Zaman Islamiceconomics

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 103

Religions and Development

Research Programme
Islamic Economics:
A Survey of the Literature

Asad Zaman
International Institute of Islamic Economics
International Islamic University, Islamabad, Pakistan

Working Paper 22 - 2008

Religions and Development


Research Programme
The Religions and Development Research Programme Consortium is an international research
partnership that is exploring the relationships between several major world religions, development in
low-income countries and poverty reduction. The programme is comprised of a series of comparative
research projects that are addressing the following questions:
z

How do religious values and beliefs drive the actions and interactions of individuals and faith-based
organisations?

How do religious values and beliefs and religious organisations influence the relationships between
states and societies?

In what ways do faith communities interact with development actors and what are the outcomes with
respect to the achievement of development goals?

The research aims to provide knowledge and tools to enable dialogue between development partners
and contribute to the achievement of development goals. We believe that our role as researchers is
not to make judgements about the truth or desirability of particular values or beliefs, nor is it to urge a
greater or lesser role for religion in achieving development objectives. Instead, our aim is to produce
systematic and reliable knowledge and better understanding of the social world.
The research focuses on four countries (India, Pakistan, Nigeria and Tanzania), enabling the research
team to study most of the major world religions: Christianity, Islam, Hinduism, Sikhism, Buddhism and
African traditional belief systems. The research projects will compare two or more of the focus
countries, regions within the countries, different religious traditions and selected development activities
and policies.
The consortium consists of six research partner organisations, each of which is working with other
researchers in the four focus countries:
z

University of Birmingham, UK: International Development Department, Department of Theology and


Religion, Centre for West African Studies, Centre for the Study of Global Ethics.

University of Bath, UK: Centre for Development Studies.

Indian Institute of Dalit Studies, New Delhi.

Nigerian Institute of Social and Economic Research, Ibadan.

University of Dar es Salaam, Tanzania.

Lahore University of Management Sciences, Pakistan.

In addition to the research partners, links have been forged with non-academic and non-government
bodies, including Islamic Relief.
http://www.rad.bham.ac.uk

Contact: [email protected]

Religions and Development


Working Paper 22
Islamic Economics:
A Survey of the Literature

Asad Zaman
International Institute of Islamic Economics
Intranational Islamic University, Islamabad, Pakistan

ISBN: 0 7044 2677 3


978 0 7044 2677 1
International Development Department, University of Birmingham

This document is an output from a project funded by the UK


Department for International Development (DFID) for the benefit
of developing countries. The views expressed are not
necessarily those of DFID.

Working Paper 22

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Contents
Acknowledgements
Glossary of Arabic Words

Summary

Preface

1.1 Self-knowledge and knowledge of others

1.2 Contrasting historical experiences with religion

1.3 The transition to secular thought and its consequences

1.4 The emergence of economics in Europe

10

1.5 Outline of the paper

16

The origins of Islamic economics

17

2.1 Historical roots of Islamic economics

17

2.2 Emergence of Islamic economics in the post-colonial era.

20

Fundamentals of an Islamic economic system

27

3.1 The Islamic view of human beings

27

3.2 Wealth and freedom

29

3.3 Contrasting principles of Islamic and neoclassical economics

30

3.4 Detached observation vs. passionate engagement

31

The framework: Shariah or Islamic law

34

4.1 Objectives of the Shariah

34

4.2 Property rights

36

4.3 Islamic rules of business

39

4.4 Labour

43

Islamic states

45

5.1 Political structure

45

5.2 Public finance

48

5.3 Justice

52

5.4 Economic security and welfare

54

5.5 Other functions of an Islamic state

57

The role of Islamic institutions

60

6.1 Islamic financial institutions

60

6.2 Takaful (insurance)

66

6.3 Waqf (endowment/trust)

69

6.4 Hisbah (audit or accountability)

72

6.5 Environmental protection, ecology and natural resources.

74

The role of Muslim individuals

76

Concluding remarks

79

Notes

81

References

85

Working Paper 22

Acknowledgements
I am deeply indebted to Carole Rakodi, Director of the Religions and Development Programme, for
putting up patiently with earlier expositions of this material, which sometimes appeared to fall short of
customary academic standards of courtesy and diplomacy. Her extraordinary forbearance and her
uncanny ability to look through the form and grasp the spirit were invaluable to me in arriving at my
present views, reflected in the current version. I have learned a lot from this effort to communicate
across radically different worldviews. Personally I had considered this to be an impossible task, and
would not have undertaken it at all, had it not been for the encouragement of many of the members of
the Religions and Development Research Programme. I would like to thank all of those who
commented on earlier versions of the paper, especially Abbas Mirakhor, M. N. Siddiqui, Akram Khan,
AbdelRahman Yousri, Uzma Qureshi, Meryem Zaman, Arshad Zaman and an anonymous reviewer.
Many others whom I cannot name individually have commented and contributed to the development of
the paper.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Glossary of Arabic Words


References to the Quran are given in form [Qxx:yy], where xx is the number of the Surah and yy is the
number of the Ayah. These can easily be looked up from many sources, including the website http://
www.islamicity.com/QuranSearch/ . Unless otherwise indicated, Hadeeth that are cited can be
looked up from http://www.muhaddith.org .
The Islamic Calendar is a lunar calendar which starts from the date of emigration (Hijra) of the
Prophet Mohammad (May Allah shower his peace and blessings upon him)1 from Mecca to Medina,
which took place in 622 AD. Since the lunar year is about 11 days shorter than solar, for a very rough
conversion, multiply the Islamic year number by 0.97, and then add 622 to get the Gregorian year
number
Farz: Compulsory, according to Islamic Law. Actions are classified as being farz, or obligatory, and
nafil, or optional acts of worship. Then there is the haram, or prohibited category. Among the nafil acts,
there can be varying grades of compulsion or necessity.
Farz-e-Kifayah: Collective responsibility of a community. If not fulfilled, it becomes farz (compulsory)
for everyone individually. If it has been fulfilled by some members, then others are absolved of the
responsibility.
Fiqh: Rules of derivation (and the methodology for development of such rules) used to apply Islamic
law to situations not directly covered by source materials for Islamic law.
Gharar: uncertainty or ambiguity about price or product, which renders a sale invalid according to
Islamic law.
Hadeeth: A report of a saying or action of the Prophet Mohammad (May the peace and blessings of
Allah be upon him). Such a report must be accompanied by a list of narrators.
Halal: Permissible, according to Islamic law.
Haram: Forbidden, according to Islamic law.
Ijtihad: The process of deriving rulings of Islamic law in new situations not covered by traditional
rulings.
Infaq: Giving money or property for the betterment of society, in order to earn the pleasure of Allah.

Working Paper 22

Jihad: Struggle. Refers to holy war, waged solely for purposes sanctioned by Islam, and without any
mingling of worldly purposes, such as material gain, conquest, or glory. It also refers to spiritual and
moral struggle for self-purification, and this has been referred to as the greater Jihad in Islamic
tradition.
Kharaj: A tax on landholding which may be based on land value or on production.
Khilafat-e-Rashida: The rightly guided Caliphate. Refers to a period of about 30 years following the
death of the Prophet Muhammad (May peace and blessings of Allah be upon him), where the rule of
the Islamic world was in the hands of people trained by the Prophet. These people had both temporal
and spiritual authority, and hence established the Kingdom of God upon earth. After this period
temporal and spiritual authority were separated (as predicted in Hadeeth), and Muslim rulers were no
longer regarded as spiritual authorities by the public.
Riba: Literally, increase, but in Islamic law, any pre-agreed excess against grant of time in sales on
deferred payment, or on loans; or as a premium (e.g. for quality) in the exchange of six commodities
(gold, silver, wheat, barley, dates, and salt) in which unequal exchange is prohibited.
Sharia: Islamic law is the usual translation, but the meaning is broader. Sharia is the set of rules
which govern behaviour of Muslims in all realms of life, from internal states of heart and personal
affairs to social and political and global affairs. These rules may be directly specified in Islamic source
materials, or else deduced from such sources.
Shoora: The process of consultation for decision making by Muslim groups, recommended in the
Quran. This process is subject to Islamic law, as described in many texts.
Sufi/Sufism: Sufism is the inner, mystical, and spiritual dimension of Islam, and a Sufi is the
practitioner of this tradition, which leads to the training of the heart in directions required by Islam.
Ulama (singular Alim): Scholars of Islam.
Ummah: The community or brotherhood of all Muslims. This can also be used to refer to the
community of all human beings,
Ushr: Payments for the poor of 10% from agricultural produce.
Zakah, Zakat: Payments to the poor of 2.5% from wealth.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Summary
A central thesis of this paper is that social science is the study of human experience, and hence is
strongly conditioned by history. Modern Western political, economic and social structures have
emerged as a consequence of the repudiation of religion associated with the Enlightenment and are
based on secular principles. Many of these are inimical to Islamic principles, and cannot be adapted to
an Islamic society. Muslim societies achieved freedom from colonial rule in the first half of the
twentieth century and have sought to construct institutions in conformity with Islam. The development
of Islamic economics is part of this process of transition away from Western colonial institutions. This
paper is a survey of the literature on Islamic economics, which focuses on the contrasts between
Western economic theories and Islamic approaches to the organization of economic affairs.
Neoclassical theory is centred around the acquisitive instinct of humans and makes competition the
driving force of economic analysis. Islamic approaches foster cooperation and encourage generosity
as the fundamental principle for handling economic affairs. Human beings have potential for good and
evil, and are free to choose between the two; their behaviour is not subject to the mathematical laws
postulated by neoclassical economic theory. The main message of Islam is that we must strive to
achieve the potential for good at both the individual and social levels. Behaviour in the economic realm
is also governed by this goal.
Islamic law (Shariah) provides the framework for all activity within an Islamic society. In the economic
domain, Islamic law regulates both methods by which money may be earned and also the ways it may
be spent. Acquisition of wealth is permissible only in ways that are just to all the parties concerned;
exploitation, arbitrary taxation, and individual profit resulting in social harm is not permissible in Islamic
law. This puts numerous restrictions on business practices utilized to make a profit. For example,
polluting the environment or selling products that lead to moral corruption are not permissible in
Islamic law. Wealth that has been acquired becomes private property, which is, according to Islamic
concepts, both a trust and a test. The trust aspect means that property must be used in ways
beneficial to the individual and society. The test aspect means that those who have more than they
need are required to take care of those who are in need. Ways in which acquired wealth can be spent
is also subject to Islamic law. People are expected to strive to be self-sufficient and not ask from
others. Thus striving to acquire wealth and spending it on personal and family needs is encouraged.
Islam does not preach austerity and encourages a comfortable standard of living. At the same time, it

