KLM develop provides a more formal framework for addressing this issue (to which I
now turn).
The Killeen-Lyons-Moore Model
The KLM model is a variation on the Evans-Lyons model of section
7.1. The intraday trading structures of the two models are identical.
(Accordingly, my exposition is fullest where the two models depart.)
The key difference is the interday structure: in the KLM model,
trading days fall into one of two regimes, a exible-rate regime followed by a xed-rate regime. The shift from exible to xed rates is a
random event that arrives with constant probability p at the end of
each trading day (after all trading). Once the regime has shifted to
xed rates it remains there indenitely. This formulation has two
Figure 7.5
The level of the FF/DM exchange rate (solid) and cumulative interdealer order ow (dashed) over EBS in 1998.
196
Chapter 7
Figure 7.6
Two trading regimes. Under the exible-rate regime, payoff increments DRt are distributed Normally, with mean zero and variance SR . The shift from exible to xed
rates is a random event, the arrival of which is shown here at the end of day T. Once
the regime has shifted to xed rates it remains there indenitely. On the rst morning
of the xed-rate regime, the central bank (credibly) commits to pegging the exchange
rate at the previous day's closing price and maintains DRt 0 thereafter.
The DRt increments are observed publicly each day before all trading. As before, these increments represent innovations over time in
public macroeconomic information (e.g., changes in interest rates).
Under the exible-rate regime, the DRt increments are i.i.d. Normal
0; sR2 . On the rst morning of the xed-rate regime, the central bank
(credibly) commits to pegging the exchange rate at the previous
day's closing price and maintains DRt 0 thereafter. FX dealers and
customers all have identical negative exponential utility, with coefcient of absolute risk aversion y. The gross return on the risk free
asset is equal to one.
Figures 7.2 and 7.6 describe the intraday and interday timing of
the model, respectively. (Figure 7.2 appears above in my review
of the Evans-Lyons model.) Within each day, there are three rounds
of trading: rst dealers trade with the public, then dealers trade
among themselves (to share the resulting inventory risk), and nally
dealers trade again with the public (to share inventory risk more
Macro Puzzles
197
N
X
i1
Cit1 :
N
X
Tit :
7:9
i1
where
7:10
198
Chapter 7
3
g z Var1 DPt1
Rt1 :
b
Xt
under exible rates t U T
b
>
t
1
2
>
< t1
t1
Pt
T
T
t
>
X
X
X
>
>
>
DR
b
X
b
Xt under xed rates t > T
b
>
t
t
1
2
3
:
t1
t1
tT1
7:11
The parameters b2 and b3 are the price impact parametersthey
govern the price impact of order ow. These b's depend inversely on
g (the return sensitivity of public demand); they also depend on the
variances sR2 and sC2 .
The message of equation (7.11) is important. It says that in the
exible regime, there should be a cointegrating relationship between
the level of the exchange rate, cumulative macro fundamentals
DRt , and cumulative interdealer order ow Xt .27 This prediction is
striking: in textbook exchange rate models there is no relationship
between order ow and exchange rates, much less a long-run relationship as implied by cointegration. An implication is that order
ow's impact on exchange rates is permanent (which is also true in
the Evans-Lyons model). This speaks directly to the theme in chapter
1 that microstructure variables can have long-lived effects. (Permanent impact does not imply that order ow cannot also have transitory effects, particularly intraday. In this model, though, inventory
effects across days are ruled out, as explained in section 7.1.)
Differences across Exchange Rate Regimes
We want to understand how the role of order ow differs under different exchange rate regimes. To do so, consider equations (7.9) and
Macro Puzzles
199
7:12
7:13
This says that exchange rates react more to order ow under exible
rates than they do under xed rates. In the limit of xed rates that are
perfectly credible (i.e., for which VarDPt1 Rt1 j Wt3 0), we have
b 3 0:
7:14
The exchange rate does not respond to order ow in this case. The
intuition is simple enough: Under perfect credibility, the variance of
exchange rate returns goes to zero because public demand is perfectly elastic, and vice versa. (If the xed regime were less than 100
percent credible, then public demand would not be inniteFX
would still be a risky asset.)
Further Intuition for the Solution
Consider PT1 , the price at the close of the rst day of the xed-rate
regime. Forex is a riskless asset at this point, with return variance
equal to zero. With a return variance equal to zero, the elasticity of
public demand is innite and the price impact parameter b3 in
equation (7.11) equals zero. This yields a price at the close of trading
(round 3) on day T 1 of
PT1 b1
T
X
t1
DRt b2
T
X
Xt :
t1
The summation over the payoff increment DRt does not include an
increment for day T 1 because the central bank maintains DRt at
zero in the xed regime. Though XT1 is not equal to zero, this has
no effect on price because b 3 0, as noted. This logic holds throughout the xed-rate regime.
200
Chapter 7
T
X
t1
DRt b2
T
X
Xt :
t1
T
X
t1
Ct1 :
Macro Puzzles
201
202
Chapter 7
b
Xt
under exible rates t U T
>
t
2
>
< 1 t1
t1
Pt
T
T
t
>
X
X
>
> X
>
DR
b
X
b
Xt under xed rates t > T
b
>
t
t
1
2
3
:
t1
t1
tT1
Like Evans and Lyons (1999), KLM use the interest differential as the
public-information variable (the Paris interbank offer rate minus the
Frankfurt interbank offer rate).
The KLM model predicts that before May 4, 1998, all these variables are nonstationary and are cointegrated. After May 4, the model
predicts that the exchange rate converges to its conversion rate, and
should be stationary. During this latter period (May to December),
therefore, equation (7.11) only makes sense if the price-impact co-
Macro Puzzles
203
204
Chapter 7
ing vector directly, this is exactly what they nd: they cannot reject
that the interest differential has a coefcient of zero. By contrast, the
coefcient on cumulative order ow is highly signicant and correctly signed. (The size of the coefcient implies that a 1 percent increase in cumulative order ow moves the spot rate by about 5 basis
points.29) These ndings of cointegration and an order ow coefcient that is correctly signed are supportive of their model's emphasis on order ow in the long run. At the same time, the lack of
explanatory power in the interest differential suggests that this specialization of the payoff increment DRt is decient (in keeping with
the negative results of the macro literature more generally).
Exogeneity of Order Flow
An important question facing the microstructure approach is the degree to which causality can be viewed as running strictly from order
ow to the exchange rate, rather than running in both directions. The
KLM framework provides a convenient way to address this question. In particular, if a system of variables is cointegrated, then it
has an error-correction representation (see Engle and Granger 1987;
also Hamilton 1994, 580581). These error-correction representations
provide clues about the direction of causality. Specically, the errorcorrection representation allows one to determine whether the burden of adjustment to long-run equilibrium falls on the exchange rate,
on cumulative order ow, or both. If adjustment falls at least in part
on order ow, then order ow is responding to the rest of the system
(i.e., it is not exogenous in the way specied by the Evans-Lyons and
KLM models).
The KLM ndings suggest that causality is indeed running strictly
from order ow to price, and not the other way around. KLM test
this by estimating the error-correction term in both the exchange rate
and order ow equations (exible-rate period, JanuaryApril). They
nd that the error-correction term is highly signicant in the exchange rate equation, whereas the error-correction term in the order
ow equation is insignicant. This implies that adjustment to longrun equilibrium is occurring via the exchange rate. More intuitively,
when a gap opens in the long-run relationship between cumulative order
ow and the exchange rate, it is the exchange rate that adjusts to reduce the
gap, not cumulative order ow. In the parlance of the literature, the in-
Macro Puzzles
205
206
Chapter 7
Macro Puzzles
207
clude Hodrick 1987; Froot and Thaler 1990; Lewis 1995; Engel 1996).
The bias is such that when Ft; 1 > Pt today's one-period forward
rate is ``predicting'' that the spot rate will risethe spot rate does not
tend to rise as much as predicted (i.e., Pt1 typically ends up below
Ft; 1 ).31 In fact, among the major oating currencies against the dollar,
when the forward rate predicts the spot rate will rise, it usually falls!
The forward rate systematically gets the direction wrong.
In this section, I consider the puzzle from three angles: the statistician's perspective, the economist's perspective, and the practitioner's perspective. My explanation for the bias draws heavily from
the practitioner's perspective.
The Statistician's Perspective
Viewed as a regression, the test for bias in forward rates is based on
the following equation:
pt1 pt a b ft; 1 pt ut1
7:15
208
Chapter 7
Figure 7.7
Statistician's perspective on forward bias. H0 denotes the null hypothesis.
Macro Puzzles
209
210
Chapter 7
ERs Rrf
;
ss
7:16
where ERs is the expected return on the strategy, Rrf is the risk-free
interest rate, and ss is the standard deviation of the returns to the
strategy.35 Over the last fty years, the Sharpe ratio for a buy-andhold strategy in U.S. equities has been about 0.4 on an annual basis
(the excess return in the numerator is about 7 percent and annualized
return standard deviation in the denominator is about 17 percent).
Under the null hypothesis of no bias in the forward rate (b 1 in
equation 1), the Sharpe ratio of currency strategies is zerothere is
no expected return differential (i.e., ft; 1 does not tend to over-predict
subsequent spot rate changes). As b departs from 1, however, the
numerator becomes positive. The larger the bias, the larger the
numerator. The denominator, on the other hand, is not a function of
the bias. Rather, it is determined by exchange rate variances and
covariances. Another determinant of the denominator is the number
of exchange rates included in the currency trading strategya
greater number of currencies provides more diversication, other
things equal.
Strikingly, it is only when b equals about 1 or 3 that the Sharpe ratio
for currency strategies is about the same as that of equities, or 0.4. (This
assumes a currency strategy that diversies across the six largest
markets; I provide further details below.) If b falls anywhere in the
interval 1; 3, then a currency strategy designed to exploit bias has
a lower return per unit risk than a simple equity investment.
From the practitioner's perspective, the two-standard-error band
that the statistician draws around the null of b 1 misses the point.
If instead, I draw a band around the null of b 1 that corresponds to
speculative signicanceas opposed to statistical signicancethen
the reality looks more like that shown in gure 7.8. If a Sharpe ratio
of 0.4 is the practitioner's threshold for determining tradable opportunities, then the interval from b 1 to b 3 would not be attractive. These values for b dene an inaction rangea range within
which the forward rate bias does not attract speculative capital.
Viewed this way, the puzzle of forward bias is not a glaring prot
opportunity.
Macro Puzzles
211
Figure 7.8
Practitioner's perspective on forward bias. H0 denotes the null hypothesis.
Anomaly Persistence
Part one of the explanation may seem intuitively obvious: ``If speculative capital is not allocated to exploiting the forward bias, then the
forward bias will persist'' But it deserves a closer look. A skeptic
would rightly assert that order ow is not necessary to move price.
212
Chapter 7
By this logic, if the current spot rate or the current forward rate (or
both) are at an incorrect level, and this is common knowledge within
the market, then these rates should adjust immediately to the correct
level, without any role for order ow. This logic would seem to hold
particularly well in the foreign exchange market. After all, goes the
traditional view, all fundamental information in this market is public
information. This is not a market that needs order ow to move price
(as compared to, say, the market for a particular stock, where order
ow can communicate inside information about earnings).
There is a big leap of faith, however, between the true statement
that ``order ow is not necessary to move price'' and the belief that,
in fact, ``order ow plays little role in moving price.''36 Consider two
points that clarify why this leap of faith is so bigone theoretical
and the other empirical.
Theory claries the conditions under which order ow plays no
role, conditions that do not hold in the FX market (see also chapter
2). Specically, unless both of the following are true, order ow will
play a role in moving price: (1) all information relevant for exchange
rates is publicly known, and (2) the mapping from that information
to prices is also publicly known. The second of these conditions is
patently violated. Even the rst is unlikely to hold (e.g., it does not
hold in the Evans-Lyons model, which includes a rather natural information structure).
Empirical evidence also runs counter to the view that ``order ow
plays little role in moving price.'' Section 7.1 shows that the effects of
order ow on price are quite strong. Moreover, the R 2 statistics
reported in that section indicate that order ow accounts for the
lion's share of exchange rate variation.
Part 2:
Macro Puzzles
213
able (so its impact on prices and returns cannot be ruled out on simple theoretical grounds).
This part of the explanation is the most contentious because, absent other frictions, capital should not be allocated based on ``variance'' risk. Rather, capital should be allocated based on covariance
with some larger objective (e.g., covariance with the market return,
as in the Capital Asset Pricing Model). Empirically, the covariance
between returns on, say, the MSCI World Equity Index and returns
on bias-exploiting currency strategies is small. This suggests that the
risk of currency strategies is largely diversiable. Thus, though their
return-per-unit total risk may be low, their return-per-unit systematic
risk is hightoo high to be consistent with standard covariance
models (i.e., too high for people who are concerned with covariance
not to take advantage). Hence, from the covariance perspective, the
puzzle endures.
For completeness, let me address why institutions might choose
to behave this way, because it appears as though trading opportunities are not fully exploited. (I reiterate, however, that institutions
do behave this way. It is this empirical fact that is most essential to
my argument, not the theoretical rationale for why this behavior
arises.)39 The model I have in mind is in the spirit of Shleifer
and Vishny's (1997) model, in which agency frictions in professional
money management lead to less aggressive trading, or what they call
limits to arbitrage. (I intentionally use the term ``limits to speculation'' in this section to establish a conceptual link to that earlier
work.) Specically, consider an agency-friction modelwhich I
only sketch herewhere the optimal contract between a rm and a
proprietary trader is one that holds the trader responsible for ownvariance, not covariance. Traders do not want their compensation
tied to securities they do not trade; doing so with a covariance-based
contract reduces prot incentives and opens the door to disruptive
levels of idiosyncratic risk.40 Given this ``constrained-optimal'' contract, limited speculative capital is allocated to trading opportunities
with the highest Sharpe ratio.
One way around these agency frictions is to imagine a market with
a very large number of individual speculators, each taking a small
position against the forward bias. In this case, agency friction does
not arise, and speculators' collective actions eliminate the bias in
forward rates. The trouble with this approach is that, in reality, individual speculators do not have specialized knowledge, low trans-
214
Chapter 7
Strategy 2:
> Median Discount
Strategy 3:
< Median Discount
Sharpe Ratio:
No Costs
0.48
0.46
0.49
Sharpe Ratio:
With Costs
0.37
0.39
0.41
Strategies for proting from forward bias entail selling foreign currency forward when
ft; 1 > pt and buying foreign currency forward when ft; 1 < pt . The three strategies shown
are implemented using the six largest currency markets: $/DM, $/yen, $/, $/Swiss,
$/FF, and $/C$. The ``Equal Weighted'' strategy has an equal position weight each
month in each of the six forward markets. The ``>Median Discount'' strategy only takes
a position in a forward market in a given month if that month's forward discount is
greater than the median forward discount for that currency over the sample (weights
are equal across forward positions taken). The ``<Median Discount'' strategy only takes
a position in a forward market in a given month if the month's forward discount is less
than the median forward discount for that currency over the sample (weights are equal
across forward positions taken). The Sharpe ratio estimate with costs assumes a cost of
ten basis points per transaction (includes price impact of trade). The sample is monthly
data, from January 1980 to December 1998 (1980 is about the time when forward bias
was rst documented in the literature).
Source: Datastream.
Macro Puzzles
215
216
Chapter 7
Empirical Support
Several empirical ndings are consistent with my inaction band explanation based on Sharpe ratios.41 One testable implication is the
following. If my explanation is true, then the coefcient b should be
closer to one in periods when forward discounts ft; 1 pt are further from zero, other things equal (see equation 7.15). To understand
why, note that the numerator of the Sharpe ratio is a function of two
variables: the size of the forward discount and the value of the coefcient b. Holding xed both the value of b and the denominator of
the Sharpe ratio (equation 7.16), a forward discount further from
zero implies a larger Sharpe ratio. A larger Sharpe ratio, in turn,
attracts more speculative capital, which induces adjustment in prices
toward consistency with unbiasedness (i.e., toward the level consistent with no inaction range). The data bears out this prediction.
Huisman et al. (1998), for example, nd that unbiasedness holds
much more tightly in periods when the forward discounts are further
from zero. Using time-averaged data, Flood and Taylor (1996) nd
the same result.
Consider a second implication of my explanation: currencies with
lower variances should have a coefcient b closer to one, other things
equal. This implication works from the denominator of the Sharpe
ratio: for given level of b and a given forward discount size, a lower
variance implies a larger Sharpe ratio. As above, a larger Sharpe
ratio attracts more speculative capital, which induces adjustment in
prices toward consistency with unbiasedness.42 The data bears out
this prediction, too. Flood and Rose (1996), for example, nd that
estimates of b within the lower volatility European Monetary System
are about 0.6.
Why Isn't the Coefcient b in the Middle of the Inaction Range?
The four-part explanation above claries why the bias can persist,
without violating speculative efciency. It does not explain why the
coefcient b (at 0.9) lies near one edge of the inaction range 1; 3.
For this, one needs a meta-modela model that determines the exchange rate when pure currency speculation does not occur. The
meta-model must confront the fact that inaction in terms of pure
currency speculation does not imply an absence of FX order ow.
Macro Puzzles
217
Sources of order ow that remain include customers in the FX market that do not engage in pure currency speculation, which includes
the great majority of mutual funds, pension funds, and nonnancial
corporations.
To begin our formulation of a meta-model, let us divide the customer portion of the order ow pie (see section 3.1) into three slices.
The three slices are
1. Leveraged investors
2. Unleveraged investors
3. Nonnancial corporations
The rst slice is what practitioners call leveraged investors. These are
the proprietary bank traders and hedge funds that are the focus of
the previous paragraphs. As noted, this is the slice that has a comparative advantage in implementing pure currency strategies to exploit forward bias. Despite their comparative advantage, however,
on average they devote little of their capital to this type of speculation. The second slice is what practitioners call unleveraged investors. These are institutions like mutual funds, pension funds,
and insurance companies. The last slice is nonnancial corporations.
With this breakdown, we can write aggregate customer order ow as
Ct CtL CtU CtN ;
7:17
7:18
7:19
218
Chapter 7
Macro Puzzles
219
220
Chapter 7
Microstructure and
Central Bank Intervention
222
Chapter 8
223
Figure 8.1
Fed balance sheet: Unsterilized purchase of $100 million with yen. FXR is foreign exchange reserves, DGB is domestic government bonds, and MS is money supplythat
is, money in circulation (currency plus monetary base).
224
Chapter 8
225
Figure 8.2
Fed balance sheet: Sterilized purchase of $100 million with yen. FXR is foreign exchange reserves, DGB is domestic government bonds, and MS is money supplythat
is, money in circulation (currency plus monetary base). Transaction (1) is the unsterilized intervention; transaction (2) is the offsetting sterilization.
226
Chapter 8
227
story, in contrast, the market learns about the market-clearing exchange rate from the engendered order ow itself. Non-zero order
ows imply that more adjustment is required.
Announced, Unannounced, and Secret Intervention
The previous paragraph made a distinction between intervention
that is publicly known and intervention that needs to be estimated.
In the intervention literature, the terms used are announced intervention and unannounced intervention. Announced interventions
are released by the central bank or other ofcials over major news
wires simultaneously with the intervention trade. (These ofcial
news releases do not typically provide full information: they often
specify only that a central bank is trading without divulging the size
of the order.) Unannounced intervention is executed with a private
bank dealer or dealers without any ofcial news release. From an
information perspective, unannounced intervention comes in two
varieties. When the central bank itself places unannounced orders,
the counterparty dealer(s) know that the central bank is on the
other side. Consequently, though there is no ofcial news release, the
market does learn over the day that there has been intervention, and
subsequent reports by newswires typically convey what the market
has learned. Alternatively, central banks sometimes place orders
through agents who do not reveal that a central bank is the source of
the orderso-called secret intervention. One reason a central bank
might want to do this is to mimic the trades of private players. (This
mimicking strategy was described to me by former Fed ofcial Scott
Pardee).