Working Paper 22

strongly discourages spending on idle desires, luxuries, and ostentation. There is also a strong
encouragement to spend what is beyond ones needs on social welfare.
These fundamental principles for acquiring wealth, using property (acquired wealth) and spending it
impact on all realms of economic activity. Since these are substantially different from Western ideas in
all three areas, there are substantial contrasts between Western economic institutions and Islamic
ones. The paper traces out these differences in many realms of economic activity. The primary
objective of an Islamic state is to provide justice, and Islamic public finance is concerned with tracing
the concrete implications of this abstraction in the economic realm. Western financial institution s
have the acquisition and multiplication of wealth as their prime objective. Since acquisition of wealth
can only be a means to an end, these institutions require modification in an Islamic society. Similarly,
Islamic imperatives for social welfare require construction of certain uniquely Islamic types of
institutions that do not have counterparts in the West. The paper discusses these issues in some
detail.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

In the name of our Creator Allah, the Merciful, the Beneficent

1 Preface
1.1 Self-knowledge and knowledge of others
Q2:269 and whoever is granted wisdom has indeed been granted wealth abundant.
The treasure of knowledge gathered by our ancestors, which is the collective heritage of mankind, is
vast. It represents the cumulative effort of generations over centuries. No human can hope to acquire
more than a small fragment of this treasure. No human can subject more than a very small
percentage of this heritage to critical examination. This means that a vast proportion of what I know
and what you know is received knowledge which we have accepted without questioning. The
knowledge that we have is strongly conditioned by the streams of history in which we live, but we are
largely unaware of this. This creates a dilemma: we have no choice but to trust the cumulative body of
received knowledge, yet there is always the possibility of systematic and widespread errors in this
body of knowledge. If nearly everybody around us believes that the earth is flat, or that white races are
superior to others, it is very hard for us to avoid such errors. There are two strategies which are
effective in liberating us from the strands of the history that bind us. One is the study of the history of
thought: studying how an idea emerged and how it was fashioned by the forces of history and viceversa leads to substantial clarity and insight. A second strategy is to study the worldviews of those
who have lived in a different stream of history and therefore come to a different way of understanding
the world. Just as a mirror allows us to see our own face, so an alternative coherent worldview
illuminates and clarifies our own worldview. Seeing ourselves as others see us permits insights
which are not possible from purely internal dialogues and discussions.
Divergent historical events have led to great differences between ways of viewing the world in
European thought and in the Islamic world. These differences lead to misunderstandings and hostility,
which are currently the source of conflicts and misery for large numbers of human beings in the
Islamic world and outside of it. One major goal of this survey is to present Islamic views on how to
arrange economic affairs in a society to a Western audience. I will focus on the contrasts between
Islamic and Western views and show that there are coherent alternatives to prevalent and dominant
Western views on the subject. This is subordinate to the larger goal of creating better understanding
and sympathy across the cultural divide, in the hope that this will improve the conditions of human
beings living on this planet. I also hope that understanding Islamic views, which closely match premodern Western views, will provide deeper insights into some essential but largely forgotten aspects

Working Paper 22

of the Western heritage, as well as a better understanding of the roots of the numerous attempts to
construct alternatives to modernity currently under way in the West.
Some methods and style of discourse utilized below are adapted to these goals, which are different
from those of a typical academic paper. Excessive attention to detail would distract from the goal of
providing a panoramic description of a coherent and integrated alternative worldview. From among a
complex and diverse set of Islamic views, I have often picked one or two for the sake of maintaining
consistency across a broad spectrum of issues to be discussed. I have similarly chosen certain
Enlightenment perspectives to represent Western views, as these views offer the maximum contrast
with the Islamic views. This approach is subject to the well-known weaknesses of the technique of
binary opposition, but it serves my purpose here of sketching a coherent Islamic view on economic
affairs with a minimum of brush strokes. I apologise in advance to both Eastern and Western readers
with heterodox views who feel misrepresented by the sketchy characterizations offered of both poles
of a binary opposition. Points of view offered as Islamic below are supported by Islamic source texts
and held by substantial numbers of Muslims, but are not necessarily majority or dominant views. A
similar warning should be kept in mind for views labelled Western, by which I usually mean views
emerging out of the Enlightenment project of rejecting religion and tradition, and relying on
observations and logic as the sole source of trustworthy knowledge.
A peculiar aspect of knowledge is that one who does not have it does not know what he or she does
not have. A non-mathematician will not be thrilled by the elegance of the Law of the Iterated
Logarithms, will not be able to differentiate between trivial and deep results, appreciate subtleties, or
evaluate the relative skill of experts and separate them from charlatans. Even more, that person will
not be able to assess the difference that possession of such knowledge will make to his or her own
life. Views like those of Macaulays that a single shelf of a good European library was worth the whole
native literature of India and Arabia, cannot easily be refuted. The effort required to acquire alien types
of knowledge will not be made by those who do not appreciate the value of this type of knowledge.
Without investment of substantial time and effort, appreciation of a complex and sophisticated alien
structure of knowledge cannot be acquired. Once acquired, it cannot be easily conveyed to others,
especially to those disdainful about the value of such knowledge. The Arabic word for `student
translates to seeker of knowledge and an attitude of humility, as well as the desire or passion to

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

acquire knowledge and to value it above all things, are essential characteristics for a student in the
Islamic tradition.

1.2 Contrasting historical experiences with religion


In the sixteenth century, religion was central to human thought both in Europe and in the Islamic world.
Subsequent events in Europe led to radical changes in ways of thinking in the West, but did not impact
on the Islamic world. Large libraries of books are devoted to details of these events and how they
affected the development of European thought. There is no way to summarize this material in a few
paragraphs without introducing substantial distortions. It is nonetheless necessary to sketch a bare
bones outline of the crucial historical events in Europe that are directly relevant to differences in
European and Islamic views about how economic affairs should be organized in societies.
Violent religious conflicts and disenchantment with religion among intellectuals in Europe led to a
search for alternatives to religion as a basis for social organization. Secular thought found
replacements for traditional, religion-based answers to the questions of appropriate standards for
individual and social behaviour, suitable forms and purposes of political and economic organization, as
well as a myriad of others. Economic theory and other social sciences emerged as means for
providing clarification of and support for answers to the questions that religion could no longer provide.
Two crucial ideas which lie at the heart of secular thought and are not consonant with Islamic views
are the following:

The assumption of shared values made possible by religion makes it possible to view society as an
organic whole, united in a common purpose (polis). Common goals, values and purposes cannot be
assumed in a secular society. Political and social organization must be re-conceived as a means of
regulating conflicts and allowing people with disparate and conflicting goals to live together in peace
(societas). Manicas (1989) discusses this transition from polis to societas in political thought as one of
the key transitions associated with modernity.

Since common goals cannot be assumed, freedom/liberty and wealth, which are regarded as
universal means to achieve all goals, are promoted to being the purpose of secular political and
economic organization. Freedom is valuable only insofar as it is freedom to pursue specific goals of
value, and not for its own sake. Setting up individual freedom as a moral value and reconciling it with
social obligations occupied many enlightenment philosophers, notably J. S. Mill (1859) in On Liberty. The

Working Paper 22

invisible hand of Adam Smith also defends freedom, purporting to show that individuals pursuing their
self-interest will automatically lead to socially optimal outcomes. Austrian economics takes this further,
saying that freedom to pursue self-interest is, by definition, the socially optimal outcome. Similarly,
wealth is useful only as a means to some ends. Nonetheless, these means become ends in a secular
system of thought. For example, Weber (1930, Chapter 2) writes that the spirit of capitalism is the
pursuit of wealth as an end in itself, to the point of being absolutely irrational.
Muslim historical experience with religion has been entirely different from that of Europe. After a brief
early period known as the Khilafat-e-Rashida (The period of the rightly guided Caliphs), temporal and
spiritual leadership were separated in the Muslim world. Religious authorities were either intellectuals
and scholars (ulama), spiritual leaders (Sufis) or both; they did not exercise political authority. Thus,
political struggles in the Islamic world were not ascribed to religion. From the beginning, jihad or
warfare was a religious duty and hence subject to very strict rules. The Islamic rules of jihad,
containing equivalents of the provisions of the Geneva convention and prohibitions on hurting noncombatants and unnecessary destruction of property, served to ameliorate rather than exacerbate the
horrors of war (see Feldman, 2003). In short, Muslim historical experience gives no reason to reject
religion as a basis for organizing social, political, and economic behaviour.

1.3 The transition to secular thought and its consequences


The transition from religious to secular thought in Europe deeply influenced the development of social
science. Secular thought emphasized the diversity of human goals and the primacy of freedom to
choose. Wealth was seen as an essential component of freedom, as it allows individuals to do
whatever they desire. Thus the pursuit of wealth became a social goal and a means of obtaining
maximum freedom in a secular society. The contrast with Christian values, which denounce
acquisitiveness and greed, has been spelled out by Tawney (1926). Insensibly, failure to prescribe
what is to be done with wealth led to the pursuit of wealth itself becoming a goal, instead of a means to
a goal. Thus the answer to the fundamental economic question of what is to be done with surplus
wealth became use it to generate more wealth. Even though this answer is patently absurd, it is
nonetheless deeply believed by many. Economics as Religion by Nelson (2001) provides many
illustrations of how deeply held this type of belief has become and also how economic theory is
described in theological terms by many leading economists. While it seems a priori obvious that

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

wealth should be used to improve welfare, satisfaction, and happiness of individuals and society,
some economists (notably Friedman, 2005) condemn diversions from the goal of pursuing wealth to
pursue social goals in no uncertain terms.
Even though these ideas are easily seen to be products of particular European historical experiences
with religious conflict, they are commonly thought to have universal applicability2. The need to justify
and rationalize European conquests led to the idea of the White Mans burden: that European culture,
thought and socio-political systems are ideal forms and must be spread to the rest of the world3.
Several authors described stages of growth which would be followed by primitive societies to reach
European levels of development. For example, Hegel (1837) saw history as a teleological process
driven towards the goal of achieving European ideal forms of society. In the End of History, Fukuyama
(1992) suggests that, with the dissolution of Soviet Union, we have arrived at this goal. All of these
lines of thought converge on the idea that European thought is applicable to all societies, instead of
being a product of special events of European history.
The emergence of the social sciences in the West is closely tied to the Enlightenment project, and
attempts to find rational grounds on which to base social, political and economic structures. Theories
in the social sciences often abstract from Western historical experiences, and often take Western
institutional structures for granted as background. Mitchell (2002, p. 7) writes that The possibility of
social science is based upon taking certain historical experiences of the West as the template for a
universal knowledge. The impact of history on the development of social sciences in the West has
been ably traced by Manicas (1989) and also Gordon (1991). Wallerstein (1996) argues for the
necessity of changing disciplinary boundaries and content in social science. Thus, there is strong
evidence of the imprint of Western history on modern social science.
The conclusion that social science is Western and not generally applicable is nonetheless strongly
resisted by many. Enlightenment conceptions of knowledge as objective, external to the observer, and
based on truth, suggest that the history, origins and context of knowledge are not important; Kuhn
(1970) and Hacking (1983) provide an exposition of these theories of knowledge, as well as a critique.
In addition, Western universalism suggests that all cultures are essentially the same as primitive
Western cultures, and will mature into European patterns, thus making Western social science

10

Working Paper 22

universally applicable; see for example Fukuyama (1992) or Wallerstein (2006). Post-modern Western
thought has rejected both of these ideas. The attempt to fit all societies into the European pattern
leads to clearly recognizable biases known as Eurocentricism. Many aspects of the European
experience are unique to Europe and were not (and cannot be) experienced by other societies.
Insights of social science based on these particular European experiences are peculiar to the West
and cannot be generalised to other societies. Many authors have documented problems and errors
resulting from Eurocentricism; see for example, Hodgson and Burke (1993), Marglin (2007), or Mitchell
(2002). Specifically in the context of economic development, Arshad Zaman (1989) discusses
historical differences between the East and the West which make Rostows idea that all development
will follow the European pattern implausible.

1.4 The emergence of economics in Europe


European history has had a tremendous impact on modern economic theory, in shaping the questions
asked, as well as the questions not asked; in delimitations of boundaries; and in methodology. This
influence is not generally recognized because of the assumption of the universality of Western
experience, as well as the pretensions of economics to the status of science, and an assumption that
scientific truth is objective. Since the Islamic world has not been subject to these historical forces,
formulations and discussions of economics in the Muslim world often reject settled answers and
disagree with universally agreed upon assumptions of modern economic discourse. Our goal in this
section is to bring out several key features of modern economic theory which are products of
accidents of European history rather than natural ways of treating the subject matter. This discussion
of the historical roots of Western economic theory is necessary because large portions of modern
Islamic economics are responses to Western economic theory, albeit informed by different historical
experiences.

1.4.1

The deification of science

European loss of faith in the certainties of religion (termed the Death of God by Nietzsche) led to the
search for alternative certainties on which knowledge could be reliably founded. Scientific knowledge
was to take the place of sacred knowledge, and an intensive effort on many fronts was made to
establish the superiority, objectivity, and certainty of scientific knowledge, and to distinguish it from
other forms of knowledge; see Science Defied and Science Deified by Olson (1990). Mirowski (1989)

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

has described how the tremendous prestige of Newtonian physics resulted in a self-conscious effort
by economists to model their discipline along similar lines. Emulation of physics has led to the
following elements of modern economic methodology which are quite alien to natural pre-conceptions.
Using just one law of motion for particles, Newton was able to present a unified treatment of a large
number of apparently unrelated phenomena. Economists have similarly adopted maximization of utility
as the sole acceptable principle of explanation for human behaviour. Surprising as it may seem to
outsiders, explanations of human behaviour which take into account motivations other than
selfishness or greed are not considered acceptable by modern mainstream economists. Physicsenvy is only one part of the explanation of why this became the dominant methodology in economic
theory. A number of other quirks of European/American history, described by Manicas (1989) among
others, have led to this outcome. The story is further complicated by the recent emergence of a
number of competitors, like institutional economics and behavioural/experimental economics, which
challenge this dominant methodology. Our goals in sketching this history are to point out that the
model of rational self-interest is not natural, does not correspond to actual human behaviour, and
does not offer any special advantages over other methods for constructing economic models. That
this has become the bedrock of mainstream methodology in economics is due to specifics of the
evolution of thought in Europe and the USA. The idea of regarding humans as solely motivated by
selfishness is repugnant to Islamic traditions for many reasons, and this creates substantial
divergence between Islamic and Western views regarding economic affairs.
Another development directly related to the tremendous prestige of physics and subsequent scientific
developments in Europe is the emphasis placed on use of formal and mathematical methods in
economics. McCloskey (1984) has discussed how Samuelson has used mathematics to impress and
appear authoritative, and not because it adds any depth to the economic argument. Echoing
complaints by many leading economists about the overuse of mathematics, Blaug (1998) writes that
Economists have gradually converted the subject into a sort of social mathematics in which analytical
rigor as understood in math departments is everything and empirical relevance (as understood in
physics departments) is nothing. Economics conceived as a set of natural laws, amenable to
analysis by mathematical models, has also displaced a historical and qualitative approach to the
subject; see Manicas (1989) for details. In contrast, the qualitative and historical tradition initiated by
Ibn-e-Khaldun, termed by many the father of the social sciences, continues to dominate Islamic
analysis4.

11

12

Working Paper 22

1.4.2

The de-moralization of economics

One set of natural questions about economic affairs relates to ethics, morality, and concepts of
fairness and justice. If I hoard goods in anticipation of scarcity, and charge high prices, is this clever or
is it immoral? Should one make profits from the misery of others? Is it fair to charge interest for the
lending of money? Is gluttony sinful, especially when the money spent to combat the problem of being
overweight is more than enough to eliminate hunger and malnutrition in the world? Should we increase
taxes to provide more aid for reducing poverty? Do we have a responsibility to feed the poor of other
countries at the expense of the wealthy in ours? Is it fair for the wealthy capitalist to exploit labourers
by paying them a very low wage? These and similar questions were central to earlier formulations of
economics in Europe. They are no longer part of the subject matter of economics, as currently
conceived in modern texts. The questions cannot even be formulated or posed within the modern
language used by economists. Many economists would consider them meaningless questions, while
others regard them as outside the discipline of economics.
It was the convergence of several different sets of historical forces in Europe that led to this outcome.
Himmelfarb (1996), in the De-moralization of Society, discusses the general weakening of the forces
of morality in England. The transition to secular thought affected all the social sciences. Tawney
(1926) has discussed how central economic problems were formulated and discussed in religious
terms in the sixteenth century, but how references to religion in relation to economic affairs became
rare by the eighteenth. The Reformation, the Enlightenment, and the drive to investigate social affairs
using only logic and empirics, without reference to religion, were important parts of this process. Many
of the questions posed above are, however, centrally addressed in Islamic tradition. Some are clearly
settled by source texts and others have been the subject of scholarly debate for a long time. Since
religion has not been marginalized in Islamic societies, any Islamic formulation of economics cannot
bypass these questions, nor can it treat them as being outside the domain of inquiry.
Another damaging consequence of the attempt by economists to emulate the physical sciences in the
West has been a general failure to appreciate the possibilities and potential for change and
transformation in human beings. Human beings are free to choose in ways not determined by their
past. Studying the laws of motion for societies requires that this possibility be denied. In many of the
social sciences, the importance of human agency and the potential for changes in cultural and group