Let me summarize the above discussion of intervention types.
There are nine types embedded in the discussion, illustrated by the
3 3 diagram in gure 8.3.
Intervention in Practice
In practice, intervention in major FX markets these days is typically
(1) sterilized, (2) unannounced, (3) effected through brokers, and (4)
infrequent. (That said, practices do differ across central banks, and
even across time at the same central bank.) As a consequence of features (1) and (2), most of the literature on intervention is focused on
228
Chapter 8
Figure 8.3
Types of intervention.
the lower left 2 2 block of gure 8.3.9 Let me address each of these
four features in more detail.
Intervention is typically sterilized in managed oat systems. This
is certainly the case for the managed oat systems that govern the
two largest spot markets: $/euro and $/yen. (These two systems are
in fact much closer to the pure oat model than to the pure xed
model.) The Fed, for example, sterilizes all its intervention as a matter of standard operating procedure (per Dominguez and Frankel
1993b: ``The stated U.S. policy is to sterilize its foreign exchange
intervention operations always and immediately''). The Bank of
Japan and the Bundesbank also typically sterilize, though not always
(Edison 1993). In pure xed-rate systems, on the other hand, interventions are frequently unsterilized; to be credible, central banks
need to adjust their monetary policies to defend the peg.
Most interventions are also not ofcially announced over major
news wires simultaneously with the trade (Dominguez and Frankel
1993b), although there is a trend toward more announcements. Even
without ofcial announcement, varying degrees of information gets
revealed. Consider the following description by ofcials at the Fed
(Smith and Madigan 1988):
Depending upon the degree of intervention visibility that is desired, we
will either call banks and deal directly or operate through an agent in the
broker's market. Most operations are conducted in the brokers' market,
though at the beginning of a major intervention episode we have sometimes
chosen to deal directly with several banks simultaneously to achieve maximum visibility. Within the brokers' market we can be more or less aggressive, hitting existing quotes or leaving trailing quotes.
229
230
Chapter 8
231
central bank is typically the only buyer of the local currency during
crises).
Order Flow and the Macro Approach
Though the term ``order ow'' as used in microstructure nance was
not used in the macro literature on intervention before the mid1990s, the idea that trades are important for pushing prices around
was certainly present. Consider, for example, the following paragraph from Dominguez and Frankel (1993b):
The next question is how much of intervention policy's inuence on the exchange rate is the ``news'' effect and how much is the effect of actual ofcial
purchases and sales of foreign currency occurring at the same time? It is clear
that news has an effect to the extent that it causes investors to revise their
expectations of future rates of return. They buy or sell foreign currency in
response to the change in expected returns and thereby drive up or down the
current price of foreign exchange.
Perhaps most interesting about this passage is that even when the
channel is the news effect on expectations, the proximate cause of the
price change is still order owthrough the induced orders of private sector investors. For both effects thenthe news effect and the
direct effect of ofcial transactionsthe authors have order ow in
mind as the proximate driver.12 In 1993, when the DominguezFrankel book was published, we had little empirical sense of the
per-dollar price impact of orders. This is precisely what the microstructure approach is now providing.
8.2
This section reviews recent theoretical work that applies microstructure models to central bank intervention. Two themes that distinguish this theoretical work are that it (1) recognizes asymmetric
information of different types, and (2) it addresses transparency
(secrecy) head on.
Addressing the asymmetric information theme rst, there are in
fact two basic types that are relevant for intervention (see also Evans
and Lyons 2000). The rst type is well recognized in the macro literature: asymmetric information between the central bank and the
public. The mere fact that the central bank controls several exchange
232
Chapter 8
233
The rst of these broad categories is based on the fact that, at times,
central banks may act secretly because they actually prefer intervention to be ineffective. For example, the decision to intervene may be
coming from another branch of government, over the central bank's
objections. The second category of reasons for secret intervention is
based on the idea that the central bank may want, for example, to
calm so-called ``disorderly'' markets by providing a sense of a twoway market. The notion here is that if intervention were observable,
this would signal that private participants are not willing to provide
liquidity on one side of the current market (presumably leading to
greater disorder). The third category of reasons for intervention secrecywhich Dominguez and Frankel consider more persuasiveis
based on the fact that central banks frequently adjust their portfolio
holdings without any intent to move the exchange rate; they don't
want the market to confuse these transactions with purposeful intervention, so they intervene secretly.
Note that for both the rst and third of these categories, the central bank is choosing secrecy so that its price impact is minimized,
whereas ``effective'' intervention is typically associated with maximized price impact. For the second category, too, the central bank
is not choosing secrecy to maximize price impact, but to prevent
undesirable movements that might otherwise occur. In sum, none of
the three categories provides a rationale for increasing the efcacy of
intervention in the usual sense.
Like Bhattacharya and Weller, Vitale (1999) addresses why central
banks prefer secrecy using a variation of the Kyle model. To provide
a deeper view on this new line of intervention theory, let me describe
the Vitale model and his analysis in a bit more detail. (It is quite accessible on the basis of the Kyle model material presented in chapter
234
Chapter 8
235
8:1
where X is the central bank's (market) order. The parameter b indicates the degree of commitment to the predetermined target P (b is
nonnegative and is common knowledge). The rst term in the loss
function reects the capital commitment or cost of intervention: if the
central bank is buying foreign currency at a local-currency price
above V, this is costlya loss.
This loss function makes it clear that if the central bank were to
reveal both its intervention trade X and its target P, then the dealer
could back out the fundamental value V (because V would be the
only unknown). With the dealer knowing V, no attempt to target the
exchange rate would be effectiveonly the dealer's expectation of V
matters. Suppose instead that the central bank attempts to fool the
dealer by announcing false intervention trades. Vitale shows that
these announcements would not be credible (implying that the central bank would derive no benet).
The essence of the model is contained in the loss function, particularly in the fact that the target P and the fundamental V are not in
general equal. This creates the central tension. It is exactly when the
target is not consistent with the fundamental and announcements are
not credible that sterilized intervention is useful. Vitale shows that,
in effect, the central bank can buy credibility via costly trading,
which allows it to push the exchange rate toward its target.
Vitale's main result is that the central bank always prefers to conceal its target. When the target is secret, the realized exchange rate
is distributed more tightly around the target, which minimizes the
expected loss. (That the exchange rate has a distribution comes from
the realization of uncertain liquidity trader demands.) The basic intuition is the following: If the marketmaker knew anything about the
target, he could adjust the signals derived from order ow to make
them more informative about the fundamental V (in much the same
way that signals were adjusted in chapter 4 to form new, more informative signalstypically denoted with Z). The more informative
the order ow, the more tightly the price P is distributed about V,
which is not what the central bank wants. A secret target gives the
236
Chapter 8
237
Figure 8.4
Intervention transparency spectrum.
The Evans-Lyons analysis shifts attention toward a type of intervention that has received little attention of late. Since the publication
of Dominguez and Frankel (1993b), something of a consensus has
arisen that for intervention to be effective, it should be announced
and coordinated across multiple central banks. The Evans-Lyons
analysis does not dispute the effectiveness of this type of intervention; indeed, because their analysis is based on private trades only, it
has nothing to say about this type of intervention. Rather, the EvansLyons analysis highlights the effectiveness of intervention that lies on
the other end of the transparency spectrum (see gure 8.4). Private
trades areby their very nature``sterilized,'' so why not learn all
we can from the price impact of this type of trade?
Why Price Impact Might Be State Dependent
To understand why a given sized trade may have different price
impact in different market states, let us revisit the concept of event
uncertainty (introduced in chapter 5). The term refers to uncertainty
about whether or not private information is present (in contrast
to most trading models, where it is known with certainty that it
is present).18 Under event uncertainty, the information content of
trades varies depending on the market's state. In the Easley and
O'Hara (1992) model, trades are more informativethat is, have more
price impactwhen trading intensity is high. To understand why, consider an environment in which new private information may exist,
but does not necessarily exist. For example, suppose that with probability p no new information exists and with probability 1 p some
traders have observed some new information (either good or bad,
with known probabilities). Easley and O'Hara demonstrate that
rational dealers in this context will view a lack of trading as evidence
that new private information is not present. The upshot is that if
trading intensity is low, then an incoming trade induces a smaller
update in beliefs because it is more likely to be purely liquidity
motivated. On the ip side, trades occurring when trading intensity
is high are more likely to be signaling private information. Though
238
Chapter 8
239
Model Solution
The model's solution is quite similar to that in the model of chapter
7. Specically, the equilibrium trading rules for round 2 interdealer
trading take the form
Tjt aCjt1
8:2
Tit aCjt1 It ;
8:3
where I use the subscript j to denote all dealers not receiving the
central bank order, and subscript i for the one dealer who does receive the central bank order. With these trading rules, the change in
price from the beginning of day t to the beginning of day t 1 takes
the familiar form:
Pt1 Pt b1 DRt b2 Xt ;
8:4
240
Chapter 8
241
Central bank's with precise knowledge of their own tradesfor example, timing, announcements, stealth level, and so onwill be able
to estimate the impact of these various ``parameter'' settings. Armed
with appropriate data, a central bank could learn exactly how trading is affected in all three market segments (direct interdealer, brokered interdealer, and customer-dealer). This would include learning
about liquidity provision (on both sides of the market), transaction
activity, and the process of price adjustment. It is something like a
doctor who has a patient ingest blue dye to determine how it passes
through the digestive systemthe whole process becomes transparent. Such is the future of empirical work on this topic.
Customers: Underlying
Demand in the Economy
Background on Customers
244
Chapter 9
ow is the essence of each, in that it is the customer orders that catalyze a market response. By extension, it is not unreasonable to view
microstructure models in this respect as similar: their broad implications for the relation between exchange rates and customer ow
are the same (though the path of price adjustment may differ across
models).1
The importance of customer orders is obvious to practitioners
as well. Any FX trader or trading-desk manager would agree. One
trader I spoke with put it rather colorfully when he said that customer trades are the market's ``crack cocaine,'' by which he meant
that the customer orders are the market's catalyst, and that catalyst is
quite powerful.2 In keeping with this notion of customer ow as the
market's catalyst, proprietary information on those ows is a prime
driver of proprietary trading at the largest banks. (Smaller banks see
too little of the marketwide customer ow to make this information
useful.) Embedded in this behavior is the fact that banks nd customer ow information valuable for predicting exchange rate movements. Thus far, this book has concerned itself only with explaining
movements, that is, accounting for movements using concurrent
ow. That customer ow has predictive power as well (i.e., today's
ow predicts future movements) adds a new dimension. It is this
predictive dimension that most interests the practitioner audience of
the microstructure approach.3
So why in previous chapters have I focused so much on order ow
between dealers? There are two reasons. The rst is the simple fact
that until the dataset described below became available, researchers
had no alternative but to work with order ow between dealers.
The second reason is that despite the constraint on data availability,
there is justication for focusing on ow between dealers, due to the
differential transparency of customer-dealer and interdealer ow
(introduced in chapter 3). The reality of this market is that dealers
can observe some order ow from interdealer trades in which they
are not involved (e.g., from brokered trades). Customer-dealer trades,
on the other hand, are not observable except by the bank that receives them. Dealers therefore learn about other dealers' customer
orders as best they can by observing other dealers' interdealer trades,
and they set market prices accordingly. Although this learning from
interdealer orders is consistent with earlier chapters' empirical models, the ultimate driver of that interdealer ow is customer ow.
Let me provide a bird's eye view of how the customer ow data of
this chapter relates to the order ow data analyzed in earlier chap-
Customers
245
Figure 9.1
Trading volume pie.
ters. As noted in chapter 3, for the data sets of the 1990s volume in
the major spot FX markets splits into three roughly equal categories:
customer-dealer trades, direct interdealer trades, and brokered
interdealer trades. Figure 9.1 provides an illustration. Chapter 7's
analysis is based on data from the two interdealer categories. The
work of Evans and Lyons (2000), for example, uses data wholly
from the direct interdealer category. The work of Payne (1999) and
Killeen, Lyons, and Moore (2000a) uses data wholly from the brokered interdealer category.
As noted in chapter 5, data on customer orders in the major spot
markets are difcult to obtain. The only possible source given the
market's current structure is private banks themselves, but in general
these banks consider these data to be highly proprietary. Recently,
however, Fan and Lyons (2000) obtained customer trade data from
Citibank, a leading FX trading bank. (Citibank is among the top three
worldwide, with a market share in major-currency customer business in the 1015 percent range.) Citibank made these data available
only on a time-aggregated basisall the customer orders received
by this bank worldwide are aggregated into daily order ows (executed trades only). The data set therefore does not include individual
trades. Consequently, transaction-level analysis along the lines of
that introduced in chapter 5 is not possible.
Against this drawback, this data set has many advantages:
1. The data span more that ve years, so analysis at longer horizons
(e.g., monthly) is possible.
246
Chapter 9
2. The data cover the two largest markets: $/euro and $/yen.
(Before the launch of the euroJanuary 1999order ow data for
the ``euro'' are constructed from ows in the constituent currencies
against the dollar.)
3. The data include both spot and forward trades, but are netted of
any trades in FX swaps (because FX swaps do not have net order
ow implications; see chapter 3).
4. The data are split into three customer-type categories, corresponding to the three categories introduced in section 7.4: nonnancial
institutions (e.g., corporations), unleveraged nancial institutions
(e.g., mutual funds), and leveraged nancial institutions (e.g., hedge
funds).
Advantage (4) provides considerable statistical power for uncovering the underlying causes of order ow's impact on price. Do all
orders have the same price impact? Or might some order typessay
the orders of hedge fundsconvey more information than others?
Our ability to disaggregate order ow to answer these questions
brings us closer to a specication of the underlying information
sources.
Order Flows versus Capital Flows
When macroeconomists hear the word ``ows,'' they think of balance
of payments ows: real trade ows in the current account and capital
ows in the capital account.4 This book, in contrast, has hammered
(mercilessly?) on the concept of order ow. This is an appropriate
point to loop back on the relation between the two because we have
left the world of interdealer trading and are now considering the
currency demands of customers, which represent the underlying demands in the economy. They are the players whose demand shifts
matter for persistent price movements. (As an empirical matter,
dealers' net demands are too short-lived to matter over longer horizons, beyond the information they convey about underlying customer demands.5) Because balance of payments ows are familiar
territory for macroeconomists, this becomes a natural contact point
for readers from that background.
Now that we are examining underlying demands in the economy,
are we closer to macroeconomic notions of balance of payments
ows? At rst blush, it might appear that we are not much closer.
Customers
247
248
Chapter 9
This follows from the model's result that dealers nish each day with
no net position, which was itself a consequence of the assumption that dealers' risk-bearing capacity is small relative to the whole
market, that is, relative to all nondealers together.
The data presented below on customer order ow data represent
the orders received by one bank, not the customer ow received by
all banks. One would not therefore expect it to net exactly to zero
each day, even if the portfolio shifts model were literally true. With
these limited data, then, hypothesis 1 is untestable. Suppose, however, that the single-bank data represent a random sample, say 10
percent, of the marketwide customer order ow on any given day. In
this case, the Evans-Lyons model predicts that
hypothesis 2: For a single bank, customer order ow each day
should differ from zero due only to random sampling error.
hypothesis 3: For a single bank, customer order ow each day
should be uncorrelated with changes in the exchange rate.
Hypothesis 3 follows from the fact that the customer-order sample is
assumed here to be random. (It should therefore contain on average
as many realizations of the model's beginning of day ``shock'' orders
Customers
249
Table 9.1 presents summary statistics for the three main customer
categories: nonnancial corporations, leveraged nancial institutions
(e.g., hedge funds), and unleveraged nancial institutions (e.g., mutual funds).8 The sample covers January 1993 to June 1999. For the
euro, the total trading volume across the three customer categories is
roughly balanced. For the yen, this is not the case: nonnancial corTable 9.1
Customer Trades: Volumes and Order Flow
Euro
Total
Trading
Volume
Yen
Cumul.
Order
Flow
Daily
Standard
Deviation
Total
Trading
Volume
Cumul.
Order
Flow
Daily
Standard
Deviation
Nonnancial
Corporations
539
25.7
0.09
259
3.3
0.07
Leveraged
Financial
667
2.5
0.16
681
16.1
0.16
Unleveraged
Financial
507
11.8
0.13
604
1.8
0.15
1,713
11.4
0.23
1,544
17.6
0.23
Total
Billions of euros for Euro and billions of dollars for Yen. Euro denotes the $/euro
market. Yen denotes the $/yen market. The sample for both currencies is January 1993
to June 1999. (Before the launch of the euro in January 1999, volume and order ow are
constructed from trading in the euro's constituent currencies.) Positive order ow in
the case of the euro denotes net demand for euros (following the convention in that
market of quoting prices in dollars per euro). Positive order ow in the case of the yen
denotes net demand for dollars (following the convention in that market of quoting
prices in yen per dollar). Daily standard deviation measures the standard deviation of
daily order ow.
250
Chapter 9
porate trading is less than half that for the other two categories (these
breakdowns may be bank specic, however). For both markets, the
daily order ow of the nonnancial corporations is the least volatile.
Cumulative order ow displays quite different characteristics across
the three customer categories. For the euro, unleveraged nancial
institutions are the largest net buyers and nonnancial corporations
are the largest net sellers. In the yen market, leveraged nancial
institutions are the largest net buyers (of dollars) and unleveraged
nancial institutions are the largest net sellers (though slight).
I turn now to plots of the customer ows, which provide a rst
glimpse of the possible link to exchange rate movements. Figure 9.2
shows cumulative customer order ows and the level of the exchange rate in both the $/euro and $/yen markets.9 Positive correlation is evident. Comparing these plots to gure 1.2which uses
the four months of daily interdealer data from Evans 1997one sees
that the correlation in gure 9.2 is not as tight at higher frequencies.
At lower frequencies, say monthly, the relation is manifested clearly.
The next section addresses this lower frequency relation more formally using regression analysis.
These plots also have implications for the three hypotheses introduced in section 9.1. Hypothesis 1 stated that marketwide customer
ow each day should net to zero. Because these plots show only one
bank's customer ow, not the whole market's, one is not able to reject this hypothesis based on these data alone. Hypotheses 2 and 3,
on the other hand, are directly testable. Hypotheses 2 and 3 stated
that this bank's daily customer ow should differ from zero due
only to random sampling error, and should therefore be uncorrelated
with exchange rate movements. These hypotheses appear to be
rejected: cumulative order ow received by this bank is correlated
with exchange rate movements.
What could explain this positive correlation? One possibility is
that it is not really therethe correlation is not statistically signicant. But I show in the next section that the relation is statistically
signicant. Another possibility is that hypothesis 1from which
hypotheses 2 and 3 are derivedmay not hold (i.e., marketwide
customer ow each day does not net to zero). For example, collectively, dealers may be maintaining nonzero positions. Though this
would not be surprising from day to day, it would indeed be surprising at weekly frequencies and lower (and these lower frequencies
are more relevant for the correlation in gure 9.2). Accordingly, I do
Customers
251
Figure 9.2
Cumulative customer ow and exchange rates. The plots show the spot exchange rate
and cumulative customer order ow received by the source bank. The sample for the
$/euro plot is January 1993 to June 1999. The sample for the yen/$ plot is January 1996
to June 1999 (the January 1993 to December 1995 period is not included due to the lack
of Tokyo ofce data). The spot exchange rate is expressed on the lefthand scale. The
cumulative customer order ow is expressed on the righthand scale (in billions of
euros for the $/euro plot and in billions of dollars for the yen/$ plot).