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

behaviour are recognized. However, these contemporary trends have not had any impact in
economics. The idea that there are natural laws governing economics, which is at the heart of
modern Western economic theory, has had grave consequences. Just as we do not ask if it is fair or
just that stones fall at 9.8 m/s2, so the natural laws of economics shield us from taking responsibility
for the hunger, misery and economic destitution around us. Recognition that any economic laws that
exist do so as a result of our individual and collective decisions about how to structure our societies
places a tremendous responsibility squarely upon our shoulders. We choose the economic structure
of our societies by the form of legislation, the development of institutions, and by teaching our children
to be kind and generous (or greedy and acquisitive). Shouldering responsibility for enjoining the good
and prohibiting the evil, and for working to transform human beings from a materialist to a spiritual
perspective, is fundamental to the message of Islam. This creates a great gap between Islamic and
Western views on economics.

1.4.3

Empiricism and logical positivism

Logical positivism and related philosophies have been tremendously influential in shaping Western
social science in the twentieth century. In general, philosophy of science was an attempt to give
rigorous analytical and philosophical backing to the European intuition that scientific knowledge is
different from, and superior to, other types of knowledge. In particular, scientific knowledge rests on
objectively verifiable facts, and trustworthy logical derivations from these facts alone. Other types of
human knowledge utilize intuition and unverifiable assumptions, posit the existence of unobservable
entities, and may utilize unreliable or false logic. One of the explicit goals of logical positivists was to
discredit religion as a source of knowledge. Attempts to accomplish this goal of differentiating between
scientific and other types of knowledge eventually failed on many different fronts. This failure5, the
death of logical positivism, has impacted on different fields within the social sciences in different
ways. While many disciplines have made suitable adjustments to their methodologies and moved
away from positivist precepts, mainstream economics continues to espouse positivist principles.
Reuben (1996) writes that in the 1870s, dominant Western views were that knowledge was all of one
piece, embracing spiritual, moral and cognitive dimensions. All knowledge was held to illuminate the
divine; thus in teaching physics, astronomy, etc., lecturers were expected to attend only to the
beautiful truths which are to be read in the works of God. In particular, morality was founded in

13

14

Working Paper 22

empirical laws about human behaviour, and hence could be studied and justified by observations about
human nature. By 1930s this unity was shattered, with positivism driving a wedge between factual
cognitive knowledge and moral/spiritual knowledge. Science was considered to be value-free and
distinct from morality. Economists have embraced the idea that their discipline is a science, and
hence objective, fact-based and value free. Some of the distortions caused by displaying ethical and
political commitments as universal scientific truths are discussed below.
Economic systems must be designed, justified and evaluated with reference to some goal for
economic activity. However, in a secular society we must make room for a variety of possible values,
and take care not to force our values on others. Webers (1918) assertion that social science should
be value-free also became widely accepted. These contingencies of European history led economists
to present their subject as a collection of facts and regularities economic laws which could be
used by any policy maker for furthering state goals. Many authors have pointed out the strong set of
values embedded in supposedly value-neutral economic discourse see, for example Nelson (2001).
Freedom, represented by free markets, free trade and wealth, are promoted as desirable values.
People who resist disruptions that would be caused by the free operation of markets (such as
transitional unemployment and lack of job stability) are labelled irrational and their preference for
tradition and stability over efficiency is considered an undesirable value. This illustrates Foucaults
thesis that modern human sciences (biological, psychological, social) purport to offer universal
scientific truths about human nature that are, in fact, often mere expressions of ethical and political
commitments of a particular society6. Values hidden in modern economics are not in conformity with
the values promoted by Islam. The distinction between Western and Islamic views in this area is not,
as often suggested, a distinction between positive and normative views, but between a hidden set of
values that is in opposition to an explicit and openly stated normative framework.

1.4.4

Fragmentation of knowledge and disciplinary boundaries

It is commonly believed that the explosion in the quantity of knowledge has led to the fragmentation of
knowledge. In fact, knowledge is unified by purpose. Having a sense of the broad outlines of human
endeavour, and how it serves the human race, one can have an idea of how ones efforts fit into this
big picture. Current conceptions of science militate against this unity. Economists claim their discipline
is positive. As scientists, they can only assess and explain the factual consequences that have
resulted from different types of economic policies. Judging which policy is better or worse is a

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

normative act, which in their view should be left to policy makers. This type of insulation and
fragmentation (which has nothing to do with the explosion of information) has disastrous
consequences. If policies enrich a few and impoverish many, or damage the environment and profit
the multinationals, or lead to debt and starvation in poor African countries, the economist has nothing
to say about it in his status as a scientific economist. The physicist who works round the clock to
produce an atom bomb claims that he is not responsible for how it is used. A biologist has discovered
high yield varieties of rice which could feed the whole world. However, distribution, publicity, pushing
for policies for adoption etc. are not within that persons specialty. Instead, if a multinational hires the
biologist for developing a variety that is not fertile (so that it will be able sell new seeds every season),
that person will do the work for a salary, and not ask whether this development will be harmful to the
interests of humanity as a whole. Islam does not allow us to dissociate ourselves from the
consequences of our deeds: Those who point to the good (deed) are like the doers7. Similarly, those
who are instrumental in evil are also responsible for the evil.
With increasing secularism, and the basing of knowledge on experience and reason, norms and
values came to be regarded as unscientific. The glue of the common purpose of serving humankind,
however, binds the strands of knowledge together. The idea that life arose by an accident and will
perish in another accident denies all purpose to human existence and dissolves this glue, leading to
the fragmentation of knowledge. Consider the field demarcation between psychology and economics.
Economists refuse to consider the issue of how wealth and materials affect the sense of satisfaction,
wellbeing, contentment or happiness that people experience, on the ground that these questions
belong to the realm of psychology (see Gul and Pesendorfer, 2007). They consider it as the role of
their profession to consider only how people can become wealthy. Recent inter-disciplinary
investigations have revealed that attitudes towards wealth, the methods by which it is acquired, as well
as interpersonal dispositions, can play an extremely important role in determining the satisfaction
obtained by the pursuit of wealth. Lane (2001) and Layard (2005) have documented how vast
increases in wealth in Western societies have failed to increase contentment, satisfaction and a
sense of wellbeing. This has extremely serious consequences for economics if determined efforts to
increase GNP and wealth have detrimental consequences for human welfare, then what is the point of
it all? At the very least, economists must pay attention to these issues, to ensure that the pursuit of
wealth has a point in terms of increasing human satisfaction. Islamic views do not permit such
separation and artificial boundaries between fields.

15

16

Working Paper 22

1.5 Outline of the paper


Knowledge is traditionally conceived of as being based on experience, observations and reason, and
assessed in terms of being true or false. This is common to both Islamic and Western traditions.
When religious tradition became contested as a source of knowledge, a deeper study of the sources
and validity of different types of knowledge was made in the West. This led to an appreciation of the
impact of history on knowledge. For example, Marx thought that theory was shaped by class interests,
while Foucault argued that knowledge functions to legitimize power structures. The idea that
knowledge interacts with historical experience is central to this paper. Historical events are analysed in
the light of dominant theories (existing knowledge), and suitable responses to the events are made. An
analysis of the outcomes of these events and responses, again made in the light of existing
knowledge, becomes part of the updated and new knowledge base. Thus experience shapes
knowledge and is also shaped by knowledge.
Exactly as Western economic theory has been shaped by the forces of history, so modern Islamic
economics has emerged in response to recent challenges faced by Muslims. In Section 2, the origins
of Islamic economics are outlined. First its origins in the history of early Islam, European colonialism
and responses to the evolution of conventional economic thinking are discussed. Second, the reasons
for its recent evolution are explored in more detail, in terms of problems facing Muslim societies and
attempts to find solutions in conformity with Islamic traditions. Section 3 sets out the goals of an
Islamic economic system. It considers some basic methodological issues, the Islamic view of human
beings and the use of material wealth for spiritual pursuits. The following section explores the
framework provided for Islamic economics by Sharia or Islamic law with respect to property rights, the
conduct of business and labour. As a preliminary to considering the role of government in establishing
and operating an Islamic economy, political aspects of an Islamic state are considered briefly. The
remainder of Section 5 considers various key elements of economic management: public finance,
distribution, social justice, security and welfare. In Section 6 the nature and role of various institutions
is discussed: financial institutions, insurance (takaful), endowment or trust (waqf), and audit or
accountability (hisbah). Finally, brief sections consider issues related to environmental protection and
use of natural resources, and the principles governing the economic behaviour of individuals.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

2 The origins of Islamic economics


Q9:111 Allah hath bought from the believers their lives and their wealth in return for Paradise.
A large number of the teachings of Islam deal with economic affairs. One of the five questions Muslims
will face on Judgement Day will be: How did you earn your wealth and how did you spend it? Our
earnings must come from halal means (permissible according to Islamic Law), and must be spent on
halal categories of expenditure. The necessities of governing an expanding empire led early Muslim
writers to discuss halal methods for raising revenues for the state, as well as the obligations of the
state (according to Islamic law) to spend on the public. Thus, public finance is a sophisticated and well
developed field within Islamic scholarship. Modern Islamic economics is based on these early Islamic
teachings, but has also been strongly shaped by the colonization of Islamic lands, struggles for
independence, and the need to respond to assertions of the superiority of Western knowledge.