252
Chapter 9
Customers
253
Figure 9.3
Cumulative customer ow and exchange rates over the Evans-Lyons sample. The plot
shows the cumulative customer order ow in the $/euro market received by the
source bank from May 1 to August 31, 1996, and the spot exchange rate over the same
period. The spot rate is expressed in DM/$ on the lefthand scale. The cumulative customer order ow is expressed in millions of euros on the righthand scale (positive for
net dollar purchases).
lation to the exchange rate, appear in gure 1.2. Figure 9.3 presents
the May to August slice from the longer order ow series shown
in gure 9.2. They are plotted against the DM/$ rate for comparison purposes because the DM/$ rate is the rate plotted in gure 1.2.
Despite these data being the composite order ow for all the euro's
constituent currencies (against the dollar), the ow series tracks the
DM/$ rate quite closely. (Most of the constituent ow against the
dollar is in the DM market.) It is heartening that the customer-dealer
and interdealer ows tell a similar story. Integrated analysis of
series from these different segments is an important area for future
research.
9.3
9:1
where Dpt is the monthly change in the log spot exchange rate. Esti-
254
Chapter 9
Table 9.2
Price Impact of Aggregate Customer Orders
Dpt b0 b1 Aggregate Customer Flowt et
b1
R2
Euro
0.8
(3.8)
0.16
Yen
1.2
(3.0)
0.15
Monthly Data
T-statistics are shown in parentheses. The dependent variable Dpt is the monthly
change in the log spot exchange rate (the $/euro rate and the yen/$ rate, respectively).
The order ow regressors are measured over the concurrent month (in billions of euros
for the euro equation and billions of dollars in the yen equation). Estimated using OLS
(standard errors corrected for heteroskedasticity). The sample is January 1993 to June
1999. Constants (not reported) are insignicant in both equations.
mates of this model provide a more rigorous measure of the correlations displayed in gure 9.2. Fan and Lyons estimate the model at
the monthly frequency, which is the most common frequency for
estimating macro exchange rate models.10
Order ow is signicant in both regressions, with t-statistics well
above three. The R 2 statistics are respectable when compared to
those typically found for empirical macro models (typically in the 0
10 percent range), but remain far below those produced at the daily
frequency by Evans and Lyons (1999) using direct interdealer order
ow.
In the euro equation, the coefcient estimate of 0.8 implies that a
net purchase of one billion euros increases the dollar price of a euro
by about 0.8 percent. Similarly, in the yen equation, the estimate of
1.2 implies that a net purchase of $1 billion increases the yen price of
a dollar by about 1.2 percent. These price-impact coefcients are
roughly twice the size of those estimated by Evans and Lyons (1999),
who found that a net purchase of $1 billion increases the DM price of
a dollar by about 0.5 percent. (In fact Evans and Lyons nd that
some of the price impact at the daily frequency dissipates, suggesting that a comparable monthly frequency impact would be less than
0.5 percent.)
One might expect the customer ow to have a larger coefcient
for two reasons. First, the source bank's customer ow may be correlated with other banks' customer ow, and because those other
Customers
255
Table 9.3
Price Impact of Disaggregated Customer Orders
Dpt b0 b 1 Unlev: Fin: Flowt b 2 Lev: Fin: Flowt b3 Non-fin: Corp: Flowt et
b1
b2
b3
R2
Euro
1.5
(4.6)
0.6
(1.6)
0.2
(0.5)
0.27
Yen
1.1
(1.9)
1.8
(4.9)
2.3
(3.5)
0.34
Monthly Data
T-statistics are shown in parentheses. The dependent variable Dpt is the monthly
change in the log spot exchange rate. The three order ow regressors are the order
ows from unleveraged nancial institutions, leveraged nancial institutions, and
nonnancial corporations. Order ows are measured over the concurrent month (in
billions of euros for the euro equation and billions of dollars in the yen equation).
Estimated using OLS (standard errors corrected for heteroskedasticity). The sample is
January 1993 to June 1999. Constants (not reported) are insignicant in both equations.
9:2
where Dpt is the monthly change in the log spot rate, as before, and
the three regressors are the three customer ow categories introduced above: UF denotes unleveraged nancial institutions, LF denotes leveraged nancial institutions, and NF denotes nonnancial
corporations. As Fan and Lyons point out, this regression is important because it addresses whether orders of some participants are
more informative than those of others (as opposed order ow simply
being undifferentiated demand). Analyzing order ow's parts illuminates the information structure that underlies trading in this
market.
The results in table 9.3 indicate that these three different types of
order ow do indeed have different price impact. The orders of nonnancial corporations have no price impact in the $/euro market
and, strikingly, appear to be negatively correlated with price changes
256
Chapter 9
Customers
257
258
Chapter 9
Customers
259
260
Chapter 9
Customers
261
for the ultimate exchange rate. For example, keeping the path of total
customer ow the same, if it had been the unleveraged nancial
institutions that had gradually ed dollars in early September, rather
than the leveraged institutions, might the new level of the yen/$ rate
in late October have been different? Though path dependence of this
kind is not a property of the earlier chapters' models, it is an interesting possibility for future work to consider.
Another larger implication of the case study is that liquidity in FX
markets varies over time, sometimes quite substantially. (In chapter
4, I provided a working denition of liquidity as an order's price
impact.) The order ow coefcients in tables 9.2 and 9.3 imply that
the relatively small portfolio shifts in gure 9.4 should have had
price impact that was much smaller, perhaps a few percent, rather
than the roughly 10 percent change that occurred. Though timevarying liquidity is also not a property of the earlier chapters' models, it is an issue that future work must consider. What triggers
liquidity changes? Might what appears on the surface to be changing
liquidity be due instead to changing order ow composition (given
the differential impact shown in the previous section)?
10
Looking Forward
264
10.1
Chapter 10
Looking Forward
265
that include only a fraction of marketwide ow, the concurrent impact of these ows accounts for 4070 percent of the persistent
movements in prices (i.e., at monthly horizons and longer, see, e.g.,
Payne 1999; Evans and Lyons 1999; Evans 2000; Rime 2000). As
richer order ow data sets become available (e.g., as they span a
larger share of the market and sign the ows more precisely), that
percentage may rise still higher.
Even Macro Announcements Affect Price via Order Flow
The ipside of the rst lesson is that concurrent macro announcements and other readily identiable macro changes do not directly
explain a large share of longer horizon price movements. Direct
mapping from concurrent macro changes to prices appears to be
limited (Evans 2000; Evans and Lyons 1999). Rather, order ow
appears to mediate most price movements (Evans and Lyons 2001).
(Recall the ``hybrid model'' in gure 7.1 that allowed information to
affect prices either directly, or indirectly via the order ow link.)
Though in some sense this result is a rediscovery of the well-known
empirical failure of macro models, work in FX microstructure is
clarifying the factors that supplement concurrent macro changes as a
driver of prices.
Price Elasticity with Respect to Order Flow is High
The elasticity of the exchange rate with respect to customer order
ow is roughly 0.8 percent per $1 billion (e.g., in the $/euro market,
per table 9.2; elasticity with respect to interdealer order ow is
roughly half that size). With world nancial wealth measured in
trillions of dollars, this is puzzlingly high. The result is consistent
with a common view that Milton Friedman's ``stabilizing speculators'' are not bold enough. Why this boldness might be lacking remains an open question. From an information-theoretic perspective,
however, high elasticity may not be so puzzling: small net ows may
be conveying signicant amounts of information.
Order Flow is a Factor in Floating Rate Volatility
We now have substantial evidence that order ow is an important
proximate factor driving volatility and may account for apparently excessive volatility under oating regimes (see, e.g., Evans and
Lyons 1999; Killeen, Lyons, and Moore 2000a). Though work on
order ow as a driver of price is focused on the sign of the relation-
266
Chapter 10
ship, there are also implications for volatility: a good model of return
rst moments is a good model of return second moments (but not
vice versa). Also relevant for this lesson is recent work by Osler
(2001). She nds that stop-loss orders on the buy (sell) side tend to
cluster at prices just above (below) round numbers, which can cause
trends to gain momentum once support and resistance levels are
crossed.
Acceleration of Information in Price
Empirical results in FX markets are not consistent with the ``accelerationist view'' that order ow simply accelerates the impounding
of information in price by, say, a few minutes (gure 3.4). As noted
above, our best measures of signed public-information ow are
virtually uncorrelated with the direction of exchange rate movements (at horizons of one year or less). This is incompatible with the
accelerated-by-a-few-minutes view.
At the same time, a fascinating possibility is that an accelerationist
story is indeed operating, but over much longer horizons. Suppose
order ow conveys individuals' expectations about macro fundamentals that are more distant (i.e., beyond the next month, quarter,
or even year). In that case, order ow serves to telescope this forward-looking information into today's spot rate. Note too that this
possibility is consistent with ndings that over longer horizons (e.g.,
three to ve years), macro variables do begin to account for a substantial share of exchange rate variation (despite concurrent macrofundamentals being virtually uncorrelated with exchange rates; see,
e.g., Mark 1995; Flood and Taylor 1996).
Order Flow Does Not Have to Sum to Zero
The Evans and Lyons (1999) model shows why order ow between
dealers does not have to sum to zero. This is important conceptually
because many people are under the mistaken impression that order
ow must sum to zero (and therefore that any ow measure that
correlates positively with price must be unrepresentative in some
way). This is not always the case.
Let me turn now to more micro-oriented lessons. By microoriented, I mean that they are based on intraday analysis of individual dealers. As such, they parallel more closely the bread and butter
work within microstructure nance.
Looking Forward
267
Micro-Oriented Lessons
Order Flow is Private Information
The behavior of individual dealers shows that they consider FX
order ow to be informative and that they set prices accordingly
(Lyons 1995, and other references in chapter 2). This empirical result
at the micro level accords well with the importance of order ow at
lower frequencies mentioned earlier. Moreover, all orders are not
alike in terms of their information content. Identifying which orders
are the most informative and who is behind them is illuminating
the market's underlying information structure. This type of analysis
goes well beyond the question of whether or not institutions affect
prices; it uses microstructure models to uncover new facets of nancial information.
Dealer Inventories Affect Price
Inventory control among spot FX dealers is strong relative to that
found for other markets. Most spot FX dealers prefer to end their day
atthat is, with no net position. Accordingly, the half-life of the
typical dealer's inventory is signicantly less than one day, and has
been estimated to be as low as ten minutes (e.g., Lyons 1998). These
half-lives are much shorter than those found in equity and futures
markets, where half-lives longer than one week are common. 2 Not
only do FX dealers control their inventories intensively, some also
adjust their prices to induce inventory-decumulating order ow.
(Lyons 1995 nds these inventory effects on price, but Yao 1998 does
not nd them for the dealer he track; see also Bjonnes and Rime 2000
and Romeu 2001.) This nding of inventory effects on price is important: they are the linchpin of the whole inventory branch of
microstructure theory, despite the fact that empiricists working on
markets other than FX have not found them.3
Hot Potato Trading Contributes to Trading Volume
Dealers describe hot potato trading as an important source of the FX
market's enormous trading volumes. The large share of trading between dealers that we nd in FX relative to other markets is consistent with a signicant role for hot potato trading. On the theoretical
front, our models show that hot potato trading is consistent with
optimizing behavior (e.g., Lyons 1997a). On the empirical front, we
268
Chapter 10
Let me begin with what are, in my judgment, the four most important open issues in FX microstructure research.
Open Issue 1: Does the Information in FX Order Flow Reect
Payoff Information, Portfolio Balance Information, or Both?
Chapter 2 covered the economics of order ow information. In that
chapter, we saw that order ow can have persistent effects on price
through two basic channels: payoffs and discount rates. Evans and
Lyons (1999, 2000) model the persistent effects wholly as discount
rate effects, which macroeconomists typically call portfolio balance
effects.4 This feature of the Evans-Lyons model comes from their assumption that customer order ow Ct is uncorrelated with current
and future payoffs Rt . We cannot rule out, however, the possibility
that order ow conveys information about future payoffs. Consider a
simple variation on the Evans-Lyons model that claries how this
might work. Suppose customer orders are correlated with future
payoffs Rtk , where k is, say, one to ve years. This could occur if
payoff expectations held by individual customers are changing,
based on a constant ow of dispersed bits of information relevant
to forming those expectations (bits that not all customers share).
Dealers wishing to aggregate the information in those changing
expectations would respond to order ow the same way as in the
original Evans-Lyons model. If this variation on the model were
correct, then one would expect order ow to forecast future macroeconomic variables (as suggested by the long horizon accelerationist
view mentioned earlier). With the longer order ow series now
available (e.g., the seven years of $/euro data described in chapter
Looking Forward
269
9), we are just now getting enough statistical power to test this. Work
along these lines will help close the current gap between order ow
analysis and macro analysis.5
Open Issue 2: To What Extent Is Reverse Causality Presentfrom
Prices to Order Flowand Under What Circumstances (e.g.,
Distressed Institutions) Is It More Acute?
The full body of microstructure theory treats causality as running
from order ow to price. To rationalize the reverse causality, one
would have to develop an optimizing model in which investors at
the price-determining margin trade with positive feedback. This is
not an easy task, particularly since there is no compelling evidence of
ongoing positive momentum in exchange rate returns. Moreover, as
an empirical matter, work such as that of Killeen, Lyons, and Moore
(2000a) nds that in statistical terms, (Granger) causality does indeed
run from order ow to price, and not vice versa. The above theoretical and empirical arguments notwithstanding, causality almost
surely runs both directions, at least part of the time. Chapter nine's
analysis of the October 1998 plummeting of the dollar's value against
the yen provides some suggestive evidence of falling prices inducing
additional selling. If this selling was indeed ``distressed'' selling
brought about by loss limits or other institutional constraints, it will
be important to model these types of institutional constraints, and to
determine empirically to what extent they aggravate extreme market
movements.
Open Issue 3:
270
Chapter 10
Looking Forward
271
272
Chapter 10
Policy Implications
Looking Forward
Policy Area 1:
273
274
Policy Area 2:
Chapter 10
International Currencies
What role should specic currencies play in the international monetary and nancial system? Recent introduction of the euro has
brought this question to a level of policy relevance not seen since the
early 1970s (when the Bretton Woods xed-rate system collapsed).
Discussion of the role for an international currencythat is, a single
currency that acts as a universal means of exchangecenters on
three key aspects: (1) use as a reserve currency by central banks, (2)
use as an invoicing currency for international transactions, and (3)
use as a vehicle currency for currency transactions (vehicle currencies are used when the transaction cost of trading two currencies
directly is higher than the cost of trading them indirectly, via two
transactions through the vehicle currency). In aspects (2) and (3),
a single currency's success as an international currency is heavily
dependent on the level of transaction costs. Therefore, to predict
Looking Forward
275
Transaction Taxes
276
Chapter 10
Looking Forward
277
Notes
Chapter 1.
280
Notes
Notes
281
dollar. When referring in general terms to an FX market, practitioners typically list the
dollar rst: orally, they refer to this market as ``dollar-mark,'' typically written as the
``$/DM market,'' or simply as ``$/DM'' (the Bank for International Settlements also
follows this dollar-rst convention in its FX market surveys; see section 3.2). In this
book, I remain true to these differing conventions. When describing an actual rate,
precision requires me to write it as it is traded (e.g., DM/$, yen/$, and $/). When
referring in general terms to a particular market, I always list the dollar rst ($/DM,
$/yen, and $/). Finally, when I use the symbol P in equations to denote the exchange
rate as a price, P always denotes the dollar price of the other currency ($/other).
17. Because the Evans (1997) data set does not include the size of every trade, this
measure of order ow is in fact the number of buys minus sells. That is, if a dealer initiates a trade against another dealer's DM/$ quote, and that trade is a dollar purchase
(sale), then order ow is 1 (1). These are cumulated across dealers over each 24hour trading day (weekend tradingwhich is minimalis included in Monday).
18. Readers familiar with the concept of co-integration will recognize that it offers a
natural means of testing for a long-run relationship. In chapter 7, I present evidence
that cumulative order ow and the level of the exchange rate are indeed cointegrated
(i.e., the relationship between order ow and price is not limited to high frequencies). I
also present models in chapter 7 that show why a long-run relationship of this kind is
what one should expect.
Chapter 2.
1. A related, less extreme view is that order ow may convey some non-public information but the information it conveys is likely to become public soon. In this case,
order ow advances the impounding of information in price by only, say, a few
minutes. This less extreme view is not consistent with the data, however. To a rst
approximation, our best measures of public information ow are uncorrelated with the
direction of exchange rate movements (at annual or higher frequencies), whereas order
ow is correlated with exchange rate movements. I return to this issue in chapter 3.
2. I have in mind here the major FX markets. This kind of private information is more
reasonable in emerging markets. For example, the IMF (1995) reports that Mexican
investors were the rst to ee Mexico in the period immediately prior to the December
1994 devaluation. It is not unreasonable to believe that certain people close to the devaluation decision had inside information and were able to act on it.
3. This section emphasizes empirical work that uses order ow data, as opposed to
empirical work that uses price data only.
4. A third method for testing whether order ow effects are persistentrelated to the
rst twois testing for cointegration between cumulative order ow and the level of
the exchange rate (see Killeen, Lyons, and Moore 2000a; Bjonnes and Rime 2000).
5. Hartmann (1999) nds that FX spreads widen with unexpected volume, which is
consistent with an adverse selection component.
6. In the case of FX, volatility over the lunch period can still be calculated because
trading continues in other trading locations, such as Singapore and Hong Kong.
Andersen, Bollerslev, and Das (2000) verify the signicance of this volatility increase
over lunch. They do nd, however, that some other results in the Ito et al. paper are
282
Notes
sensitive to an outlier in the data set. Covrig and Melvin's analysis (1998) of the same
Tokyo experiment excludes the outlier observation, but still nds evidence that Japanese banks are relatively well informed, corroborating the Ito et al. interpretation. The
Covrig-Melvin evidence is based on price leadership by Japanese banks. For related
evidence on volatilities during the LondonNew York trading overlap, see Hsieh and
Kleidon (1996).
7. By ``better'' I mean lower conditional variance.
8. Empirical evidence of inventory effects on FX prices is in Lyons (1995).
9. To understand why the change in the risk premiumi.e., the expected return
changes price, think of a pure discount bond: when the market interest ratethe
expected returnchanges, the price of the bond must change, even though the cash
ow at maturity does not change.
10. This logic is also behind my choice of V in this book to denote payoffs, rather than
the more customary F; the symbol F is too easily interpreted as the whole of fundamentals, an interpretation that is too narrow in my judgment.
11. This expectations story is also applicable to information about discount rates, in
which case it would fall into type (2) or type (3).
12. Other proxies for expectationssuch as time-series measures like ARIMA or VAR
modelsdo not share this backed-by-money, information-encompassing property. A
quote by Frankel and Rose (1995, 1701) provides some perspective on these time-series
measures. In their words, ``To use an ARIMA or VAR process as a measure of what
agents expect, is to ascribe to them simultaneously not enough information, and too
much. It does not ascribe to them enough information, because it leaves out all the
thousands of bits of information that market investors use. . . . It ascribes to them too
much information . . . because it assumes that they know the parameters of the statistical process from the beginning of the sample period.'' Also relevant is the discussion
in Engel (1996), where he describes ``peso problems'' in exchange rates as a case where
the market had more information than empiricists, and ``learning'' as a case where the
market had less information than empiricists (ex-post).
13. Within the literature on asset pricing more broadly (e.g., the pricing kernel
approach), work on time-varying discount rates is sometimes referred to as addressing
``stochastic discount factors.'' As is mine, the focus of this literature is on variation in
the risk-premium component of discount rates, not the risk-free-rate component.
14. Though this discount rate effect on price emerges in most models as a risk premium, for technical convenience sometimes models are specied with risk-neutral
dealers who face some generic ``inventory holding cost,'' which produces similar
results.
15. Readers familiar with microstructure theory will recognize that this gure assumes that there is no xed component to the spreadi.e., the effective spread shrinks
to zero as the size of the incoming order shrinks to zero. This is a detail that need not
concern the more macro-oriented reader.
16. For evidence of imperfect substitutability across stocks, see Scholes (1972); Shleifer
(1986); Bagwell (1992); and Kaul et al. (2000), among others. For at least two reasons,
imperfect substitutability may be more applicable to currency markets than to markets
in individual stocks. First, note that the size of the order ows that the $/euro market needs to absorb are on average more than 10,000 times those absorbed in a
Notes
283
representative U.S. stock (e.g., the average daily volume on individual NYSE stocks
in 1998 was about $9 million, whereas the average daily volume in $/DM spot
was about $150 billion). Second, there are far more individual stocks that can substitute for one another in portfolios than there are individual currencies (particularly
major currencies).
Chapter 3.
1. This statistic is from the Bank for International Settlements, BIS (1999a). I examine
BIS survey data in more detail in section 3.2.
2. BIS (1999a), 17.
3. Briey, covered interest parity is a no-arbitrage condition that implies that
F$= =P$= 1 i$ =1 i , where F$= is today's one-period forward rate ($/), P$= is
today's spot rate, i$ is today's one-period nominal interest rate in dollars, and i is
today's one-period nominal interest rate in pound sterling. In economic (and order
ow) terms, taking offsetting positions on the lefthand side of this equation is equivalent to taking offsetting positions on the righthand side (in markets free of capital
controls).
4. One fascinating branch of related work on derivatives involves derivative and spot
market interaction (as opposed to analysis of a derivatives market in isolation). The
question is whether introducing a derivatives market can rectify specic market failures. See, for example, Brennan and Cao (1996) and Cao (1999), among many others.
5. There is a large literature on limit-order auction markets. See, for example, Glosten
(1994); Biais, Hillion, and Spat (1995); Chakravarty and Holden (1995); Harris and
Hasbrouck (1996); Handa and Schwartz (1996); Seppi (1996).
6. The terms ``dealer'' and ``marketmaker'' are typically interchangeable in the academic
literature. When there is a distinction, the term dealer is used for dealership-market
settings (like the FX market) and marketmaker is used for hybrid auction-dealership
settings (like the New York Stock Exchange). My use of these terms will be consistent
with this distinction throughout the book. I should also note that FX practitioners
typically use the term ``trader'' to describe a dealer. Because the term trader is rather
general, I opt for more specic terms when possible.
7. There is a screen called Reuters FXFX that displays dealer quotes, but these quotes
are not rm. (I provide more detail on the FXFX screen in chapter 5.) Though quotes
on the electronic brokerage screens that I describe later in this section are rm, these
brokerage quotes reect only a subset of rm quotes in the market at any given time.
For currency options, though some trading occurs on exchanges, most occurs in a
decentralized, multiple-dealer setting. For currency futures, trading around the world
tends to be centralized in various futures exchanges.
8. Though the spot FX market and the U.S. government bond market currently share
a similar structure, the way the bond market trades is evolving toward a more centralized auction structure (like the Paris Bourse and Hong Kong Stock Exchange, as
described above). See section 10.4 for more detail. Other countries' bond markets have
already moved to a centralized auction format (e.g., the Italian government bond
market). Recent work in the burgeoning literature on bond market microstructure
includes Fleming and Remolona (1999) and Vitale (1998).
284
Notes
9. See BIS (1999a). The interdealer share of volume for NASDAQ and SEAQ (London's
Stock Exchange Automated Quotations System) is less than 40 percent (see Reiss and
Werner 1995).
10. One of the big changes in the FX market over the last few years is the shift away
from voice-based brokers, where prices are advertised over intercoms at dealers'
desks, and toward electronic brokers, where prices are advertised over a screen. Indeed, there is evidence that the electronic brokers have also taken market share away
from direct interdealer trading (BIS 2001). Currently, the dominant electronic broker in
$/euro and $/yen is EBS. The other major electronic broker is Reuters 2000-2. For
more on this shift to electronic brokerage, see the Financial Times ``Survey: Foreign
Exchange,'' 5 June 1998. Interdealer brokers are also quite important in U.S. bond
markets.
11. I should mention two important variations on this story. First, banks do their best
to ``internalize'' as much customer order ow as possible. That is, they want to match
the incoming customer buy orders with incoming customer sell orders. When successful, any net ows that get passed on to the interdealer market are much reduced.
Second, the order ow lifecycle does not really ``end'' once nondealers reabsorb net
balances. Rather, that reabsorption moves through a ``chain'' of liquidity providers, the
rst nondealer link being hedge funds and banks' proprietary trading desks, and the
last link being so-called ``real money accounts.'' The real money accounts, such as
mutual funds and pension funds, are institutions that absorb positions over longer
horizons. Chapter 9 on customer trading provides more perspective.
12. One important source of noise comes from the fact that brokered trading systems
do not indicate the size of all individual transactions in real time, so it is not possible
from information about transactions' signs to construct an exact order ow measure.
For example, on the D2000-2 system, dealers only see an r on both the bid side and the
offer side if the quantity available at the best price is $10 million or more; otherwise, they see the quantity available. If, after a trade, the screen is still showing r on
both the bid and offer sides, then one cannot infer the size. Often, though, a trade
causes the size to drop below $10 million, or the quantity on one side is exhausted, in
which case dealers have received information about size. EBS, the other major electronic broker, is similar. Both systems also provide a high-frequency (but not complete) listing of deals as either ``paid'' or ``given,'' where paid indicates buyer-initiated
and given indicates seller-initiated.
Research data sets are a bit different. (In chapter 5 I review the data sets that cover
brokered interdealer trading.) These data sets, constructed from records well after
actual trading, provide exact measures of order ow, but these measures were not in
the dealers' information sets while trading.
13. For comparison, a stock selling at $50 per share with a spread of only 10 cents
would still translate into a spread of 20 basis points10 times that in $/euro.
14. There is a common misconception that dealers within a given bank pass their
positions from Tokyo to London to New York during each trading day. This is not true
in generalindividual dealers are responsible for managing their own positions. What
is true is that the bank's book of customer limit orders is passed from Tokyo to London
to New York. These unexecuted orders are not the same as dealer positions.
15. There are two nice multimedia resources that bring still more perspective on the
life of an FX dealer: (1) Goodhart and Payne 1999, and (2) Citibank's ``Bourse Course.''
The former provides a visual account of trading in an electronic interdealer broker
Notes
285
system (Reuters Dealing 2000-2). The latter is a simulated trading game designed to
replicate the FX market; it includes trading of all three types depicted in gure 3.1.
(Contact Citibank directly for more information.)
16. Chapter 5 describes the Reuters Dealing 2000-1 system in detail, including the rich
data it generates for empirical work.
17. For the equity dealer comparison, I use the numbers from Hansch et al. 1999 for
the London Stock Exchange because, unlike the NYSE, the LSE was a pure dealership
market and therefore more comparable to FX. The authors nd that dealers make a
prot of roughly 10 basis points on the average transaction. Though the authors do not
provide an average turnover by dealer, they do provide data that allow a rough estimate. The average daily turnover for FTSE-100 stocks is about $10 million (6.9 million). This total turnover is divided among dealers (active dealers make markets in
many stocks). Given the market shares the authors report for the more active dealers,
and given the number of stocks in which each makes markets, the estimated average
turnover of $10 million per dealer is about right.
18. The median quoted spread in the sample of 0.0003 DM/$ is the mode as well: that
spread size accounts for about three-quarters of all the dealer's bilateral interdealer
quotes.
19. The story is a bit subtler here, though, because this dealer does not have much
customer business. In my judgment, the right way to think about this dealer is that he
was supplying liquidity and inventory management services to other dealers that have
more customer business. So, in effect, there is a kind of ``tiering'' in the interdealer
marketFX dealers are not a homogeneous lot. My understanding is that dealers of
this type are much less protable now that electronic interdealer brokers play such an
important role (table 3.2 corresponds to a trading week in 1992).
20. An important determinant of whether $100,000 per day is ``large'' is the amount of
bank capital this dealer ties up when trading. If the capital required were $1 billion
per dayequal to his total volumethen $100,000 would be rather small. In reality,
the capital required to support a dealing operation like this one, which involves only
intraday positions, is far smaller than $1 billion. For more on whether banks' FX profits come from positioning versus intermediation, see Ammer and Brunner (1997).
21. Beyond the BIS, there are several institutions that serve as semi-ofcial coordinators in establishing FX trading practices and serving as forums for debate. In
the United States, that institution is the Foreign Exchange Committee of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York. For more information, see their Web site at hwww.ny.
frb.org/fxci.
22. The role of derivatives in determining market resilience and efciency was a topic
of increasing public policy concern in the 1990s. The considerable emphasis afforded
derivatives in the BIS survey is in keeping with this policy concern. One should not
lose sight, however, of the fact that in FX it is the spot markets that generate most of
the order ow (per my point in the text about the largest of the FX derivative marketsthat for forex swapsgenerating lots of turnover, but no order ow).
23. The statistic of 10 percent for 19891992 is (390/356) 1, with 390 being the corrected spot turnover for 1992 of 400(800/820) and 356 being the corrected spot turnover for 1989 of 350(600/590). Corrected spot turnovers for the other years are
calculated similarly. Note that this correction should be viewed as approximate for the
spot turnover because the mix of currencies that are traded spot does not match exactly the mix of currencies in total turnover.
286
Notes
24. Part of this large amount of dollar trading (but only part) is due to use of the dollar
as a vehicle currency. When the dollar is used as a vehicle, then when trading two nondollar currencies one does so indirectly, by going through the dollar rst. With the
launch of the euro, the dollar's role as an international currency has received much
attention recently. See, for example, Hartmann 1998a and Portes, and Rey 1998. Much
of the analysis in this area turns on microstructural matters; it is a natural application
of microstructure tools to what has traditionally been a macro topic.
25. Of the major central banks, only the Bank of Japan was intervening much in the
major markets at this time. See chapter 8 for more on intervention.
26. Do not be misled by the expression ``transacted by brokers'' that appears in the
rst sentence of section 7 (BIS 1999a): brokers do not themselves transact; they merely
facilitate the transactions of dealers (for a fee).
27. The U.K. market is the biggest in terms of spot trading, accounting for about 28
percent of the worldwide spot total (table E-9).
28. There is a second major policy issue in equity-market transparency that is more
relevant to pre-trade information: Is the public entitled to see all the price quotes that
the dealers observe? As for pre-trade transparency in FX, an issue that warrants
greater policy attention is whether customer limit orders at individual banks should be
exposed to the market at large (as was recently imposed on the U.S. NASDAQ market;
see Weston 2000). Aggregation of these limit orders represents, in some sense, the
wider market's latent demand.
29. I should add, though, that transparency in centralized exchange markets (stock
and futures exchanges) was historically imposed by the members on themselves, prior
to government regulation. For work on transparency in equity markets see, for example, Naik, Neuberger, and Viswanathan (1999) and Pagano and Roell (1996).
30. In June 2000, three investment banks (Goldman Sachs, Merrill Lynch, and Morgan
Stanley Dean Witter) announced that they were launching a centralized electronic
system for the U.S. bond markets (government and corporate bonds). This system, if
successful, represents a fundamental transformation of that market, not just in terms of
increased transparency, but also in terms of access and cost of liquidity.
31. As an aside, there is an interesting argument why increasing transparency of the
trading process might reduce the information in prices: increased transparency might
reduce incentives to invest in information production. This effect does not arise in
standard trading models because the amount of private and public information is
assumed xed.
32. I consider this possibility further in chapter 10.
Chapter 4.
Theoretical Frameworks
1. For a broader treatment of theoretical microstructure, see O'Hara (1995). For a recent survey, see Madhavan (2000). For historical perspective on trading models, see
Keynes (1936); Hicks (1939); Working (1953); and Houthakker (1957). For early
reviews of microstructure theory's relevance for the FX market, see Flood (1991) and
Suvanto (1993).
2. Even in quote-driven markets, though, order ow still drives price, not the other
way around (as we shall see in the models of this chapter).
Notes
287
288
Notes
14. The Grossman and Stiglitz (1980) version of the model has a nite number of
traders i i; . . . ; n, so the assumption of perfectly competitive behavior is less of a
stretch than in the two-trader case here (but still problematic). One technique commonly used to address the issue is to assume that the informed and uninformed represent separate continuums of traders, so that no one trader has a measurable impact
on price.
15. The literature on rational expectations models of trading is vast. Papers on how
prices aggregate information include Grossman (1977); Grossman and Stiglitz (1980);
Hellwig (1980); and Diamond and Verrecchia (1981). For papers on the existence of
equilibria and their degree of revelation, see the overview in Jordan and Radner (1982).
Papers that address connections between rational expectations models and microstructure models include Hellwig (1982); Kyle (1989); and Rochet and Vila (1995). For a
multiple-period rational expectations model and its application to the home-bias puzzle in international nance, see Brennan and Cao (1997). For applications to FX markets, see Bhattacharya and Weller (1997) and Montgomery and Popper (1998).
16. Though much macro information satises the rst of these two criteria, very little
macro information satises the second. See chapter 2 for more detail on specic types
of nonpublic information.
17. In general, opportunities for protable manipulation require situations where
markets are more liquid when investors are unwinding their trades than when the
original trades are made. For models that do permit some manipulation in equilibrium, see, e.g., Allen and Gorton (1992); Lyons (1997a); and Vitale (2000).
18. For expositional clarity, I continue to use this zero-mean specicationit has no
impact on the underlying economics.
19. The original Kyle paper (1985) has this same direct observation of V, rather than a
signal of V, as in the rational expectations auction model earlier in this chapter.
Changing the Kyle specication so that the informed trader observes a signal of V is
straightforward. Note that changing the specication of the rational expectations
model so that the informed trader observes V directly would result in full revelation:
the demand of the informed trader in equation (4.3) would be either positive or negative innity at any price other than the fully revealing price.
20. Note that the demand function introduced earlier in equation (4.3) does not appear
here. That demand function is inappropriate because the informed trader does not take
price as given (i.e., he is strategic).
21. See Subrahmanyam (1991); Admati and Peiderer (1988); and Holden and Subrahmanyam (1992), respectively. For a recent application of the Kyle (1985) model in
FX, see Vitale (1999). References to other variations on the Kyle model are available in
O'Hara (1995).
22. Recall from the introduction to this chapter that the traditional focus of inventory
models is transitory variation in price around xed expected payoffs, caused by some
inventory cost (the cost typically arises from risk aversion). The focus of information
models, in contrast, is permanent price adjustment toward changing future payoffs.
23. Most of the ``single-dealer'' models in the theoretical literature actually admit
multiple dealers, but Bertrand (price) competition sufces to restrict the problem to
one dealer.
Notes
289
24. For expositional clarity I am associating these insights with the sequential-trade
model. Given the sequencing of models in this chapter this is certainly the place that
they enter. These ideas have a history, however, that predates Glosten and Milgrom
(1985), the paper that develops the sequential-trade model. See, for example, Bagehot
(1971) and Copeland and Galai (1983).
25. More formally, price follows a Martingale with respect to an information set Wt if
EPt1 j Wt Pt .
26. See Easley and O'Hara (1987, 1992); and Easley et al. (1996), respectively.
27. This is especially true when considering multiple-dealer models that capture important features of the foreign exchange market. Work on multiple-dealer theory more
generally includes Ho and Stoll (1983); Leach and Madhavan (1993); Biais (1993); Perraudin and Vitale (1996); Vogler (1997); Werner (1997); Hau (1998); and Viswanathan
and Wang (1998). Most of these papers model a centralized interdealer market rather
than a decentralized market like that in FX. Also, unlike the simultaneous-trade model,
most of these models include either fundamental private information or risk aversion,
but not both.
28. Think of the common signal S as, say, a public macro announcement. The private
signal Si allows for information advantage beyond that which will arise from observing order ow. An example often cited by dealers is that Si could capture knowledge
of customers' identity and trading motiveshedge fund trades may have more price
impact than corporate trades. I choose to model this more metaphorically with Si ,
rather than introducing identity explicitly. Evidence that customer identities do indeed
matter is provided in chapter 9.
29. It is a simple matter to add spreads to the quotes that apply to the trading between
customers and dealers (e.g., to determine the number of participating dealers endogenously). Adding spreads to the interdealer quotes is more complex.
30. An unknown m becomes intractable, however, because it generates a non-Normal
position disturbance.
31. Other features are captured in various extensions of the model, including variable order ow transparency (Lyons 1996a) and interday trading (Evans and Lyons
2000).
32. That utility is negative under the negative exponential is not problematic: utility
functions capture the ordinal ranking of outcomes, not the absolute utility attached to
any given outcome. Adding a large positive constant to all these utility values would
not change individuals' decisions.
33. This is not to suggest that wealth redistribution is irrelevant in nancial markets.
One needs to use judgment about whether the question being addressed is one for
which redistribution is likely to matter.
Chapter 5.
Empirical Frameworks
1. See Goodhart and Figliuoli (1991) and Bollerslev and Domowitz (1993), among
many others. At the daily frequency, early work includes Glassman (1987); Bossaerts
and Hillion (1991); and Wei (1994).
290
Notes
2. See Lyons (1995); Goodhart et al. (1996); Yao (1998a); and Evans (1997). For an
emerging experimental literature on markets organized like FX, see Flood et al. (1999).
For a simulation methodology, see Flood (1994). For work on information networks
embedded in FX trading technologies, see Zaheer and Zaheer (1995). For work on
emerging-market currencies, see Goldberg (1993), Goldberg and Tenorio (1997), Carrera (1998); Galati (2000); and Becker, Chadha, and Sy (2000).
3. Two Web sites are valuable for obtaining more information on the systems that
produce the data. The rst covers the Reuters dealing systems, D2000-1 and D2000-2:
hwww.reuters.com/transactions/tran00m.htmi. The second covers the EBS system
used for brokered interdealer trading: hwww.ebsp.comi.
4. Though in number, fewer than 90 percent of the world's dealers in major spot
markets use the Dealing 2000-1 system, a higher percentage of the dollar value goes
through the system because the most active dealers use the system quite intensively.
5. Speaking of ``electronic trading systems'' without rst separating direct and brokered
trading can be quite misleading in terms of the information available to dealers while
trading. The D2000-2 system, like EBS, competed with traditional voice-based brokerage, and now these systems dominate the FX brokerage business (the voice-based
brokers have been driven out). Dealing 2000-1 is the electronic means for direct trading. In terms of information dissemination, though, electronic trading in these two
different segments is very different: a communication over D2000-1 is strictly bilateral,
whereas brokered trading communicates much more information to other dealers.
6. A data set of customer orders that hit the literature just as this book was going to
print is that in Osler (2001). Her data include roughly 10,000 customer limit orders
(including stop loss orders) from a ``large'' bank from September 1999 to April 2000
(mostly $/yen and $/euro).
7. There is a large and important body of empirical work that is based on these FXFX
data. My focus in this book, however, is order ow and its effects on price. Accordingly, work based on FXFX data does not gure as prominently here as it does in the
literature. For a survey that includes much of this FXFX work, see Goodhart and
O'Hara (1997).
8. A recently introduced data setnot summarized abovethat makes progress in
integrating data from multiple market segments is that in Bjonnes and Rime (2000).
9. A more recent approach that is not on my list is the structural sequential-trade
approach pioneered by Easley et al. (1996). This approach has not yet been applied to
FX markets.
10. The cited papers provide a good deal more detail on the approach for interested
readers. For an application to the Tokyo Stock Exchange, see Hamao and Hasbrouck
(1995).