2.1 The historical roots of Islamic economics


Knowledge of permanent and enduring value is that which permits us to realize our potential as human
beings. This is recorded in the Quran and translated into human experience by the Prophet
Muhammad8, as captured in the Hadeeth (records of the sayings and actions of the Prophet or his
companions). Other knowledge can be relevant and important in particular historical circumstances.
For example, knowledge of castle building, astrolabes and sailing ships was important in an earlier
era. In contemporary times, the development of Islamic economics represents a Muslim response to
the challenge created by the ascendance of the West. Increasing materialism, changing attitudes
towards poverty, and other effects of the development of capitalism are aptly summarized in the
transition from the Biblical love of money is the root of all evil to Shaws lack of money is the root of
all evil. Since the economic system (capitalism, communism, socialism) is a major feature of
Western identity, engagement requires a Muslim response in these terms. This is complicated by the
fact that economics is not a high priority in Islam. As put by Mufti Shafi (1978):
There is no doubt that Islam is opposed to monasticism and considers economic
activities to be permissible, desirable, and even necessary and required at times.
Economic progress is desirable for men, and the earning of a Halal livelihood is required
after the religious requirements. At the same time, it is equally self evident that in Islam
the fundamental problem of man is not economic, and economic progress is not a goal
or objective of life for humans.

17

18

Working Paper 22

Mufti Shafi goes on to explain that in Islam, economic activity is a means to an end, and not an end in
itself. This difference in purpose is fundamental, and is the basis for all other differences between
Islamic and Western views on economic affairs. There is no doubt that many Islamic teachings relate
to economic affairs, and there exists a vast literature on many aspects of economic affairs, starting
from the earliest periods of Islamic history. A survey and summary of the economic thought of early
Muslims is given in Sadeq and Ghazali (1992),9 and Islahi (2008) provides an excellent literature
survey of Muslim economic thought in general. Nonetheless, economics was never considered in
isolation, as a separate subject, since it is always a means to an end, and never an end in itself.
Numerous specific goals or ends for economic activity will be discussed in what follows. As a broad
general principle, Islamic systems in all spheres are built with the goal of promoting community feeling
and cooperation among all members of society:
(Q3:103) And hold fast, all together, by the rope which Allah (stretches out for you), and
be not divided among yourselves; and remember with gratitude Allahs favour on you; for
ye were enemies and He joined your hearts in love, so that by His Grace, ye became
brethren;
Other verses (Q8:62, 63) state that all the treasure in the world cannot purchase love between hearts.
This prioritization of community feeling over material wealth differentiates Islamic systems from the
competitive self-interest based individualistic systems at the heart of modern economic theory.
The birth of Islamic economics as we know it today can be dated to the early twentieth century. The
needs of liberation movements gave a distinct shape to Islamic thought all over the Islamic world. It
was necessary to argue that Islam required Muslims to struggle for freedom, and that it offered a
better way of life than the dominant Western systems of capitalism and communism. This forced
Muslim thinkers to delineate and distinguish Islamic socio-political and economic systems10. Although
these issues have been discussed by many Muslim thinkers, two major figures devoted substantial
energy and time to developing the basis and defending the need for a distinct Islamic economic
system: Mohammad Baqir Al-Sadr (1961) in his book Our Economy, and Sayyid Abul Ala Maududi in
numerous books and articles (e.g. Economic System of Islam, 1970). Chapra (2004) summarises
this historical background and the views of Maududi, and gives citations to the latters numerous
works. Chapra also remarks on the courage it took to formulate an Islamic system and defend it
against the dominant and apparently tremendously successful Western systems in the early twentieth

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

century. Mirakhor (2005) presents a survey of trends in Islamic economics, which includes some
discussion of the contributions of Baqir Al-Sadr. T. M. Aziz (1993) and Wilson (1998) have discussed
at much greater length the contribution and legacy of Baqir Al-Sadr. The founders of Islamic
economics (Al-Sadr, 1961; Maududi,1947, 1970) agree that the focus of Islam is on human and
spiritual development, and the purpose of an economic system is to promote justice and equity. Both
believed that applications of Islamic laws and guiding principles in the economic sphere would bring
advances in human welfare and be superior to Western systems for handling economic affairs, which
promote only material welfare.
To summarise, it is worth putting the development of Islamic economics into a broader perspective.
During the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, European colonization of Muslim lands had destroyed
functioning political, social, health and educational structures11. This was considered necessary for
progress since, as Lord Cromer, the British counsel in Cairo from 1883-1907, said as a social
system, Islam has been a complete failure. Islam keeps women in a position of inferiorityit permits
slaveryits general tendency is intolerance towards other faiths Said (1978, Introduction, part III)
provides a penetrating analysis of the effects of European colonisation on the production of Western
knowledge about the Orient; he writes that All academic knowledge about India and Egypt is
somehow tinged and impressed with, violated by, the gross political fact (of imperialism).
It is now widely agreed that good institutions and public participation in and ownership of socio-political
processes12 are crucial to progress and development (broadly defined). Indigenous institutions,
created and adapted to perceived public needs, had been replaced during the colonial era by alien and
exploitative governance structures designed solely for the efficient extraction of revenues. Replacing
these relics of the colonial era and adapting them for use in states based on Islamic principles, as well
as creating new institutions in line with Islamic ideals, is a huge task, requiring both vision and the
political power and energy to implement the vision. The task is further complicated by powerful vested
interests, as well as European interests and fears of Islam. The failure of alien, authoritarian, and
exploitative Western institutions to take root in Muslim societies has been attributed to Islam and
characterised by some as backwardness (e.g. Lewis, 2003a, 2003b, but see also rebuttals by Alam
(2002), Dalrymple (2004) and Hirsh (2004)). Concerted efforts are being made to co-opt and coerce
Muslims into following Western agendas, with explicit encouragement to creating versions of Islam

19

20

Working Paper 22

amenable to Western interests and fomenting divisions among Muslims see, for example, Benard
(2004). The struggle to find a suitable compromise between the demands of modernity and the
demands of Islam is under way throughout the Islamic world, with a wide spectrum of positions being
adopted by different groups. Maulana Syed Abul Hasan Ali Nadvi (1980) gives a Muslim point of view
regarding this struggle, which will shape the future of the Muslim world and of which the development
of Islamic economics is part.

2.2 The emergence of Islamic economics in the post-colonial era


There is widespread agreement among Muslims with the theses of Maududi and Baqir Al-Sadr that the
moral imperatives embedded in an Islamic economic system differentiate it from both capitalism and
communism13. More detailed articulation of such a system had, however, to wait until the 1970s, when
several factors created a need for new economic thinking. The emergence of OPEC put a substantial
amount of political power and wealth in Muslim hands. At the time, developed financial markets existed
only in the West, so this newfound wealth was placed in American and European markets. However,
the interest-based financial system conflicted with Islamic law, and this created a demand for
Islamically permissible alternatives. The seizure of USD 8 billion of Iranian assets by the USA in 1979
and subsequent similar threats have also led Muslims to seek alternatives to investment in the West.
Many Islamic economists date the birth of the second wave of Islamic economics to the First
International Conference on Islamic Economics held in Mecca in 1976. The papers presented at that
and subsequent conferences, which rapidly multiplied, conform to the thesis of Pfeifer (1996), who
argues that Islamic economics was a response to the economic problems facing many Muslims, just
as Keynesian economics responded to problems created by the Great Depression and Marxian
economics responded to problems created by industrialization in England. A characteristic of this
second wave of Islamic economic thinking is its concern with details, and technical and operational
aspects, as opposed to the general systems and global outlook of the first wave. Islahi (2008) has
presented an excellent account of the history and a categorization of the different types of Islamic
Economics corresponding to the characteristics of different eras.
The recent literature on Islamic economics is so vast that only a tiny percentage can be referred to
here. Akram Khan (1983, 1991, 1998) has provided extensive annotated bibliographies of material in
English and Urdu. I must also apologise for my lack of familiarity with the vast Arabic literature that has

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

not been translated, as well as scattered offerings in many Islamic languages14; this may have led to
significant omissions and distortions without my being aware of it. Broad overviews from different
perspectives are given in Chapra (2000), Kuran (1997), Pfeifer (1996) and Issawi (1984). An early but
nonetheless useful literature survey is Siddiqi (1980). Monzer Kahf has written extensively on nearly all
aspects of Islamic economics (Kahf, 1991, 1995a, 1995b, 1996a, 1996b, 1998a, 1998b, 2000, 2003,
2004, undated)15. The Islamic Research and Training Institute (IRTI), a department of the Islamic
Development Bank (IDB), has initiated a project to build a comprehensive web-based library of Islamic
economics16.
In the post-colonial era, Muslims have (differing degrees of) freedom to handle their economic affairs.
Western methods of organizing economic affairs and Western institutions are often in conflict with
Islamic laws and, more fundamentally, Islamic concepts of socio-political and economic organization.
Efforts to transform these organizations and institutions have led to both theoretical and practical
developments in Islamic economics. In states where Muslims have had political power and live in
sufficient numbers, fully or partially Islamic systems have resulted. In other situations, Muslims have
used private and market-oriented means rather than government policies to create economic
institutions in conformity with Islamic law. These three situations (fully Islamic governments, a mixture
of secular and Islamic institutions, and purely private market-based Islamic institutions) have led to the
establishment of different types of economic institutions and are considered separately below.
Differing types of needs have led to the involvement of different types of contributors to the
development of the literature. The need for articulation of an ideal Islamic system in conformity with
Islamic law led to the first wave of authors, consisting of traditional scholars of Islam, who mainly have
legal training in Islamic law. The need to analyse modern economic institutions in order to transform
them in appropriate directions led to a second wave of authors trained in Western schools of
economics. Practical aspects of making concrete changes in financial institutions and government
regulations have led to a number of political and policy oriented writings from various sources. Kahf
(2004) discusses these categories and also provides a chronology and history, as well as identifying
problems arising from the multidisciplinary nature of the subject. It has been realised for some time
that training in several disciplines (including both traditional Islamic law and modern economics) is
needed and several institutions have been set up to meet this need. Among the largest is the Islamic

21

22

Working Paper 22

Development Bank (IDB), established in 1975 to foster the economic development and social
progress of member countries and Muslim communities individually as well as jointly in accordance
with the principles of Shariah i.e. Islamic Law. The Islamic Research and Training Institute (IRTI) is
the academic wing of the IDB and has produced a substantial number of publications on all aspects of
Islamic economics.

2.2.1

Fully Islamic governments

Any government committed to enforcing Islamic law (or the Shariah) may be considered a fully Islamic
government for our present purposes in this paper. In the modern era, Iran, Saudi Arabia, Sudan, and
also Afghanistan for a short period of time, might be considered fully Islamic. However, an implicit
agreement by religious leaders to leave political and economic control in the hands of the Saud family,
in return for enforcement of Islamic law in social, family and personal matters, has meant that the
economic structures in Saudi Arabia have not been subjected to Islamic law. This situation is slowly
changing in response to changes in the rest of the Islamic world. The experience of Iran in Islamizing
its economic system has been discussed in Niblock and Wilson (1999) and Farhadian (2002). Some
aspects of the Sudanese experience with Islamization of its economic system have been discussed
by Elhiraika (2003, 2004) and Elhiraika and Ismail (2000). Movements for full Islamization of social,
political and economic structures have occurred in other countries, notably Algeria, Afghanistan and
Pakistan. Although these struggles have not been fully successful, they have nonetheless had
substantial impacts on institutional structures.

2.2.2

Partially Islamic governments

At the global and nation-state levels, Islamic movements have generated a large amount of political
literature, which seeks to persuade the public of the benefits of an Islamic system, generally defined in
rather vague terms. For example, the Refah party in Turkey promised a just economic system and
defined it as an Islamic economic system. Numerous Islamic political parties all over the world have
published platforms about how they would organize economic affairs along Islamic lines. In practice,
tensions between the idealistic vision of Islam and practical necessities have led to gaps between
promises and performance. Noori (1986) studied these issues in Pakistan and Iran, while Beinin
(2004) analyses the performance of Islamic parties in Egypt and Turkey. To attract voters, even parties
based on other ideologies have attempted to portray their economic policies as Islamic. For example,

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

the Peoples Party in Pakistan promoted Islamic communism as part of its platform, and tracts on
Islamic socialism also exist (see Mintjes, 1978; Sibai, 1982).
In many Muslim countries, demands for Islamization have led to governments creating and/or
accommodating Islamic financial and other institutions. In Malaysia and Indonesia, many Islamic
financial institutions operate alongside conventional ones, with government support. Ariff (1419H/1998)
and Timberg (2000) respectively discuss the Malaysian and Indonesian economic experiences. In
Pakistan, demands for complete Islamization of the financial sector have been resisted by the
government, and there is a move towards the Malaysian/Indonesian models of allowing both secular
interest-based institutions and Islamic institutions to operate. Tahir (2007) gives some details of the
progress of Islamic banking in the Muslim world, while Ayub (2007) discusses the history of Islamic
banking in Pakistan.
It is worth mentioning that the struggle to establish Islamic institutions has occurred in other domains
as well, influencing government policy and decisions, as well as civil society. For example, Martin Lau
(2006) details the impact of Islam and Islamic law on the Pakistani legal system, which led to
emergence of Sharia courts (in parallel with secular ones).

2.2.3

Private sector solutions

Where Muslims are in a minority or lack political power, private and market-based solutions (which do
not require governmental support) have been developed to allow financial transactions in conformity
with Islamic law. While the number of such institutions is extremely large and diverse, they have not
been the subject of any systematic study. A few areas in which there has been substantial activity are
listed below.
There are a large number of Islamic mortgage companies operating throughout the world. These are
generally based on diminishing musharka, which is an Islamic version of a rent-purchase scheme
(see Bendjilali and Tariqullah Khan, 1995). There are also two listed mutual funds in the USA (AMANA
growth and income), which purchase stock in companies declared to be Islamically permissible. The
launch of the Dow Jones Islamic Index in 1999 was a milestone in this development. Conventional
insurance has an element of gambling, which is not permissible according to most scholars of Islamic

23

24

Working Paper 22

law (see Section 6.2). Accordingly, alternatives have been devised, and many companies based on
Islamically permissible forms of insurance have been launched. Usmani (2000) and El-Gamal (2000)
provide introductory explanations of Islamic law about banking and insurance, with references to both
contemporary and older primary sources. In the private sector, many types of firms have developed
innovative means to cleanse their day-to-day operations of interest-based and other un-Islamic
transactions (see for example, Sitara Chemicals at http://www.sitara.com.pk/company/finplcy.htm ).
Schemes to provide Islamic microfinance and microcredit have also been launched. Sait and Lim
(2005, Paper 8) give a broad overview, while Grace and Al-Zamzami (2001) discuss a case study of
microcredit in Yemen. These private sector initiatives are diverse, decentralized, and uncoordinated,
and to my knowledge, there has not yet been any systematic academic study of the phenomenon17.

2.2.4

Islamic economics as a response to Muslim needs

The different situations faced by Muslims require different types of solutions along Islamic lines.
Muslims in control of a modern nation state need guidance on how to run a state along Islamic lines.
Traditional forms of Islamic states and the extensive legal apparatus developed by Muslims to run
such states needs to be updated and modified to meet modern requirements. Kahf (1991), Siddiqui
(1948) and Hasanuzzaman (1980) discuss the economic functions of an Islamic state in the light of
history and Islamic law, with a view to implementation in a modern state. Tahir et al (1999) and Waqar
M. Khan (2002), among others, detail concrete steps required for a transition from secular financial
institutions to Islamic ones.
In the majority of Muslim states, secular and westernized elites compete with Islamic elements and
prevent the formation of fully Islamic states. In other cases, non-Muslim governments may seek to
accommodate Muslim minorities (India, Sri Lanka, South Africa, etc.) or Muslim governments may
seek to accommodate non-Muslim minorities (Malaysia, Indonesia, etc.). In all such cases, partial
government support for initiatives for Islamization and Islamic institutions is available. Muslim authors
agree that the financial, political and social institutions of an Islamic state form a coordinated and
integrated whole. There is some controversy about whether partial Islamization, or the introduction of
Islamic institutions working within an un-Islamic framework, is feasible or desirable in an Islamic state.
A minority have taken the view that the philosophy and worldview behind capitalistic institutions is
antithetical to Islam (Taseen 2001, Vadillo n.d., Ansari 2000). In their view it is necessary to make

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

radical transformations and Islamize the whole state prior to building Islamic institutions; they consider
that efforts to Islamize institutions within an un-Islamic framework are counterproductive. The majority
of authors have taken the point of view that gradual and step-by-step Islamization will require
transitional forms in which some parts and aspects of the economy are Islamized. Books like
Introduction to Islamic Finance by Usmani (2000) and Islamic Banking and Finance: Theory and
Practice by M. N. Ayub (2002) spell out the technical requirements and changes in conventional
banking that would be required to make it conform to Islamic law, without assuming a fully Islamic
framework and other supporting Islamic institutions.
In situations where Muslims are in a minority, and government and large scale institutional support or
changes in legal frameworks are not possible, rulings of Islamic law are required on what is and is not
permissible for Islamic institutions and individuals operating in a non-Islamic environment. Fahim Khan
(2002) provides a survey of the literature on the application of Islamic law to different types of modern
economic issues.
In a broader perspective, Islamic economics can be considered part of an ongoing project for the
Islamization of knowledge, as defined by Al-Attas (1984) and Al-Faruqi (1982). Prior to the colonization
of Islamic lands, centres for religious learning (madrassas and jamias or universities) taught the basic
Islamic sciences and provided education in all fields. For example, Sikand (2004) writes about
madrassas in pre-colonial and early colonial British India:
The syllabus employed at the Nizamia madrassa, which served as a model for
madrassas elsewhere, represented a blend of naqli ulum (revealed sciences), including
the Quran, the hadith, fiqh (Islamic jurisprudence) and tafsir (Quranic commentary), on
the one hand, and the aqli ulum (rational sciences), including Arabic language, grammar,
logic, rhetoric, philosophy, astronomy, medicine, physics and mathematics, on the other.
These systems of education were eventually destroyed by colonization. For example, in British India,
properties of trusts devoted to educational and health services were seized and government jobs were
restricted to graduates of English-medium educational institutions. Madrassas adopted creative
strategies to survive, but loss of prestige, state patronage, endowments and jobs for their graduates
led to substantial changes in their role and function. In particular, they retrenched to the core function
of providing a religious education, abandoning the secular fields partly because of lack of resources,