11. When this approach is applied in a limit order auction setting, order ow is measured as described in chapter 1: trades are signed according to the direction of market
orders, with limit orders being the passive side of each trade. This is tantamount to
assuming that information is conveyed by market orders, whereas liquidity-providing
limit orders convey no information. In general, in models where informed traders can
choose between market and limit orders, they choose market orders, in part because
they do not want to advertise superior information in advance of execution (see, e.g.,
Harris and Hasbrouck 1996).
Notes
291
12. The variable xt takes different denitions in different applications, and can even be
dened more generally as a vector of characteristics. One common variation on the use
of signed order ow for xt is the use of a signed trade indicator, which takes the value
of one for an incoming buy and minus one for an incoming sell. Use of this trade indicator parallels closely the second of the two empirical approaches presented here
the Trade-Indicator approach.
13. In chapter 2, I dened private information as information that (1) is not known by
all people, and (2) produces a more precise price forecast than public information
alone. By this denition, superior information about FX dealer inventories that allows
one to more accurately forecast inventory effects is private information. However, this
type of private information may not help forecast price in the long run, which precludes it from being counted as information by the denition employed in the VAR
approach (equation 5.6).
14. The estimate by Payne (1999) may in fact be an underestimate because he uses
order ow from brokered interdealer trading (versus direct interdealer ow, such as
that used by Evans and Lyons 1999). Bjonnes and Rime (2000) nd that brokered
interdealer order ow conveys less information than direct ow. Reiss and Werner
(1999) nd a similar result for trading among dealers on the London Stock Exchange.
See also Saporta (1997).
15. To be fair, Huang and Stoll (1997) do estimate their TI model for three different
categories of trade size. This amounts to modeling size via splitting one's sample,
rather than modeling size explicitly.
16. Price can of course be moving over time for other reasons. I have chosen to
hold these other reasons constant in the gure to highlight this specic source of
transaction-price variation.
17. In this case, too, prices can be moving over time for other reasons. Also, the gure
assumes that the width of the spread does not change. This is the simplest case, and it
holds in some inventory models; however, it is not a general property of inventory
models. See O'Hara (1995) for more detail along these lines.
18. In implementing the model for NYSE stocks, the indicator Qt typically takes on
values f1; 0; 1g, where 0 is assigned if the trade is executed at the posted bid-ask
midpoint. Execution at the midpoint does not occur in pure dealer markers. But the
NYSE is not a pure dealer market (see chapter 3). It is possible on the NYSE for incoming orders to be executed at the midpoint (e.g., if two limit ordersone buy and
one sellarrive simultaneously with limit prices at the posted midpoint).
19. Let me provide an example of the type of question that spread decomposition can
address (one that is relevant to FX, given increasing concentration of the market
among the largest dealing banks). The example comes from a recent paper by Weston
(2000). He asks whether competition-increasing reforms on the Nasdaq reduced the
order-processing component of the spread. (Recall that the order-processing component also includes ``rents.'') He nds that they did, suggesting that the pre-reform
spreads were less than perfectly competitive.
20. Other work using structural models includes Foster and Viswanathan (1993),
which, like Madhavan and Smidt (1991), addresses the NYSE; structural models in a
multiple-dealer setting include Snell and Tonks (1995) for stocks and Vitale (1998) for
bonds.
292
Notes
21. The model in Lyons (1995) also makes another change to accommodate FX institutions: it incorporates the fact that FX dealers use inventory control methods that are
not available to a specialist (e.g., laying off inventory at another dealer's price). To
keep things simple, I omit this second change from the version of the model presented
here.
22. Estimation of the model can also accommodate variation in desired inventory. See
Lyons (1995).
23. The moving-average error term here comes from the inference problem embedded
in the model; see Madhavan and Smidt (1991) for details. I should also add that one
might be tempted to believe that estimation of this equation using OLS would be
biased because of correlation between Xjt and eit due to correlation between St and eit
(from equation 5.21). This is not true, however: because dealer i knows both St and eit
at the time of quoting, correlation between Xjt and eit is inconsistent with quotes being
regret free (i.e., it is inconsistent with rational expectations).
24. Recent work on markets other than FX may provide an explanation why the inventory effects on the dealer's own prices are so weak: non-FX dealers appear to hedge
a lot of their inventory risk using derivatives rather than winding down the inventory
itself (Reiss and Werner 1998; Naik and Yadav 2000). FX dealers, on the other hand, do
not use derivatives much; they nd it less expensive to control inventory with actual
spot trades (see Lyons 1995).
25. The work on transaction volume in nancial markets is vast. See, for example,
Karpoff (1986, 1987) and Wang (1994).
26. We do not yet know, for example, what share of interdealer trading is due to hot
potato trading.
Chapter 6.
1. When I use the symbol P in equations to denote the exchange rate, it will always
represent the dollar price of other currencies (i.e., $/other).
2. See the survey by Froot and Rogoff (1995) in the Handbook for International Economics.
3. Note that, though I motivated the model with the law of one price, it is not necessary that the law of one price hold for every good. PPP might still hold if, for example,
policymakers are successfully intervening in the FX market to maintain PPP. That said,
there are many reasons why PPP does not hold in the short run (such as nontradable
goods, trade barriers, and many others).
4. The approximation is close over shorter periods of time as long as interest rates and
rates of currency appreciation are not too large. Over periods of years or over periods
of hyperination the approximation can be quite imprecise.
5. This formulation is intended to speak to readers from the eld of nance who are
more familiar with valuation based on discounted cash ows. Readers from international economics will see their more familiar formulation based on discounted monetary and real variables in the following subsection.
6. For more detail, see the surveys by Taylor (1995) and Isard (1995). In particular,
these surveys provide ample evidence of these models' lack of empirical success
(which I revisit in chapter 7).
Notes
293
7. Readers familiar with exchange rates will recognize this version of PPP as the absolute version. The relative version is expressed in rst differences in logs, or Dp$=
DpUS DpUK , where the difference operator D denotes the change from time t 1 to
time t.
8. This is the equation for the ``LM'' curve in the familiar IS-LM model. Note that here
the ``money market'' is used in the narrow, macroeconomic sense of the market for
actual money, not in the broader practitioner sense of the market for xed-income
securities with maturity of one year or less.
9. I present here only the solution that excludes rational bubbles. As is standard,
equation (6.9) has an innite number of rational expectations solutions, but the others
include a bubble component in the price path. For more on solution techniques in
rational expectations models, see Blanchard and Fischer (1989), 261266.
10. The poor empirical performance of this and other macro models of this chapter is
documented in Meese and Rogoff (1983a, b), and surveyed more recently in Frankel
and Rose (1995).
11. Strictly speaking, PPP holds in the long run only in simpler versions of this model.
It does not hold in versions with real shocks, or other shocks requiring adjustment in
the long-run real exchange rate.
12. Overshooting does not necessarily occur in versions of the model that allow output y to vary.
13. In fact, iUS < iUK throughout the adjustment period in the standard model, which
means that the dollar is expected to appreciate monotonically toward its long-run
level.
14. More precisely, as a matter of balance of payments accounting, a current account
surplus must be offset in the capital account with a net increase in domestic claims
against the foreign economy (assuming no reserve transactions on the part of central
banks).
15. Another dimension of ``tastes'' in these models is the preferences of policymakers,
e.g., over various monetary policy rules.
16. For an extensive, nontechnical overview see Stockman (1987). For more recent GE
models, which include sticky prices, see Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996).
17. The word ``general'' in the name of this model stresses that the model includes
a wide array of different markets, all of which must clear simultaneously in equilibrium (e.g., individual goods markets, labor markets, bond markets, FX markets, etc.).
18. Whether this statement is strictly true depends on the breadth of one's denition of
microstructure. One literature that links to the real economy using microstructure
models is that on insider trading. In Leland (1992), for example, insider trading can
affect a rm's real investment.
19. Recall from the previous section that I referred to the GE model's cash-in-advance
constraint as ``technology.'' In contrast to production technology, it might be more
precise to refer to the cash-in-advance constraint as an institution, albeit a rather simple one.
20. Volatility determination has traditionally attracted a lot of attention from the
macro end of the spectrum. More recently, though, the literature has begun to address
294
Notes
FX volatility from the micro end of the spectrum, which is why I list this issue in the
middle group. Recent contributions from the micro end include Wei (1994); Andersen
(1996); Andersen and Bollerslev (1998); Hau (1998); Jeanne and Rose (1999); and Cai
et al. (1999).
Chapter 7.
Macro Puzzles
1. Per earlier chapters, the relevant literature is vast. At longer horizons, e.g., longer
than two years, macro models begin to dominate the random walk (e.g., Chinn 1991;
Mark 1995). But exchange rate determination remains a puzzle at horizons less than
two years (except in cases of hyperination, in which case the ination differential
asserts itself as a driving factor, in the spirit of PPPsee chapter 6).
2. The determination puzzle exists in equity markets as wellsee Roll (1988). Roll can
account for only 20 percent of daily stock returns using traditional equity fundamentals, a result he describes as a ``signicant challenge to our science.'' The microstructure approach had not been applied directly to the determination puzzle in equity
markets when Evans and Lyons (1999) applied it in the FX market.
3. Another alternative to traditional macro modeling is the recent ``new open-economy
macro'' approach (e.g., Obstfeld and Rogoff 1995see chapter 6). I do not address this
alternative here because, as yet, the approach has not produced empirical exchange
rate equations that alter the Meese-Rogoff (1983a) conclusions.
4. If order ow is an informative measure of macro expectations, then it should forecast surprises in important variables (like interest rates). New order ow data sets
that cover up to six years of FX tradingsuch as the data set I examine in chapter
9provide enough statistical power to test this. The Evans (1997) data set used
by Evans and Lyons (1999) is only four months, so they are not able to push in this
direction.
5. Chapter 2 introduces two subcategories of discount rate information: information
about inventory effects and information about portfolio balance effects. I do not consider information about inventory effects in this chapter because inventory effects are
transitory, and are therefore unlikely to be relevant for longer horizon macro puzzles.
6. As a practical matter, however, the underlying causes of order ow X may not
captured by traditional specications of i; m; z in empirical portfolio balance models.
Note, too, that I do not consider the general equilibrium (GE) macro model in this
discussion. For the GE model, it is difcult to make meaningful statements about
whether X and i; m; z are independent when X is conveying information about portfolio balance effects: it depends on the GE model's specic features. (To clarify terms,
when X is conveying this type of information in GE models, it is conveying information about ``pricing kernels''the general-equilibrium analogue of discount rates.)
7. As in the simultaneous-trade model, introducing a bid-offer spread (or price schedule) in round one to endogenize the number of dealers is a straightforward extension.
8. Recall from chapter 4 that simultaneous and independent interdealer trades Tit
implies that dealers cannot condition on one another's trades in a given round.
9. This is tantamount to assuming thatwhen it comes to bearing overnight riskthe
dealers' capacity is small relative to the capacity of the whole public.
Notes
295
10. Note that this equation describes a cointegrating (i.e., long-run) relationship that
includes the level of price and cumulative interdealer order ow, which we revisit in
section 7.3.
11. This model can also be used to generate multiple equilibria. Introducing multiple
equilibria obscures the essential portfolio balance logic, however, so I do not pursue
this direction here.
12. In the Evans-Lyons model, these are exogenous. If one were to model them
explicitly, they could arise from any number of motives, including hedging demand,
liquidity demand, and changing risk preferences.
13. Consider an example. Starting from Xt 0, an initial customer sale to a dealer does
not move Xt from zero because Xt measures interdealer order ow only. After the
customer sale (say of one unit), then when dealer i unloads the position by selling to
another dealer, dealer j, Xt drops to 1. A subsequent sale by dealer j to another
dealer, dealer k, reduces Xt further to 2. If a customer happens to buy dealer k's
position from him, then the process comes to rest with Xt at 2. In this simple scenario,
order ow measured only from trades between customers and dealers would have
reverted to zero: the concluding customer trade offsets the initiating customer trade,
putting a stop to the hot potato. The interdealer order ow, however, does not revert
to zero.
14. Cheung and Chinn (1999b) corroborate this empirically: their surveys of foreign
exchange traders show that the importance of individual macroeconomic variables
shifts over time, but ``interest rates always appear to be important.''
15. As a diagnostic, though, Evans and Lyons also estimate the model using the level
of the differential, in the manner of Uncovered Interest Parity, and nd similar results.
16. There is a vast empirical literature that attempts to increase the explanatory power
of interest rates in exchange rate equations (by introducing individual interest rates as
separate regressors, by introducing nonlinearities, etc.). Because these efforts have not
been successful, it is very unlikely that variations on the interest rate specication
could alter the relative importance of order ow.
17. Recall from chapter 5 that one of the shortcomings of the Evans (1997) data set is
that it does not include the size of each trade, so that order ow is measured as the
number of buys minus the number of sells. (However, the data set does include the
total volume over the sample, so that an average trade size can be calculated.) This
shortcoming must be kept in perspective, however: if the Evans-Lyons results were
negative, then data concerns would be serious indeedthe negative results could
easily be due to noisy data. But their results are quite positive, which noise alone could
not produce. Indeed, that there is noise in the data only underscores the apparent
strength of the order ow/price relation.
18. These higher coefcients at higher activity levels are consistent with the ``event
uncertainty'' model described in chapter 5 (see Easley and O'Hara 1992). It should be
noted, though, that the daily frequency of the Evans-Lyons analysis is lower than the
typical transaction frequency tests of event uncertainty. Results from intraday analysis
of the Evans (1997) data paint a different picturesee chapter 8.
19. A direct role for macro announcements in determining order ow warrants exploring as well. Another possible use of macro announcements is to introduce them
directly into an Evans-Lyons-type regression. However, this tack is not likely to be
296
Notes
fruitful: there is a long literature showing that macro announcements are unable to
account for exchange rate rst moments (though they do help to account for second
momentssee Andersen and Bollerslev 1998).
20. See Osler (1998) and Carlson and Osler (2000) for models in which current account
ows are central to exchange rate determination. Unlike traditional ow approach
models, the exchange rate in these models is determined in its own speculative market.
21. I would add that this analogy also sheds light on the asset approach. In the asset
approach, too, there is no inference effect of order ow on price because all information is public, by assumption (i.e., public information is a sufcient statistic for price).
22. Contrary to popular belief, in an absolute sense, exchange rates are less volatile
than stock prices: the annual standard deviation of exchange rate returns is in the 10
12 percent range for major currencies against the dollar, whereas the annual standard
deviation of equity market returns is in the 1520 percent range (and for individual
stocks it is higher still).
23. Exchange rate regimes are not limited to oating and xed. They fall along a
spectrum. Ordered in terms of increasing commitment to the exchange rate target,
these regimes include: (1) free oat, (2) dirty oat, (3) target zone, (4) pegxed or
crawling, (5) currency board, and (6) monetary union. A dirty oat involves some
limited intervention. A currency board is an institutional commitment to dedicate
monetary policy to the exchange rate target. For more on the differences between these
regimes, see, for example, Krugman and Obstfeld (2000).
24. The transition from EMS to EMU was indisputably a transition toward exchange
rate xity. KLM assume that EMU was perfectly credible after the weekend of May 2
3, 1998the date the eleven ``in'' countries were selected and the date the internal
conversion rates for the euro-zone were determined. Extending their model to environments of imperfectly credible xed rates is a natural direction for further research.
25. The logic of this examplebased on the polar extreme of perfectly xed rates
also holds for intermediate regimes under which some volatility remains.
26. Nonstationary variables are cointegrated if there exists a linear combination of
them that is stationary. Cointegration means that although many developments can
cause permanent changes in these three series, there is an equilibrium relation that ties
them together in the long run. A good reference on cointegration is Hamilton (1994),
chapter 19.
27. EBS has a prescreened credit facility whereby dealers can only see prices for trades
that would not violate their counterparty credit limits, thereby eliminating the potential for failed deals due to these limits.
28. In their sample, the mean value of cumulative order ow is DM1.38 billion.
29. This is a theoretical point. Empirically, it appears that there was little intervention
by the national central banks or the ECB in the period from May to December 1998
(verication is difcult because these banks are not terribly forthcoming with intervention data over this period).
30. This type of bias is often referred to as ``conditional bias'' to distinguish it from
``unconditional bias.'' Conditional bias refers to the fact that to predict whether Pt1
will be lower than Ft; 1 , one needs to ``condition'' (i.e., base the prediction) on whether
Ft; 1 > Pt . Forward rates would be unconditionally biased if the average of Ft; 1 Pt1 is
Notes
297
statistically different from zero (there is no conditioning in this case on time t information). Unconditionally, major-currency forward rates tend to be unbiased (see, for
example, Perold and Schulman 1988).
31. A no-arbitrage relation called covered interest parity (introduced in an early footnote in chapter 3) requires that the forward discount equal the interest differential (as
long as there are no capital market controls that prevent arbitrage trades). This yields a
regression that is equivalent to equation (7.15) with the one-period interest differential
on the righthand side (i$ iother ) in lieu of the forward discount ft; 1 pt . Many
authors in this literature estimate equation (7.15) in this interest-differential form (in
effect, a test of uncovered interest parityintroduced in chapter 6).
32. Though I have introduced the two main economic explanations for bias
inefciency versus risk premiumthere is a third explanation that any anomaly must
confront, namely measurement error (broadly dened), i.e., that the anomaly doesn't
really exist. In the forward bias literature, the measurement error explanation is typically referred to as the ``peso problem.'' The name comes from a period through which
the Mexican peso was consistently selling at a forward discount because the market
felt devaluation was possible. When, over many years, the devaluation didn't occur,
it appeared in-sample as though the forward rate was biased, consistently overpredicting the exchange rate change. Estimates of the coefcient b are biased in this
case because the measured changes in exchange rates do not match what the market
expected (a small sample problem). Engel (1996) provides several arguments that
make the peso problem explanation difcultbut not impossibleto defend in the
context of the major exchange rates. (See Lewis 1995 for a thorough survey in which
she rightly points out that alternative hypotheses to the bias anomaly are not mutually
exclusive.)
33. The currency trading strategy here would entail selling foreign currency forward
when ft; 1 > pt and buying foreign currency forward when ft; 1 < pt . To understand
why, recall that when ft; 1 > pt , then on average pt1 ends up below ft; 1 . One can expect
to prot from locking in a sale of foreign currency at a dollar price of ft; 1 when the
expected market price (value) at t 1 is below ft; 1 . Similarly for the case when ft; 1 < pt :
one can expect to prot from having locked in a purchase of foreign currency at a
dollar price of ft; 1 when the expected market price (cost) at t 1 is above ft; 1 . (One
could trade this in an equivalent way by borrowing in the low interest rate currency
and investing in the deposit of the high interest rate currency.) Finally, by ``buy-andhold equity strategy'' I mean a simple strategy of buying and holding an equity index
fund (e.g., a fund that tracks the S&P 500 index).
34. The Sharpe ratio, named after Nobel prize winner William Sharpe, has a natural
interpretation in the standard diagram used to illustrate the Capital Asset Pricing
Model (CAPM): with expected return on the vertical axis and return standard deviation on the horizontal axis, every security (or portfolio) that lies on a ray originating
from the vertical axis at the risk-free rate has the same Sharpe ratio. For example, in a
CAPM with lending and borrowing, every point on the ray from the risk-free rate
through the tangency point on the efcient frontier has the same Sharpe ratio. In a
frictionless environment, using a Sharpe ratio criterion to select among investments is
optimal only if the investments are mutually exclusive.
35. Remember that order ow and volume are quite different: order ow is signed
volume (i.e., sell orders have a negative sign).