25

26

Working Paper 22

and partly because they could not compete with newly founded modern educational institutions. This
history is available from Akram (1975), Ahmad (1953), Sikand (2004) and others.
From the earliest colonial times, the desire to incorporate western science into the curriculum of a
standard Islamic training has been tempered with the knowledge that the worldview underlying these
sciences is antithetical to Islam. A penetrating analysis of the both the attractions and perils of
Western science and differing Muslim attitudes is given in Kalin (2002). Nevertheless, efforts have
been made, and continue to be made, to integrate Western sciences into the framework of an Islamic
education, and Islamic economics is part of this effort. In concrete form, the Organization of the
Islamic Conference (OIC) chartered and launched the two International Islamic Universities explicitly
for this purpose at the start of the fifteenth century Hijri (1979-80 A.D.)18. In addition to these Islamic
universities, and numerous other Islamic institutions that are trying to integrate Islamic and Western
knowledge, some Western institutions (for example the universities of Harvard in the USA,
Loughborough in the UK, and Bochum in Germany) have launched departments or programmes
designed to study Islamic economics. In addition to the desire to study this new phenomenon,
activities are probably motivated by a desire to benefit from the large amount of money in Muslim
countries and the Muslim preference for financial services that conform to Islamic law.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Fundamentals of an Islamic economic system


(Q28:77) But seek, with the (wealth) which Allah has bestowed on thee, the Home of the
Hereafter, nor forget thy portion in this world: but do thou good, as Allah has been good to
thee, and seek not (occasions for) mischief in the land: for Allah loves not those who do
mischief.

As the earlier quote from Mufti Shafi (1978) indicates, an Islamic economic system is a means to an
end, rather than an end in itself. A defining characteristic of capitalism is the pursuit of wealth, and the
use of wealth as a yardstick to define development and progress (see, for example, Weber, 1930;
Giovanni Arrighi, 1997). This limited focus has been criticized by Islamic economists. Maududi (1970),
for example, writes that difficulties and complexities in understanding economics arise because
economic problems, which form a part of the larger problems of human existence,
have been separated out of the collectivity and considered in isolation. This tendency
eventually grew to the extent that economic problem became the central problem of
human existence. This second mistake was even larger than the first.
Many other authors criticize the simplifying assumptions of some conventional economics, especially
the pre-eminence given to economic growth as both a goal and a means of achieving welfare for all.
Chapra (1993), for example, writes: mere maximization of total output cannot be the goal of a Muslim
society. [It] must be accompanied by ensuring efforts directed to spiritual health justice
and fair play.
Specific goals and Islamic institutions, injunctions and concrete measures designed for their
realisation are detailed later. In this section, the religious starting points for Muslims attempts to design
an economic system that is compatible with Islam are outlined. These constitute a number of general
principles based on Islamic teaching and have methodological implications that will also be briefly
discussed. The detailed interpretation of Islamic teaching is not, however, the main focus of this paper,
and so the discussion will be limited to what I consider vital for the reader to understand subsequent
sections.

3.1 The Islamic view of human beings


The Islamic view of humans is dynamic and complex. It is acknowledged that greed and other base
motivations exist in humans, but the essence of humanity is the possibility of not acting on these and
instead choosing a higher and more spiritual mode of existence.

27

28

Working Paper 22

Q3:14) Fair in the eyes of men is the love of things they covet: Women and sons;
Heaped-up hoards of gold and silver; horses branded (for blood and excellence); and
(wealth of) cattle and well-tilled land. Such are the possessions of this worlds life; but in
nearness to Allah is the best of the goals.
Islam is concerned with the transformation of human beings from followers of base desires to people
concerned with achieving higher goals. It was this transformation of human beings, brought about by
the training of the Prophet Muhammad (may Allah shower his blessings upon him) that revolutionized
the world and changed the course of history19. The Quran asserts that there exists tremendous
potential for both good and evil within people:
Q95:4,5 Surely We created man in the best of forms. Then We reduced him to the
lowest of the low
The purpose of life is to struggle for the inner spiritual transformation required to achieve the potential
to be the best of the creation, superior even to the angels. This potential exists within every human
being; in this way, all are equal before God. These views are in stark contrast with the conception of
humans that is at the heart of modern neoclassical economic theory: in this view humans are solely
motivated by selfishness and greed, and are completely indifferent to others. We have already
discussed the historical origin of these views in the West, which arose from an attempt to mimic
successful methodology in physics. Humans imbued with Islamic values have been labelled homo
islamicus and contrasted with the homo economicus of neoclassical economic theory by several
authors see for example, Hosseini (1992), Kahf (1996b) and Mortazavi (2004).
We have suggested above that neo-classical economic theory is based on the assumption of
competition between self-interested individuals, while Islamic economics is based on advocacy of
cooperation within a community with shared goals. An empirical approach requires us to ask which of
the two theories is more accurate empirically. Are people selfish or cooperative? is the title of a
section in a literature survey of experiments on behaviour with respect to public goods by Ledyard
(1995). He concludes that the experiments show that people are neither20. Instead, a small minority of
people are unfailingly cooperative, a greater number are invariably selfish, while a majority exhibit
different behaviour in different circumstances, throwing doubt on one of the key assumptions of
neoclassical economics.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Islam takes a clear and definite stand on this issue, and suggests that the question itself is not wellposed. Every human being has the capability of being a saint, but even saints have base impulses and
the possibility of succumbing to temptation. Furthermore, human beings are essentially free, so their
past does not determine the future: the greatest of sinners can choose to become a saint, and vice
versa. Due to this plasticity and the essential freedom of human behaviour, the scientific method of
observation and theory construction is not well suited to the study of society. Instead, since human
behaviour responds to expectations and social norms, we are free to choose the type of society in
which we wish to live. If we promote that idea that human beings are naturally selfish, and that such
selfish behaviour leads to the best social outcomes, human beings will learn to behave selfishly21. In
fact, Islam teaches us that all children are born in Islam, which is the religion of nature (deen-ul-fitrah),
but that childhood training causes them to deviate from the natural path. This does not mean that
children are naturally cooperative and generous; rather, that the recognition and appreciation of
virtuous behaviour is built into their hearts. This makes it easy to train them to be good.
Use of the terms human capital, human resource development and development of job skills and
productivity as a means to progress highlight the currently dominant view of humans as an input to the
production process. This contrasts with the Islamic view that development of human beings is the goal
and production of resources etc. is only useful to the extent that it is a means to this goal; see for
example, El-Ghazali (1994).

3.2 Wealth and freedom


This concern with higher goals determines how the ends to be achieved by the use of economic
means are defined. A clear and comprehensive statement is provided by the Quran in verse Q28:77
cited above: Wealth is to be used to pursue the home of the hereafter (by doing things that will please
Allah). Since wealth has been given to us as a gift from Allah, we should also be generous in giving to
others. These principles resemble those promoted by other religions, although they stand in stark
contrast to conventional economics. Since property is a trust from Allah, we cannot do with it as we
please. Those who do not believe this, in contrast, are quoted as asserting that they have earned their
wealth through their own efforts and therefore have a right to do as they please with it:
(Q 11:87) They said: O Shuaib! Does thy religion command thee that we leave off
doing what we like with our property?

29

30

Working Paper 22

In particular, pursuit of luxurious lifestyles and the pleasures of this world is not the object of wealth:
the Quran condemns both the pursuit of idle desires (Q45:23) and emulation of luxurious lifestyles
(Q3:196). The modes of behaviour encouraged by Quranic injunctions are not primarily for the
economic welfare of society; that is a fringe benefit. Rather, behaving in these ways will bring people
closer to God, lead to spiritual development, and develop the potential within them to be better than the
angels.
Dissatisfaction with the results of the unconstrained pursuit of material wealth has led to substantial
reconsideration of the idea of development in the recent past. While many different approaches have
emerged, all emphasize the role and importance of human beings (relative to material wealth or
capital) in the development process. Putting an abstraction over material goals, Development as
Freedom by Sen (1999) is perhaps the most radical departure from conventional views amongst
economists. Sen advocates evaluating development in terms of human capacities and freedoms,
which has some resemblance to Muslim views. However, a major difference is pointed out by Ali
(1931) in Tareequl-Qalander; unlike Sen, he holds that real freedom is only given to people who have
freed themselves from base selfish desires others are just slaves to their egos/desires and are not
really free at all22.