36. It is true that the high historical returns on U.S. equities are themselves a puzzle
(the so-called equity premium puzzle). Given those high risk-adjusted equity returns,
298
Notes
Notes
299
45. This particular thought experiment is essentially the same as that of Froot and
Thaler (1990, 188). Missing from their story, however, is a reason why the seemingly
large prot opportunity can persist (indeed, they describe this missing feature as an
``apparently serious aw'' in their story). My explanation does provide persistence: it
comes from institutions' Sharpe ratio based evaluation of risk. In the last sentence of
their article, Froot and Thaler point in the general direction of my approach when they
write, ``Although much of the risk in these strategies may be diversiable in principle,
more complex diversied strategies may be much more costly, unreliable, or difcult
to execute.'' See also Carlson (1998) for a gamblers' ruin model of why institutions put
tight limits on FX position taking. For a microstructure analysis of interest rate
increases at times of xed-rate crisis, see Lyons and Rose (1995).
46. As an empirical matter, this story of gradual adjustment to monetary policy
changes is borne out in the datasee Eichenbaum and Evans (1995).
47. One might wonder whether the bias from a coefcient b of 0.9 is large enough to
be consistent with an exchange rate that is misaligned by 20 percent. To understand
why it can be consistent, note that the 20 percent misalignment is in the current exchange rate level, which impounds the whole stream of future one-month bias realizations; 20 percent is not an indicator of bias over short horizons (otherwise it truly
would be an extraordinary trading opportunity).
48. Though order ow is clearly insufcient, I do not mean to suggest that the disparity is not being traded. Long Term Capital Management, for example, was one of
several institutions that selectively opened positions based on this disparity.
Chapter 8.
300
Notes
5. Central banks now also trade via interdealer brokers like EBS. Because brokermarket counterparties are dealing banks, the balance sheet effects are the same. One
difference that arises from trading via brokers that is not reected in balance sheets is
the degree of transparency: central bank trades done directly with a single dealer are
less transparent than central bank trades done via brokers (more on this below,
including the use of agents to protect central bank secrecy).
6. Though not essential to the story, it should be noted that foreign exchange reserves
held by central banks are not held in the form of currency, which earns no interest, but
mostly in the form of foreign government bonds. Foreign bonds have to be liquidated
to generate the yen used for payment by the Fed. Making this point explicit helps one
understand why there is not also an effect on the yen money supply from the Fed
``injecting'' $100 million worth of yen: the net effect of these transactions on the Fed's
holding of yen currency is zero.
7. Harder to understand is why the central bank would want to intervene in an
unannounced way if it intends to send a signal to the market. (I describe unannounced
intervention below.) There is no obvious rationale for this. See Dominguez and Frankel
(1993b) for a discussion.
8. Equations (6.14) and (6.15)which describe the macro portfolio balance model
provide a sense for how the two bond demands would have to adjust to accommodate
a change in supply: with xed interest rates, expected dollar depreciation, E%DP,
must change. Holding the long-run nominal value of the dollar xed, an increase in the
current value of the dollar will increase the expected rate of dollar depreciation. This
effect is akin to changing the price of a bondwhich has a xed terminal payoffin
order to change its expected return (yield).
9. I do not address the distinction between coordinated and uncoordinated central
bank intervention (i.e., coordination across central banks). For more on this topic, see
the surveys cited at the outset of this chapter.
10. Or, as is common more recently, monetary policy can be dedicated to achieving
explicit ination targets.
11. It is important to remember that order ow being near zero does not imply that
trading volume must be near zero.
12. Less clear from the context of the quoted paragraph is whether Dominguez and
Frankel consider the news effectwhich ``causes investors to revise their expectations
of future rates of return''to include only the signaling channel (i.e., payoff information), or whether it includes the portfolio balance channel (which also changes
expectations of future returns). If the latter, then their direct effect on price is probably
best thought of as representing the third information category of chapter 2: information about inventory effects.
13. This is true even in the case where intervention is announced. For announced intervention to eliminate information asymmetry, it would have to: (1) be fully credible;
(2) be fully informative regarding the size, direction, and timing of the trade; and (3)
occur in advance of, or simultaneously with, the trade. There are no ``announced''
interventions in the existing empirical literature that fulll these conditions. Moreover,
even these conditionsas strong as they areare not sufcient to eliminate an order
ow role: it would also have to be true that market participants agree on intervention's
implications.
Notes
301
14. Recall from the discussion of the Kyle model in section 4.2 that the risk neutrality
of the dealer precludes portfolio balance effects on price. Because of this narrow context, use of the term ``fundamental'' is appropriate. Regarding broader notions of fundamentals, see the discussion in section 2.3.
15. It is worth noting that, at times, the objective of central banks is to minimize the
price impact of their trades. This is the case, for example, when they are trying to
rebalance their portfolio of foreign exchange reserves, without any intention of moving
exchange rates. The intervention rules from the Evans and Lyons (2000) analysis are
useful for this objective as well.
16. For other empirical papers on intervention that use microstructure-style approaches, see Bossaerts and Hillion (1991); Goodhart and Hesse (1993); Peiers (1997);
Naranjo and Nimalendran (2000); Chang and Taylor (1998); Fischer and Zurlinden
(1999); Dominguez (1999); De Jong et al. (1999); Payne and Vitale (2000) and Chaboud
and LeBaron (2001).
17. Though indistinguishable, this is not to say that trades of these two types come
from the same distribution. Indeed, an interesting issue for future work is the extent to
which the market would adjust the mean of expected central bank orders (in the spirit
of the Lucas critique) if the central bank began to intervene secretly in a more aggressive way.
18. Recall from chapter 2 that my denition of private information is broad: information qualies as private as long as it is not known by all people and produces a better
forecast of price than public information alone. Private information does not have to be
inside information about the Fed's next interest rate move.
19. The model also claries why this learning is based on trades between dealers.
Interdealer ow is, in reality, the variable that price setters (dealers) are reacting to
when intervention is secret.
20. The model treats the central bank trade as exogenous, with expected value zero.
This might be viewed as a normalization around an ``expected'' intervention trade.
Note too that the central bank here is initiating all its trades. This is reasonable because
central banks are like other customers in this sense. In a xed rate regime, however,
where a central bank is obligated to absorb ow, the central bank will often be on the
passive side: dealers and customers initiate trades with the central bank to lay off
unwanted positions.
21. Evans and Lyons present this estimate as a ``lower bound.'' In their model, interdealer ow is equal to customer ow times a constant, a b 1. Thus, by measuring the
price impact of interdealer order ow they are underestimating the price impact of
customer tradesincluding the trades of the central bankby a factor of a. Be that as
it may, this 1-percent-per-$2-billion estimate provides some sense for why portfolio
balance effects from sterilized intervention have been so hard to detect empirically: the
average intervention trade of $200 million (Dominguez and Frankel 1993b) would
have a price impact of only about 10 basis points.
22. Because I am referring to secret intervention here, there is no way for the public to
respond to a change in central bank strategy and fully undo it. That said, one would
expect the public's trading strategiesand dealer's pricing rulesto be affected by a
changed intervention strategy. This is an interesting avenue for future theoretical work
within the microstructure approach.
302
Chapter 9.
Notes
Customers
1. By analogy, it is not unreasonable to view rms that trade on the NYSE as fundamentally the same as rms that trade on the NASDAQ, other things equal (i.e., similar
cost of capital, similar relative valuation, etc.). The distinction between them boils
down to what I called in chapter 3 the ``microstructure effects'' question. Per earlier
chapters, the microstructure effects question is not the focus of this book.
2. Recall, too, the discussion and quotations in chapter 3 regarding customer order
ows.
3. For practitioner-oriented research on order ow effects on exchange rates, see, e.g.,
Citibank's Citiows Global Flow and Volume Analysis (various issues); Deutschebank's
Flowmetrics Monthly (various issues); and Lehman Brothers' Global Economic Research
Series, particularly the issue on ``FX Impact of Cross-Border M&A.'' For evidence from
practitioner surveys on the use of ow analysis, see Gehrig and Menkhoff (2000).
4. Balance of payments accounts are based on the concept of residency. They are a
statistical record of the economic transactions taking place between a nation's residents and the rest of the world.
5. Recall that the Evans-Lyons model of chapter 8 was designed (in part) to show that
even with short-lived dealer positions, interdealer order ow still has persistent effects
on price because it conveys information about the persistent portfolio shifts of underlying customers.
6. One could argue that in frictionless general equilibrium, starting from paretooptimal allocations, it is not clear why rms' ex ante ``portfolios'' are not instantaneously restored. As an empirical matter, this objection to my example is not so
compelling. For many institution types, there are substantial (labor intensive) costs of
adjusting their net positions in the market. This may produce path dependence in
portfolio allocation, even if the relation between realized order ow and price is
unique.
7. A future direction for research in this area is to isolate categories of trades that t
neatly into a particular balance of payments category. For example, one could isolate
equity mutual funds. In this case, one could be condent that their FX trades t neatly
into the category called international portfolio investment.
8. A natural question is where the trades of central banks appear. The source of these
data is reluctant to disclose the specics. Though not reported in the table, the source
bank does maintain a small fourth category of customer, called ``miscellaneous.''
Though the trades within this category are quite small relative to the trades in the
three main categories, the category is likely to include any central bank trades for
which the source bank was the counterparty. (Recall from chapter 8 that central bank
trades tend to be small relative to private trades.)
9. The yen plot begins in January 1996 because the source bank did not include customer ow data from its Tokyo ofce in its database until late 1995. (The Tokyo ofce
is especially important for this bank's $/yen customer ow.) Note that this may account for the seemingly small share of non-nancial corporate trading in total customer trading in $/yen shown in table 9.1: If nonnancial corporations tend to trade
via their regional ofce, whereas nancial institutions tend to trade on a 24-hour basis
worldwide, then the customer trades in the database before 1996 would be tilted
toward the nancial institutions.
Notes
303
10. Integrating macro variables into this monthly regression is an important topic for
future work.
11. Because these customer ow data are not available publicly, forecasting power is
not ruled out on the basis of market efciency (e.g., on the basis of semi-strong form
efciency, under which price impounds all publicly available information). Note too
that differential price impact leaves room for the (theoretical) possibility of market
manipulation by customers who can disguise the source of trades. For a nice treatment
of traditional forecasting techniques for FX markets, see Rosenberg (1996).
12. There is a comprehensive description of events in BIS (1999b).
Chapter 10.
Looking Forward
1. Recall from chapter 1 that my focus in this book is on analysis based on order ow.
There is a lot of ne work on high-frequency exchange rates that does not integrate
order ow. For more on this branch of the literature, see the survey by Goodhart and
O'Hara (1997).
2. Resolving these differences may lie in the fact that non-FX marketmakers hedge inventory risk with instruments other than those in which they make the market (e.g.,
with related derivatives), whereas spot FX dealers nd that inventory control using
spot currencies alone is least expensive. See Reiss and Werner (1998) and Naik and
Yadav (2000) for evidence that non-FX marketmakers do indeed use derivatives for
inventory control.
3. For the NYSE, a possible resolution of these differences lies in the obligation of the
NYSE specialist to smooth prices, a task that existing inventory may facilitate.
4. If, in the end, the portfolio balance view of order ow's price effects wins out, a
subsidiary question remains: what is driving the portfolio shifts? Possibilities (mentioned in earlier chapters) include changing risk preferences, changing hedging
demands, changing liquidity demands, and changing (payoff unrelated) opinions.
5. Part of closing the gap with macro analysis will come from theoretical advances. A
natural direction along these lines is models of market incompleteness (of various
types), which t naturally with current empirical results on order ow. For a contact
point with recent work on dynamic open-economy models, see Duarte and Stockman
(2001).
6. A precondition for integrating data is availability. At present, much of the data
used in this literature is not publicly available. (As noted in chapter 5, my Web site
provides links to data sets that are publicly available.) Moving forward, one hopes that
sources of these data will recognize the value of making them available to researchers
generally.
7. Interested readers should see the material on FXNeta system for managing settlement riskon the EBS Web site (hwww.ebsp.comi).
8. One paper that addresses speculative attacks in Mexico using a microstructure
approach is Carrera (1999).
9. For an interesting article on the advent of electronic trading in FX, see Euromoney
(2000). For equity markets, Institutional Investor (2000) is a nice treatment of the electronic trading threat to more traditional trading methods.
304
Notes
10. Frankel (1996, 62) was perhaps the rst to write about such a scenario in FX,
though he was considering a Tobin tax as the possible trigger. He wrote: ``It is possible
that the imposition of a Tobin tax . . . would alter the structure of the market in a fundamental way. It might become more like other major nancial markets, in which a
sale or purchase by a customer generates only one or two transactions, rather than ve
or eight. This would be the case particularly if such a tax triggered a transition to a
new trading structure equilibrium, with the decentralized dealer network . . . replaced
by a system in which foreign currency was traded on a centralized exchange in the
manner of the NYSE.'' For more on the legal history relating to openness of broker
systems to nondealers, see Levich (2001, 100).
11. For a theoretical treatment of whether centralized limit order structures are likely
to capture liquidity and thereby dominate trading, see Glosten (1994). An issue not
addressed in that paper that is important for FX is credit risk. I noted in the previous
section that bank dealers may have a comparative advantage in managing the credit
risk arising from large transactions with customers. New entrants who want to centralize this market around an electronic trading platform need to solve this problem
because non-nancial corporations do not want to take the counterparty credit risk
that banks are comfortable taking. The standard approach is to establish a clearing
house system with margin accounts (akin to those used in futures markets).
References
Admati, A., and P. Peiderer. 1988. A theory of intraday patterns: Volume and price
variability. Review of Financial Studies 1: 340.
Allen, F., and G. Gorton. 1992. Stock price manipulation, market microstructure and
asymmetric information. European Economic Review 36: 624630.
Amihud, Y., and H. Mendelson. 1980. Dealership markets: Marketmaking with inventory. Journal of Financial Economics 8: 3153.
Ammer, J., and Brunner, A. 1997. Are banks market timers or market makers?
Explaining foreign exchange trading prots. Journal of International Financial Markets,
Institutions & Money 7: 4360.
Andersen, T. 1996. Return volatility and trading volume: An information ow interpretation of stochastic volatility. Journal of Finance 51: 169204.
Andersen, T., and T. Bollerslev. 1997. Heterogeneous information arrivals and return
volatility dynamics: Uncovering the long-run in high frequency returns. Journal of
Finance 52: 9751006.
Andersen, T., and T. Bollerslev. 1998. Deutsche mark-dollar volatility: Intraday activity patterns, macroeconomic announcements, and longer run dependencies. Journal of
Finance 53: 219266.
Andersen, T., T. Bollerslev, and A. Das. 2001. Variance-ratio statistics and highfrequency data: Testing for changes in intraday volatility patterns. Journal of Finance
56: 305328.
Backus, D., A. Gregory, and C. Telmer. 1993. Accounting for forward rates in markets
for foreign currency. Journal of Finance 48: 18871908.
Bagehot, W. 1971. The only game in town. Financial Analysts Journal 27: 1222.
Bagwell, L. 1992. Dutch auction repurchases: An analysis of shareholder heterogeneity. Journal of Finance 47: 71105.
Baillie, R., and T. Bollerslev. 1991. Intra-day and inter-market volatility in foreign exchange rates. Review of Economic Studies 58: 565585.
Baldwin, R. 1990. Reinterpreting the failure of foreign exchange market efciency tests:
Small transactions costs, large hysteresis bands. NBER Working Paper 3319.
306
References
Bank for International Settlements. 1996. Central bank survey of foreign exchange
market activity in April 1995. Publication of the Monetary and Economics Department,
BIS, March.
Bank for International Settlements. 1999a. Central bank survey of foreign exchange
market activity in April 1998. Publication of the Monetary and Economics Department,
BIS, May (available at www.bis.org).
Bank for International Settlements. 1999b. A review of nancial market events in
autumn 1998. Publication of the Committee on the Global Financial System, October.
Bank for International Settlements. 2001. BIS 71st Annual Report, June (available at
www.bis.org).
Bank for International Settlements. 2002. Central bank survey of foreign exchange
market activity in April 2001. Publication of the Monetary and Economics Department,
BIS, forthcoming (available at www.bis.org).
Bank of England. 1998. The UK foreign exchange and over-the-counter derivatives
markets in April 1998, September (available at www.bankofengland.co.uk).
Becker, T., B. Chadha, and A. Sy. 2000. Foreign exchange bid-ask spreads in the Asian
crisis. Typescript, International Monetary Fund, April.
Bessembinder, H. 1994. Bid-ask spreads in the interbank foreign exchange market.
Journal of Financial Economics 35: 317348.
Bhattacharya, U., and P. Weller. 1997. The advantage of hiding one's hand: Speculation and central bank intervention in the foreign exchange market. Journal of Monetary
Economics 39: 251277.
Biais, B. 1993. Price formation and equilibrium liquidity in fragmented and centralized
markets. Journal of Finance 48: 157184.
Biais, B., P. Hillion, and C. Spatt. 1995. An empirical analysis of the limit order book
and the order ow in the Paris bourse. Journal of Finance 50: 16551689.
Biais, B., P. Hillion, and C. Spatt. 1999. Price discovery and learning during the preopening period in the Paris Bourse. Journal of Political Economy 107: 12181248.
Bishop, M. 1996. Corporate risk management. The Economist, survey October 2, 1996.
Bjonnes, G., and D. Rime. 2000. FX trading . . . live: Dealer behavior and trading systems in foreign exchange markets. Typescript, Norwegian School of Management,
August.
Blanchard, O., and S. Fischer. 1989. Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
Blume, L., D. Easley, and M. O'Hara. 1994. Market statistics and technical analysis:
The role of volume. Journal of Finance 49: 153182.
Board, J., and C. Sutcliffe. 1995. The effects of trade transparency in the London stock
exchange. Report commissioned by the London Stock Exchange, January.
Bollerslev, T., and I. Domowitz. 1993. Trading patterns and prices in the interbank
foreign exchange market. Journal of Finance 48: 14211443.
References
307
Bollerslev, T., and M. Melvin. 1994. Bid-ask spreads and volatility in the foreign
exchange market: An empirical analysis. Journal of International Economics 36: 355
372.
Bossaerts, P., and P. Hillion. 1991. Market microstructure effects of government intervention in the foreign exchange market. Review of Financial Studies 4: 513541.
Branson, W., and D. Henderson. 1985. The specication and inuence of asset markets. In Handbook of International Economics, vol. 2, edited by R. Jones and P. Kenen.
Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Brennan, M., and H. Cao. 1996. Information, trade, and derivative securities. Review of
Financial Studies 9: 163208.
Brennan, M., and H. Cao. 1997. International portfolio investment ows. Journal of
Finance 52: 18511880.
Brock, W., and A. Kleidon. 1992. Periodic market closure and trading volume: A model
of intraday bids and asks. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 16: 451489.
Burnham, J. 1991. Current structure and recent developments in foreign exchange
markets. In Recent Developments in International Banking and Finance, edited by
S. Khoury. Amsterdam: Elsevier North Holland.
Caballero, R., E. Engel, and J. Haltiwanger. 1997. Aggregate employment dynamics:
Building from microeconomics. American Economic Review 87: 115137.
Cai, J., Y. Cheung, R. Lee, and M. Melvin. 1999. ``Once in a generation'' yen volatility in
1998: Fundamentals, intervention, or order ow? Typescript, Arizona State University,
July.
Calvo, G. 1999. Contagion in emerging markets: When Wall Street is a carrier. Working
paper, University of Maryland.
Cao, H. 1999. The effect of derivative assets on information acquisition and price
behavior in a rational expectations equilibrium. Review of Financial Studies 12: 131
164.
Cao, H., and R. Lyons. 1998. Inventory information. Working paper, Haas School of
Business, U.C. Berkeley, August.
Carlson, J., 1998. Risk aversion, foreign exchange speculation and gambler's ruin.
Economica 65: 441453.
Carlson, J., and C. Osler. 1999. Determinants of currency risk premiums. Typescript,
New York Federal Reserve Bank, February.
Carlson, J., and C. Osler. 2000. Rational speculators and exchange rate volatility.
European Economic Review 44: 231253.
Carrera, J. 1999. Speculative attacks to currency target zones: A market microstructure
approach. Journal of Empirical Finance 6: 555582.
Chaboud, A., and B. LeBaron. 2001. Foreign exchange trading volume and Federal
Reserve intervention. Journal of Futures Markets, forthcoming.
Chakrabarti, R. 2000. Just another day in the interbank foreign exchange market. Journal of Financial Economics 56: 2964.
308
References
Chakravarty, S., and C. Holden. 1995. An integrated model of market and limit orders.
Journal of Financial Intermediation 4: 213241.
Chang, Y., and S. Taylor. 1998. Intraday effects of foreign exchange intervention by the
Bank of Japan. Journal of International Money and Finance 18: 191210.
Chen, Z. 1997. Speculative market structure and the collapse of an exchange rate
mechanism. Working paper, London School of Economics.
Cheung, Y., and M. Chinn. 1999a. Traders, market microstructure, and exchange rate
dynamics. NBER Working paper 7416, November. Journal of International Money and
Finance.
Cheung, Y., and M. Chinn. 1999b. Macroeconomic implications of the beliefs and
behavior of foreign exchange traders. NBER Working paper 7417, November.
Cheung, Y., M. Chinn, and I. Marsh. 1999. How do UK-based foreign exchange dealers
think their market operates? CEPR Discussion Paper 2230, September.
Cheung, Y., and C. Yuk-Pang. 1999. Foreign exchange traders in Hong Kong, Tokyo,
and Singapore: A survey study. U.C. Santa Cruz Department of Economics Working
Paper a425, January.
Cheung, Y., and C. Yuk-Pang. 2000. A survey of market practitioners' views on
exchange rate dynamics. Journal of International Economics 51: 401423.
Chinn, M. 1991. Some linear and non-linear thoughts on exchange rates. Journal of
International Money and Finance 10: 214230.
Chinn, M., and R. Meese. 1994. Banking on currency forecasts. Journal of International
Economics 38: 161178.
Citibank. 2001. Citiows Global Flow and Volume Analysis (various issues). London:
Citibank, NA (email: [email protected]).
Clyde, W. 1993. Intraday foreign exchange market anomalies and microstructure.
Working paper, Quinnipiac College, August.
Copeland, T., and D. Galai. 1983. Information effects and the bid-ask spread. Journal of
Finance 38: 14571469.
Corsetti, G., S. Morris, and H. Shin. 1999. Does one Soros make a difference? The role
of a large trader in currency crises. Typescript, Yale University, March.
Covrig, V., and M. Melvin. 1998. Asymmetric information and price discovery in
the FX market: Does Tokyo know more about the yen? Typescript, Arizona State
University.
Dacorogna, M., U. Muller, R. Nagler, R. Olsen, and O. Pictet. 1993. A geographical
model for the daily and weekly seasonal volatility in the FX market. Journal of International Money and Finance 12: 413438.
Danielsson, J., and R. Payne. 1999. Real trading patterns and prices in spot foreign
exchange markets. Typescript, London School of Economics, February.
Degennaro, R., and R. Shrieves. 1997. Public information releases, private information
arrival, and volatility in the foreign exchange market. Journal of Empirical Finance 4:
295315.
References
309
De Jong, F., R. Mahieu, P. Schotman, and I. van Leeuwen. 1999. Price discovery on
foreign exchange markets with differentially informed traders. CEPR Discussion Paper
No. 2296, November.
De Jong, F., T. Nijman, and A. Roell. 1996. Price effects of trading and components of
the bid-ask spread on the Paris bourse. Journal of Empirical Finance 3: 193213.
Demsetz, H. 1968. The cost of transacting. Quarterly Journal of Economics 82: 3353.
Deutschebank. 2001. Flowmetrics Monthly (various issues). London: Deutschebank AG
London (email: [email protected]).
Devereux, M., and C. Engel. 1999. The optimal choice of exchange-rate regime: Pricesetting rules and internationalized production. NBER Working Paper 6992.
Diamond, D., and R. Verrecchia. 1981. Information Aggregation in a Noisy Rational
Expectations Economy. Journal of Financial Economics 9: 221235.
Dominguez, K. 1986. Are foreign exchange forecasts rational? New evidence from
survey data. Economic Letters 21: 277281.
Dominguez, K. 1990. Market responses to coordinated central bank intervention.
Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, vol. 32.
Dominguez, K. 1999. The market microstructure of central bank intervention. NBER
Working Paper 7337, September.
Dominguez, K., and J. Frankel. 1993a. Does foreign exchange intervention matter? The
portfolio effect. American Economic Review 83: 13561369.
Dominguez, K., and J. Frankel. 1993b. Does Foreign-exchange Intervention Work? Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Domowitz, I. 1990. The mechanics of automated trade execution. Journal of Financial
Intermediation 1: 167194.
Dooley, M., and P. Isard. 1982. A portfolio-balance rational-expectations model of the
dollar-mark rate. Journal of International Economics 12: 257276.
Dornbusch, R. 1976. Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political
Economy 84: 11611176.
Duarte, M., and A. Stockman. 2001. Rational speculation and exchange rates. Typescript, University of Rochester, March.
Dumas, B. 1996. Comment on Jorion. In The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets,
edited by J. Frankel et al. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Easley, D., S. Hvidkjaer, and M. O'Hara. 1999. Is information risk a determinant of
asset returns? Typescript, Cornell University, November.
Easley, D., and M. O'Hara. 1987. Price, trade size, and information in securities markets. Journal of Financial Economics 19: 6990.
Easley, D., and M. O'Hara. 1992. Time and the process of security price adjustment.
Journal of Finance 47: 577606.
Easley, D., N. Kiefer, M. O'Hara, and J. Paperman. 1996. Liquidity, information, and
infrequently traded stocks. Journal of Finance 51: 14051436.
310
References
Edison, H. 1993. The effectiveness of central-bank intervention: A survey of the literature after 1982. Special Papers in International Economics, no. 18, Princeton University.
Eichenbaum, M., and C. Evans. 1995. Some empirical evidence on the effects of shocks
to monetary policy on exchange rates. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 9751009.
Engel, C. 1996. The forward discount anomaly and the risk premium: A survey of
recent evidence. Journal of Empirical Finance 3: 123192.
Engle, R., and C. Granger. 1987. Cointegration and error correction: Representation,
estimation and testing. Econometrica 55: 251276.
Engle, R., and J. Russell. 1998. Autoregressive conditional duration: A new model for
irregularly spaced transaction data. Econometrica 66: 11271162.
Euromoney. 2000. A true exchange for forex. July.
Evans, G. 1986. A test for speculative bubbles in the sterling-dollar exchange rate.
American Economic Review 76: 621636.
Evans, M. 1997. The microstructure of foreign exchange dynamics. Typescript, Georgetown University, November.
Evans, M. 2001. FX Trading and Exchange Rate Dynamics. NBER Working Paper 8116,
February.
Evans, M., and R. Lyons. 1999. Order ow and exchange rate dynamics. Typescript,
U.C. Berkeley (available at www.haas.berkeley.edu/@lyons). Forthcoming in Journal of
Political Economy.
Evans, M., and R. Lyons. 2000. The price impact of currency trades: Implications for
Secret Intervention. Typescript, U.C. Berkeley, June, presented at the NBER Summer
Institute, July.
Evans, M., and R. Lyons. 2001. Why order ow explains exchange rates. Typescript,
U.C. Berkeley, March.
Fan, M., and R. Lyons. 2000. Customer-dealer trading in the foreign exchange market.
Typescript, U.C. Berkeley, July.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. 1998. Foreign exchange and interest rate derivatives markets survey: Turnover in the United States (available at www.ny.frb.org).
Fieleke, N. 1981. Foreign-currency positioning by U.S. rms: Some new evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics 63: 3543.
Financial Times. 1998. Survey: Foreign exchange, June 5.
Fischer, J., and M. Zurlinden. 1999. Exchange rate effects of central bank interventions:
An analysis of transaction prices. Economic Journal 109: 662676.
Fleming, M., and E. Remolona. 1999. Price formation and liquidity in the U.S. treasury
market: The response to public information. Journal of Finance 54: 19011916.
Flood, M. 1991. Microstructure theory and the foreign exchange market. Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 73 (November/December): 5270.
Flood, M. 1994. Market structure and inefciency in the foreign exchange market.
Journal of International Money and Finance 13: 131158.
References
311
Flood, M., R. Huisman, K. Koedijk, and R. Mahieu. 1999. Quote disclosure and price
discovery in multiple-dealer nancial markets. Review of Financial Studies 12: 3760.
Flood, R., and R. Hodrick. 1990. On testing for speculative bubbles. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 4: 85101.
Flood, R., and A. Rose. 1995. Fixing exchange rates: A virtual quest for fundamentals.
Journal of Monetary Economics 36: 337.
Flood, R., and A. Rose. 1996. Fixes: Of the forward discount puzzle. Review of Economics and Statistics 78: 748752.
Flood, R., and M. Taylor. 1996. Exchange rate economics: What's wrong with the conventional macro approach? In The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, edited by
J. Frankel, G. Galli, and A. Giovannini. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Foster, D., and S. Viswanathan. 1990. A theory of interday variations in volumes, variances, and trading costs in securities markets. Review of Financial Studies 3: 593624.
Foster, D., and S. Viswanathan. 1993. Variations in trading volume, return volatility,
and trading costs: Evidence on recent price formation models. Journal of Finance 48:
187211.
Frankel, J. 1982. A test of perfect substitutability in the foreign exchange market.
Southern Economic Journal 46: 406416.
Frankel, J. 1996. How well do markets work: Might a Tobin tax help? In The Tobin Tax:
Coping with Financial Volatility, edited by M. ul Haq et al. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Frankel, J., and C. Engel. 1984. Do asset demand functions optimize over the mean and
variance of real returns? A six-currency test. Journal of International Economics 17: 309
323.
Frankel, J., and K. Froot. 1987. Using survey data to test standard propositions regarding exchange rate expectations. American Economic Review 77: 133153.
Frankel, J., and K. Froot. 1990. Chartists, fundamentalists, and trading in the foreign
exchange market. American Economic Review 80: 181185.
Frankel, J., G. Galli, and A. Giovannini, eds. 1996. The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Frankel, J., G. Galli, and A. Giovannini. 1996. Introduction. In The Microstructure of
Foreign Exchange Markets, edited by J. Frankel, G. Galli, and A. Giovannini. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Frankel, J., and A. Rose. 1995. Empirical research on nominal exchange rates. In
Handbook of International Economics, edited by G. Grossman and K. Rogoff. Amsterdam:
Elsevier Science.
French, K., and R. Roll. 1986. Stock return variance: The arrival of information and the
reaction of traders. Journal of Financial Economics 17: 99117.
Frenkel, J. 1976. A monetary approach to the exchange rate: Doctrinal aspects and
empirical evidence. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 78: 200224.
Froot, K., and E. Dabora. 1999. How are stock prices affected by the location of trade?
Journal of Financial Economics 53: 189216.
312
References
Froot, K., and K. Rogoff. 1995. Perspectives on PPP and long-run real exchange rates.
In Handbook of International Economics, edited by G. Grossman and K. Rogoff. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Froot, K., and R. Thaler. 1990. Anomalies: Foreign exchange. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4: 179192.
Galati, G. 2000. Trading volumes, volatility, and spreads in FX markets: Evidence from
emerging market countries. Typescript, Bank for International Settlements, July.
Garman, M. 1976. Market microstructure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 257275.
Gehrig, T., and L. Menkhoff. 2000. The use of ow analysis in foreign exchange: Exploratory evidence. Typescript, University of Freiburg, Germany, August.
Gennotte, G., and H. Leland. 1990. Market liquidity, hedges, and crashes. American
Economic Review 80: 9991021.
Gersbach, H., and K. Vogler. 1998. Learning from informed and uninformed traders
and the role of interdealer trading. Typescript, University of Heidelberg, March.
Glassman, D. 1987. Exchange rate risk and transactions costs: Evidence from bid-ask
spreads. Journal of International Money and Finance 6: 479490.
Glosten, L. 1989. Insider trading, liquidity, and the role of the monopolist specialist.
Journal of Business 62: 211236.
Glosten, L. 1994. Is the electronic open limit order book inevitable? Journal of Finance
49: 11271162.
Glosten, L., and L. Harris. 1988. Estimating the components of the bid-ask spread.
Journal of Financial Economics 21: 123142.
Glosten, L., and P. Milgrom. 1985. Bid, ask, and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed agents. Journal of Financial Economics 14: 71100.
Goldberg, L. 1993. Foreign exchange markets in Russia: Understanding the reforms.
International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 40: 852864.
Goldberg, L., and R. Tenorio. 1997. Strategic trading in a two-sided foreign exchange
auction. Journal of International Economics 42: 299326.
Goldstein, M., and K. Kavajecz. 2000. Liquidity provision during circuit breakers and
extreme market movements. Typescript, Babson College, November.
Goodhart, C. 1988. The foreign exchange market: A random walk with a dragging
anchor. Economica 55: 437460.
Goodhart, C., and L. Figliuoli. 1991. Every minute counts in nancial markets. Journal
of International Money and Finance 10: 2352.
Goodhart, C., and T. Hesse. 1993. Central bank forex intervention assessed in continuous time. Journal of International Money and Finance 12: 368389.
Goodhart, C., and M. O'Hara. 1997. High frequency data in nancial markets: Issues
and applications. Journal of Empirical Finance 4: 73114.
Goodhart, C., and R. Payne. 1996. Micro structural dynamics in a foreign exchange
electronic broking system. Journal of International Money and Finance 15: 829852.
References
313
Goodhart, C., and R. Payne. 1999. The foreign exchange market: A multimedia representation, compact disk, distributed by Enterprise LSE Ltd. (www.enterprise-lse.
co.uk).
Goodhart, C., and R. Payne, eds. 2000. The Foreign Exchange Market: Empirical Studies
with High-Frequency Data. New York: St. Martin's Press.
Goodhart, C., and M. Taylor. 1992. Why don't individuals speculate in the forward
foreign exchange market? Scottish Journal of Political Economy 39: 113.
Goodhart, C., T. Ito, and R. Payne. 1996. One day in June 1993: A study of the working
of the Reuters 2000-2 electronic foreign exchange trading system. In The Microstructure
of Foreign Exchange Markets, edited by J. Frankel, G. Galli, and A. Giovannini. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press.
Gordon, R., and L. Bovenberg. 1996. Why is capital so immobile internationally? Possible explanations and implications for capital income taxation. American Economic Review 86: 10571075.
Grammatikos, T., and A. Saunders. 1986. Futures price variability: A test of maturity
and volume effects. Journal of Business 59: 319330.
Grossman, S. 1977. The existence of futures markets, noisy rational expectations and
informational externalities. Review of Economic Studies 44: 431449.
Grossman, S. 1988. An analysis of the implications for stock and futures price volatility
of program trading and dynamic hedging strategies. Journal of Business 61: 275298.
Grossman, S., and M. Miller. 1988. Liquidity and market structure. Journal of Finance
43: 617633.
Grossman. S., and J. Stiglitz. 1980. On the impossibility of informationally efcient
markets. American Economic Review 70: 393408.
Grossman, S., and L. Weiss. 1983. A transactions-based model of the monetary transmission mechanism. American Economic Review 73: 871880.
Grundy, B., and M. McNichols. 1989. Trade and the revelation of information through
prices and direct disclosure. Review of Financial Studies 2: 495526.
Guillaume, D., M. Dacorogna, R. Dave, U. Muller, R. Olsen, and O. Pictet. 1995. From
the bird's eye to the microscope: A survey of new stylized facts of the intradaily foreign exchange markets. Finance and Stochastics 1: 95129.
Habermeier, K., and A. Kirilenko. 2000. Securities transaction taxes and nancial
markets. Typescript, International Monetary Fund, June.
Hamao, Y., and J. Hasbrouck. 1995. Securities trading in the absence of dealers: Trades
and quotes on the Tokyo stock exchange. Review of Financial Studies 8: 849878.
Hamilton, J. 1994. Time Series Analysis. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Handa, P., and R. Schwartz. 1996. Limit order trading. Journal of Finance 51: 1835
1861.
Hansch, O., N. Naik, and S. Viswanathan. 1998. Do inventories matter in dealership
markets? Evidence from the London Stock Exchange. Journal of Finance 53: 1623
1656.
314
References
Hansch, O., N. Naik, and S. Viswanathan. 1999. Preferencing, internalization, best execution, and dealer prots. Journal of Finance 54: 17991828.
Harris, L. 1986. A transaction data study of weekly and intradaily patterns in stock
returns. Journal of Financial Economics 16: 99117.
Harris, L., and J. Hasbrouck. 1996. Market versus limit orders: The SuperDOT evidence on order submission strategy. Journal of Financial & Quantitative Analysis 31:
213231.
Harris, M., and A. Raviv. 1993. Differences of opinion make a horse race. Review of
Financial Studies 6: 473506.
Hartmann, P. 1998a. Currency Competition and Foreign Exchange Markets: The dollar, the
Yen, and the Euro. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hartmann, P. 1998b. Do Reuters spreads reect currencies' differences in global trading activity? Journal of International Money and Finance 17: 757784.
Hartmann, P. 1999. Trading volumes and transaction costs in the foreign exchange
market: Evidence from daily dollar-yen spot data. Journal of Banking and Finance 23:
801824.
Hasbrouck, J. 1988. Trades, quotes, inventories, and information. Journal of Financial
Economics 22: 229252.
Hasbrouck, J. 1991a. Measuring the information content of stock trades. Journal of
Finance 46: 179207.
Hasbrouck, J. 1991b. The summary informativeness of stock trades: An econometric
analysis. Review of Financial Studies 4: 571595.
Hasbrouck, J. 1992. Using the TORQ database. Typescript, New York University
(available at jhasbrouck.stern.nyu.edu/main).
Hasbrouck, J. 1997. One security, many markets. Typescript, New York Univeristy.
Hasbrouck, J., and G. Soanos. 1993. The trades of market makers: An empirical
analysis of NYSE specialists. Journal of Finance 48: 15651593.
Hau, H. 1998. Competitive entry and endogenous risk in the foreign exchange market.
Review of Financial Studies 11: 757788.
Hau, H. 2000. Information and geography: Evidence from the German stock market.
Typescript, Insead, March.
Hau, H., and A. Chevallier. 2000. Evidence on the volatility effect of a Tobin tax.
Typescript, Insead, April.
Hau, H., W. Killeen, and M. Moore. 2000. The euro as an international currency:
Explaining the rst evidence. Typescript, Insead, April.
Hausman, J., A. Lo, and C. MacKinlay. 1992. An ordered probit analysis of transaction
stock prices. Journal of Financial Economics 31: 319379.
Hayek, F. 1945. The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review 35: 519
530.
References
315
He, H., and D. Modest. 1995. Market frictions and consumption-based asset pricing.
Journal of Political Economy 103: 94117.
Heere, E. 1999. Microstructure theory applied to the foreign exchange market. Ph.D.
dissertation, Maastricht University, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration.
Hellwig, M. 1980. On the aggregation of information in competitive markets. Journal of
Economic Theory 22: 447498.
Hellwig, M. 1982. Rational expectations equilibrium with conditioning on past prices:
A mean variance example. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 279312.
Hicks, J. 1939. Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Ho, T., and H. Stoll. 1983. The dynamics of dealer markets under competition. Journal
of Finance 38: 10531074.
Hodrick, R. 1987. The Empirical Evidence on the Efciency of Forward and Futures Foreign
Exchange Markets. New York: Harwood Academic Publishers.
Holden, C., and A. Subrahmanyam. 1992. Long-lived private information and imperfect competition. Journal of Finance 47: 247270.
Hong, H., and J. Wang. 1995. Trading and Returns Under Periodic Market Closures.
Working paper, MIT, July.
Houthakker, H. 1957. Can speculators forecast prices? Review of Economic Studies 39:
143151.
Hsieh, D. 1988. The statistical properties of daily foreign exchange rates: 19741983.
Journal of International Economics 24: 129145.
Hsieh, D., and A. Kleidon. 1996. Bid-ask spreads in foreign exchange markets: Implications for models of asymmetric information. In The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange
Markets, edited by J. Frankel et al. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Huang, R., and R. Masulis. 1999. FX spreads and dealer competition across the 24 hour
trading day. Review of Financial Studies 12: 6194.
Huang, R., and H. Stoll. 1997. The components of the bid-ask spread: A general
approach. Review of Financial Studies 10: 9951034.
Huisman, R., K. Koedijk, C. Kool, and F. Nissen. 1998. Extreme support for uncovered
interest parity. Journal of International Money and Finance 17: 211228.
Hung, J. 1997. Intervention strategies and exchange rate volatility: A noise trading
perspective. Journal of International Money and Finance 16: 779793.
Institutional Investor. 2000. Trading meets the millennium. January.
International Monetary Fund. 1995. International capital markets: Developments, prospects, and policy issues, edited by D. Folkerts-Landau and T. Ito. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund.
Isard, P. 1995. Exchange Rate Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ito, T., R. Lyons, and M. Melvin. 1998. Is there private information in the FX market?
The Tokyo experiment. Journal of Finance 53: 11111130.
316
References
Ito, T., and V. Roley. 1990. Intraday yen/dollar exchange rate movements: News or
noise? Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 1: 131.
Jacklin, C., A. Kleidon, and P. Peiderer. 1992. Underestimation of portfolio insurance
and the crash of October 1987. Review of Financial Studies 5: 3563.
Jeanne, O., and A. Rose. 1999. Noise trading and exchange rate regimes, NBER Working Paper a7104, April. Forthcoming in the Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Johansen, S. 1992. Cointegration in partial systems and the efciency of single equation
analysis. Journal of Econometrics 52: 389402.
Jones, C., G. Kaul, and M. Lipson. 1994. Transactions, volume, and volatility. Review of
Financial Studies 7: 631651.
Jordan, J., and R. Radner. 1982. Rational expectations in microeconomic models: An
overview. Journal of Economic Theory 26: 201223.
Jorion, P. 1996. Risk and turnover in the foreign exchange market. In The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, edited by J. Frankel et al. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Kaminsky, G., and K. Lewis. 1996. Does foreign exchange intervention signal future
monetary policy? Journal of Monetary Economics 37: 285312.
Kandel, E., and N. Pearson. 1995. Differential interpretation of public signals and trade
in speculative markets. Journal of Political Economy 103: 831872.
Kang, J., and R. Stulz. 1997. Why is there a home bias? An analysis of foreign portfolio
equity ownership in Japan. Journal of Financial Economics 46: 328.
Karpoff, J. 1986. A theory of trading volume. Journal of Finance 41: 10691087.
Karpoff, J. 1987. The relation between price changes and volume: A survey. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22: 109126.
Kaul, A., V. Mehrotra, and R. Morck. 2000. Demand curves for stock do slope down:
New evidence from an index weights adjustment. Journal of Finance 55: 893912.
Keynes, J. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York:
Harcourt Brace (see especially chapter 12).
Killeen, W., R. Lyons, and M. Moore. 2000a. Fixed versus oating exchange rates:
Lessons from order ow. Typescript, U.C. Berkeley, July.
Killeen, W., R. Lyons, and M. Moore. 2000b. The puzzle of the euro. Typescript, U.C.
Berkeley, July.
Kim, O., and R. Verrecchia. 1991. Trading volume and price reactions to public
announcements. Journal of Accounting Research 29: 302321.
Kirilenko, A. 1997. Endogenous trading arrangements in emerging foreign exchange
markets. Working paper, University of Pennsylvania (Wharton).
Klein, M. 1993. The accuracy of reports of foreign exchange intervention. Journal of International Money and Finance 12: 644653.
Kouri, P., and M. Porter. 1974. International capital ows and portfolio equilibrium.
Journal of Political Economy 82: 443467.
References
317
Krugman, P., and M. Miller. 1993. Why have a target zone? Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 38: 279314.
Krugman, P., and M. Obstfeld. 2000. International Economics, 5th ed. Reading, Mass.:
Addison-Wesley.
Kurz, M. 1997. Foreign exchange rates under alternative expectational paradigms: A
resolution of the excess volatility puzzle. Working paper, Stanford University.
Kyle, A. 1985. Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica 53: 13151335.
Kyle, A. 1989. Informed speculation with imperfect competition. Review of Economic
Studies 56: 317356.
Leach, J., and A. Madhavan. 1993. Price experimentation and security market structure. Review of Financial Studies 6: 375404.
Lee, C., and M. Ready. 1991. Inferring trade direction from intradaily data. Journal of
Finance 46: 733746.
Lehman Brothers. 2000. Global Economic Research Series: FX Impact of Cross-Border MA.
London: Lehman Brothers International (20 April).
Leland, H. 1992. Insider trading: Should it be prohibited? Journal of Political Economy
100: 859887.
Levich, R. 2001. International Financial Markets: Prices and Policies, 2nd ed. New
York: McGraw-Hill Irwin.
Lewis, K. 1988. Testing the portfolio balance model: A multilateral approach. Journal of
International Economics 24: 109127.
Lewis, K. 1995. Puzzles in international nancial markets. In Handbook of International
Economics, edited by G. Grossman and K. Rogoff. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Loopesko, B. 1984. Relationships among exchange rates, intervention, and interest
rates: An empirical investigation. Journal of International Money and Finance 3: 257
277.
Luca, C. 2000. Trading in the Global Currency Markets, 2nd ed. New York: Prentice
Hall.
Lui, Y., and D. Mole. 1998. The use of fundamental and technical analyses by foreign
exchange dealers: Hong Kong evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance 17:
535545.
Lyons, R. 1995. Tests of microstructural hypotheses in the foreign exchange market.
Journal of Financial Economics 39: 321351.
Lyons, R. 1996a. Optimal transparency in a dealer market with an application to foreign exchange. Journal of Financial Intermediation 5: 225254.
Lyons, R. 1996b. Foreign exchange volume: Sound and fury signifying nothing? In The
Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, edited by J. Frankel et al. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Lyons, R. 1997a. A simultaneous trade model of the foreign exchange hot potato.
Journal of International Economics 42: 275298.
318
References
Lyons, R. 1998. Prots and position control: A week of FX dealing. Journal of International Money and Finance 17: 97115.
Lyons, R., and A. Rose. 1995. Explaining forward exchange bias . . . intraday. Journal of
Finance 50: 13211329.
Machlup, F. 1939. The theory of foreign exchanges. Economica. Reprinted in Readings
in the Theory of International Trade, edited by H. Ellis and L. Metzler. Philadelphia:
Blakiston, 1949.
Madhavan, A. 1992. Trading mechanisms in securities markets. Journal of Finance 47:
607642.
Madhavan, A. 1996. Security prices and market transparency. Journal of Financial
Intermediation 5: 255283.
Madhavan, A. 2000. Market microstructure: A survey. Journal of Financial Markets 3:
205258.
Madhavan, A., and S. Smidt. 1991. A bayesian model of intraday specialist pricing.
Journal of Financial Economics 30: 99134.
Madhavan, A., and S. Smidt. 1993. An analysis of changes in specialist inventories and
quotations. Journal of Finance 48: 15951628.
Madrigal, V. 1996. Non-fundamental speculation. Journal of Finance 51: 553578.
MAR/Hedge. 2000. Monthly issues, Managed Account Reports, Inc., New York
(available at www.marhedge.com).
Mark, N. 1995. Exchange rates and fundamentals: Evidence on long-horizon predictability. American Economic Review 85: 201218.
Meese, R. 1986. Testing for bubbles in exchange markets. Journal of Political Economy 94:
345373.
Meese, R. 1990. Currency uctuations in the postBretton Woods era. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4: 117134.
Meese, R., and K. Rogoff. 1983a. Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies.
Journal of International Economics 14: 324.
Meese, R., and K. Rogoff. 1983b. The out-of-sample failure of empirical exchange
rate models. In Exchange Rate and International Macroeconomics, edited by J. Frenkel.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Mehra, R., and E. Prescott. 1985. The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of Monetary
Economics 15: 145161.
Melvin, M., and B. Peiers. 1997. The global transmission of volatility in the foreign
exchange market. Working paper, Arizona State University.
Melvin, M., and X. Yin. 2000. Public information arrival, exchange rate volatility, and
quote frequency. Economic Journal 110: 644651.
Mendelson, H. 1987. Consolidation, fragmentation, and market performance. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis 22: 189208.
References
319
320
References
Osler, C. 2001. Currency orders and exchange-rate dynamics: Explaining the success of
technical analysis. Typescript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, March.
Pagano, M. 1989. Trading volume and asset liquidity. Quarterly Journal of Economics
104: 255274.
Pagano, M., and A. Roell. 1996. Transparency and liquidity: A comparison of auction
and dealer markets. Journal of Finance 51: 579612.
Payne, R. 1999. Informed trade in spot foreign exchange markets: An empirical investigation. Typescript, London School of Economics, January.
Payne, R., and P. Vitale. 2000. A transaction level study of the effects of central bank
intervention on exchange rates. Typescript, London School of Economics, July.
Peiers, B. 1997. Informed traders, intervention, and price leadership: A deeper view of
the microstructure of the foreign exchange market. Journal of Finance 52: 15891614.
Perold, A., and E. Schulman. 1988. The free lunch in currency hedging: Implications
for investment policy and performance standards. Financial Analysts Journal MayJune,
4550.
Perraudin, W., and P. Vitale. 1996. Interdealer trade and information ows in a
decentralized foreign exchange market. In The Microstructure of Foreign Exchange Markets, edited by J. Frankel et al. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Portes, R., and H. Rey. 1998. The emergence of the euro as an international currency.
Economic Policy 26: 307343.
Reiss, P., and I. Werner. 1995. Transaction costs in dealer markets: Evidence from the
London Stock Exchange. In Industrial Organization and Regulation of the Securities Industry, edited by A. Lo. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Reiss, P., and I. Werner. 1997. Interdealer trading: Evidence from London. Stanford
Business School Research Paper No. 1430, February.
Reiss, P., and I. Werner. 1998. Does risk sharing motivate interdealer trading? Journal of
Finance 53: 16571704.
Reiss, P., and I. Werner. 1999. Adverse selection in dealers' choice of interdealer trading system. Dice Working Paper no. 99-7, Ohio State University, June.
Rey, H. 2001. International trade and currency exchange. Review of Economic Studies 68:
443464.
Rime, D. 2000. Private or public information in foreign exchange markets? An empirical analysis. Typescript, University of Oslo, March (available at www.uio.no/
@dagnri).
Robinson, J. 1937. The foreign exchanges. Reprinted in Readings in the Theory of International Trade, edited by H. Ellis and L. Metzler. Philadelphia: Blakiston, 1949.
Rochet, J., and J. Vila. 1995. Insider trading without normality. Review of Economic
Studies 61: 131152.
Rogoff, K. 1984. On the effects of sterilized intervention: An analysis of weekly data.
Journal of Monetary Economics 14: 133150.
Roll, R. 1988. R 2 . Journal of Finance 43: 541566.
References
321
322
References
References
323
Weston, J. 2000. Competition on the Nasdaq and the impact of recent market reforms,
Journal of Finance 55: 25652598.
Wolinsky, A. 1990. Information revelation in a market with pairwise meetings. Econometrica 58: 123.
Working, H. 1953. Futures trading and hedging. American Economic Review 43: 314
343.
Yao, J. 1998a. Market making in the interbank foreign exchange market. New York
University Salomon Center Working Paper aS-98-3.
Yao, J. 1998b. Spread components and dealer prots in the interbank foreign exchange
market. New York University Salomon Center Working Paper aS-98-4.
Zaheer, A., and Zaheer, S. 1995. Catching the wave: Alertness, responsiveness, and
market inuence in global electronic networks. Typescript, University of Minnesota,
December.
Zhou, B. 1996. High frequency data and volatility in foreign exchange rates. Journal of
Business and Economic Statistics 14: 4552.
Index
326
Data sets, foreign exchange market (FX)
(cont.)
and information sets, 125126
integration, 125, 270271, 290n8
Killeen, Lyons, and Moore, 123124,
192198, 200202
Lyons, 117118
Yao, 118121
Dealer markets, 6365
multiple, 4041, 93105, 289n27
single, 40, 8693
Dealer-problem structural model, 134
139
formation of expectations in the, 137
138
quote determination, 138
Dealers, foreign exchange market, 68,
40, 4551, 93
and brokered interdealer transactions,
123124
and customer-dealer trades, 124125
and the daily frequency model, 176190
data integration among, 270271
and direct interdealer transactions, 93
94, 9899, 117123
inventories, 46, 141, 267
and marketmakers, 283n6
prots, 4951, 285n20, 288n23
position sheets, 4749
structural microstructure models, 134
139
and types of markets, 6366
vote counters, 7778
Demand and order ow, 7, 73, 188, 198
199
Derivatives, 3839, 52, 246, 283n4,
285n22
Determination puzzle, exchange rates,
172173
and asset payoff, 176180
and causality, 189190
daily frequency model, 176180
and dealers, 176190
and equity markets, 294n2
and the Evans-Lyons model, 176190
hybrid micro-macro models, 173176
and order ow, 187189
and the portfolio balance model, 180
184
and price, 180187
and robustness checks, 187188
Direct interdealer trading, 115123
and the Dealing 2000-1 system, 117123
Index
Evans data set on, 121123
Lyons data set on, 117118
Yao data set on, 118121
Discount-rate information, 3031
and imperfect substitutability, 3334
transitory inventory effects on, 3233
Distressed selling, 257, 269
Efciency
semi-strong form, 3, 128, 303n11
strong form, 87, 271
Electronic Broking System (EBS), 116
117, 123124, 201202, 276277, 290n3,
300n5
Electronic trading, 55, 113114, 290n5
Emerging markets, 274, 281n2, 290n2
Equilibrium
model of exchange rate determination,
164166
Killeen, Lyons, and Moore model, 198
Kyle auction model, 8081, 8284
rational expectations auction model, 66
67, 7071
simultaneous-trade model, 100102
Error correction, 204205
European Monetary Union (EMU), 53,
193
Evans data set, 121123, 176190
Evans-Lyons model
and asset payoff, 176179
and causality, 189190
and customer ow, 248249, 252253
and the ow approach to exchange
rates, 190192
and interdealer trading, 179180
and intervention trades, 236241
and order ow, 187189
and portfolio balancing, 181184, 222
and price, 180184
results, 184187
robustness checks, 187188
simultaneous-trade model links, 183
184
Event uncertainty, 145, 237238, 295n18
Excess volatility puzzle, the, 192206
Exchange rate economics
asset market approach to, 3, 15, 153155
and the collapse of the Yen/$ rate, 256
261
and the determination puzzle, 172190,
294n3
and the excess volatility puzzle, 192
206
Index
and expectations, 14, 173176
and xed versus oating rates, 192206,
229231, 296n23
exible-price monetary model, 155157
and oating rate volatility, 265266
ow approach to, 190192
and the forward bias puzzle, 206220
fundamentals, 28, 151155, 157, 301n14
general equilibrium model, 164166,
294n3, 298n44, 303n5
goods market approach to, 2, 152153
hybrid micro-macro models of, 1618,
173176
and information dispersion, 1213
and the issues spectrum, 167, 169
and macroeconomic models, 12, 294n1
and microfoundations, 151152, 164
167, 303n5
microstructure approach to, 45, 1011,
1314, 1518
and micro versus macro issues, 167
170
models, 155163
and order ow, 68, 910, 139142,
198199
overshooting model, 155157
portfolio balance model, 160163
and purchasing power parity, 152153,
155157
and spread, 89
sticky-price monetary model, 157160
and trading volume, 3, 1314, 5155
and uncovered interest parity, 153
155
and utility maximization, 164166
and the wealth constraint, 161162
Expectations
and exchange rate determination, 14,
173176, 282n12, 295n4, 300n12
and the rational expectations auction
model, 7173
tools for calculating, 72, 83, 108, 111
112, 137138
Fixed exchange rates, 12, 192206, 229
231, 273274
Flexible-price monetary model, 155157
Flow approach to exchange rates, 190
192, 279n1
Foreign exchange markets (FX), 25. See
also Spot market, the
asset market view of, 153155
and book passing, 284n14
327
brokered interdealer trades, 114117,
123124
brokers, 4245
central bank intervention, 223225, 227
229
choke point, 222
and the collapse of the Yen/$ rate, 256
261
compared to other markets, 41
credit risk and market structure, 272,
296n27
customer-dealer trades, 114117
customers, 42, 243261
daily volume, 3839
dealers, 68, 2326, 4041, 4551
derivatives, 3839, 52, 246, 283n4,
285n22
description of, 3738
direct interdealer trades, 117123
directions for research, 268272
Evans data set, 121123
and expectations, 14
exible-price monetary model, 155157
future of, 275277
Goodhart and Payne data set, 123
goods market view of, 152153
and hot potato trading, 144149, 267
268
and international currencies, 274275
and inventory control, 143144
Killeen, Lyons, and Moore data set, 123
124
large dealer positions, 4651
Lyons data set, 117118
market design, 274
microstructure effects, 5962, 302n1
modeling strategies, 4551
order ow, 3132, 139142
overshooting model, 157160
players, 4145
policy implications in, 272275, 286n28
portfolio balance model, 160163, 222
and price, 142149
protability, dealer, 4951, 285n20,
288n23
and public information, 2122, 25,
281n1
and purchasing power parity, 152153,
155157
research data sets, 113117
and the simultaneous-trade model, 93
105
and spreads, 4344, 5051
328
Index
Index
329
330
Index
dened, 67
and demand, 7, 73, 188, 198199
and distressed selling, 257, 269
and the Evans-Lyons model, 187189
and the excess volatility puzzle, 194
195
exogeneity of, 204205, 269
and expected future payoffs, 3435
expected versus unexpected, 188
and oating rate volatility, 265266
and foreign exchange dealers, 2526,
3132, 139142
and FX swaps, 3839, 5152, 246
and forward rate bias, 219
graphical interpretation of, 3235
and hot potato trading, 146149
hybrid micro-macro models of, 1618,
173176
and imperfect substitutability, 3334
information role for, 2022
and information structure, 253256, 265
and institution types, 253256
and the Killeen, Lyons, and Moore
model, 200202
and the Kyle auction model, 78
and limit orders, 67, 290nn6, 11,
304n11
measuring, 127, 284n12
and microstructure approach to
exchange rates, 1518, 6062, 173176,
267
and monetary models, 167, 295n4
and price, 1112, 2223, 2930, 198200,
264266, 273, 291nn13, 14
price impact measured, 141, 147, 186
187, 236, 239240, 254255, 265, 270,
273, 301n21
and random walk, 184
and the rational expectations auction
model, 76
and reverse causality, 269
and spot market dealers, 4546
and spreads, 2324
and structural models, 139142
and supply and demand, 3132
and survey data, 2526
time-aggregated, 23
and trading volume, 67
and transitory inventory effects on
discount rates, 3233
transparency of, 4546, 5557, 275276,
289n31
Index
331
332
Index
Index
333