3.3 Contrasting principles of Islamic and neoclassical economics


While other Western disciplines and heterodox economists have broader views, neoclassical
economists base their analysis of markets on cut-throat competition between selfish individuals. At the
heart of Islam is the promotion of cooperation between individuals who can be motivated to be
generous. This contrast can be displayed along three dimensions as principles which differentiate
Islamic and neoclassical economics.
1. In general, Islam stresses co-operation and harmony, and the spending of wealth and materials to
achieve this goal. This contrasts with the neoliberal economic vision of the free market as a jungle where
enterprises and people compete to achieve maximum wealth. Nevertheless, although the dominant
views have favoured individualism, competition and selfishness, many well-known economists have
wrestled with the conflict between these views and the value of social interests, community and
cooperation (see Ali Khan, 2004, for references and discussion).

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

2. Social interests take precedence over personal ones. The commons dispute in England was resolved
by enclosures, favouring private interests over public, and the rich over the poor. The same dispute was
resolved in the opposite way in the early Islamic era, by banning rich people with large herds from use of
the commons for grazing (see Zarqa, 1995; Hasanuzzaman, 1981; Mortazavi, 2004).
3. Intentions for actions in all domains, including the economic, are crucial. In contrast, Western
economists distrust internal states and strongly prefer to base their theories on observable behaviour.
Positivism, as interpreted by economists, suggests that only observable actions matter; the internal
states of satisfaction and motivations do not. For example, economists rely on observed choices, rather
than unobserved preferences, as a guide to consumer behaviour.
I will show how these contrasts differentiate between Islamic and neoclassical analyses of economic
behaviour in the many different domains to be discussed later.

3.4 Detached observation vs. passionate engagement


Reuben (1996) has described how conflicts between religion and science, as well as changing ideas
about the nature of science, led to the abandonment of the moral mission of building character in
American universities in the early twentieth century. In the process, social scientists abandoned the
role of activists and reformers working to bring about a better world in favour of the detached observer
role of the Baconian scientist. Unfortunately, as Nelson (2001) and many other authors have
remarked, social science is relevant only to the extent that it is concerned with human goals and
values. The effort to make social science value-free merely leads to the masking of political and
ethical commitments under various guises.
Because they have been hidden beneath apparently sterile mathematics, the values on which
neoclassical economics is based have not been subjected to examination. To evaluate the effects of
economic actions, neoclassical economists refer to a fairytale world populated entirely by cold,
calculating and callous people with no social feelings. In this world, everyone is perfectly informed
about all possibilities; there are no transaction, communication or transportation costs; and everyone
calculates, to the last penny, the actions which will be most beneficial to their selfish interests.
Economic policies are evaluated solely in terms of their effects on the wealth of these imaginary
individuals living in this never-never land. In social and political arenas, the wonders of this imaginary

31

32

Working Paper 22

world are idealized and promoted, and aggressive actions to change the world to bring it closer to this
ideal have been advocated and undertaken. The realization that it will never actually be achieved does
not discourage followers of this economic ideology from attempting to bring the world closer to their
dreams.
Because of the claims to positive status of western economics, the issue of whether Islamic
economics is positive or normative is often debated in the literature. In light of the earlier discussion, I
would assert that the answer is neither Islamic economics is transformative. It seeks to change
society, and all individuals within that society, towards an ideal. The previous paragraph responds to
the charge that Islamic economics is utopian by showing that neoclassical economics is dystopian. In
addition, history shows us that utopians and dreamers have often had a tremendous impact on human
lives.23 Since Islamic ideals have been realised in the past, Islamic views about society are not
utopian in the sense of being unrealistic. For example, Lopez (1976) documents the existence of a
vast and prosperous global network of commerce guided by Islamic law in the heyday of the Islamic
empire.
Compassion and concern for all human beings and passionate engagement in improving their lot is a
central teaching of Islam. The struggle to improve ourselves and our societies, and to overcome our
base desires, is the greater Jihad (while war is the lesser). Furthermore, it is part of Islamic teaching
that it is this struggle to change the world in ways pleasing to God that will generate knowledge:
Q29:69 As for those who strive in Us, We surely guide them to Our paths, and lo! Allah is with the
good.
The idea that Islamic economics is transformative resembles the Marxist concept of praxis Marxists
do not seek to study the world but to change it. There is a key difference, however. Muslims struggle
for justice, equitable economic outcomes, etc. because such struggles will bring about an inner
spiritual transformation. Thus the goal of the struggle is spiritual rather than material. Marxists
emphasize material outcomes to the extent that they suggest that ideals, philosophies, and visions are
conditioned by the material prospects of humanity. Islam denies this emphatically, and tells us of the
primacy and dominance of the spiritual over the material world. Human history bears witness to this
primacy, as demonstrated by numerous instances of men with vision who have changed the world
without any apparent material means of doing so. A prime example is that of our Prophet Mohammad

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

himself (may the peace and blessing of Allah be upon him), who changed the course of human history
solely by inspiring the people of the Arabian desert with a grand vision, without bringing about any
change in the material means at their disposal.
For Muslims, Islamic law, known as the Shariah, and the accompanying apparatus for deriving laws
(fiqh) from source materials, is the source of guidance for translating principles into practice and
provides a framework within which all activity, economic and other, should take place. The overall
framework for Islamic economics that is provided by Islamic law is discussed in Section 4 below.

33

34

Working Paper 22

4 The framework: Shariah or Islamic law


Q7:157 [The Prophet] who will enjoin upon them the doing of what is right and forbid them
the doing of what is wrong, and make lawful to them the good things of life and forbid
them the bad things, and lift from them their burdens and the shackles that were upon
them
Although the nearest translation of the Sharia is Islamic law, this is somewhat misleading, since the
Sharia covers all aspects of life from details of personal hygiene, to social organisation, permissible
and impermissible commercial transactions, rules for spiritual and emotional conduct, etc. An
accessible introduction can be found in Theories of Islamic Law: The Methodology of Ijtihad by Nyazee
(1994). Among the rules of the Sharia, many relate to economic life. Economic teachings from the
Quran have been collected in Maududi (1963, 1969) and more recently by Hasanuzzaman (1999). The
second source of Islamic law is the Sunnah, or reported sayings or activity of the Prophet (s.a.w.) or
his companions. These have been gathered in Economic Teachings of Prophet Muhammad, by
Akram Khan (1989). Fiqh is the name for the process of deriving rulings on situations not directly
covered from these basic sources of Islamic law. Fahim Khan (2002) discusses fiqh foundations of
the theory of Islamic economics. In this section, we will discuss only those aspects of Islamic law that
relate to collective economic activity, at the state or social level. Teachings related to individual
behaviour will be discussed separately, in Section 7.

4.1

Objectives of the Sharia

The primary sources of Sharia are the Quran and Sunnah. These contain rules and recommendations
on all aspects of individual and social life, dividing actions into three broad categories: farz
(compulsory), halal (permissible), and haram (prohibited). Within each category there are refinements,
subtleties and complexities; for example within the halal category, there are gradations from highly
recommended to highly disliked. The Quran states that Islam is a complete religion; hence, it is
axiomatic that all human actions fall within the scope of Islam. Extending the application of Islamic law
to a new situation is called ijtihad. Rules by which ijtihad is done (analogy to similar situations,
consensus, etc.) are called fiqh. Over the centuries, a large body of rulings covering applications of
Islamic law to different situations encountered in the historical experience of Muslims has emerged. I
will refer to the collectivity of these rulings as the Islamic tradition. This tradition covers a broad range
of issues, with sharp conflicts over some, and a wide range of positions adopted by different groups
over others. Despite diversity and conflicts, the tradition as a whole forms a harmonious collection of

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

rules broadly consonant with the spirit of Islam for a wide range of situations faced by humans both
individually and collectively. Islam also has a tradition of tolerance for dissent, so that conflicting
opinions may simultaneously be held to be acceptable Islamic solutions to a given problem. Walbridge
(2002) discusses this tradition of tolerance and its significance in Islamic history. Deeper and more
extensive discussions based on source materials are given in Zakariyya (1938) and Waliullah (1750,
conclusion of Part I).
Engaging in the struggle (jihad) to bring justice and good to the world, as prescribed by the Sharia, will
bring us closer to God, and lead to spiritual development, realization of the human potential within us,
and an increase in knowledge. Islamic law covers both external and internal actions. For example, to
be acceptable, the external act of giving money in charity must be accompanied by the intention of
pleasing God by doing so. The intention to be praised for generosity, or the feeling of superiority or
contempt for the poor, invalidates the act. This tension between the visible action and the invisible
intent has played an important role in many aspects of Islamic history. The ulama, or religious
scholars, have traditionally been concerned with external aspects, or the form, and have been content
to leave the invisible intentions to God. In contrast Sufis have focused on the desired conditions of the
heart or the spirit, sometimes to the neglect of form. These two groups have often been at odds with
each other24, although there have also been many individuals who have combined the best of both
traditions. Islamic history shows that exclusive focus on one or the other leads to an imbalance and
harmful outcomes.
The complexity of modern economies, and of modern life in general, has led to many situations not
covered by the tradition. Thus ijtihad to cover these new complexities of economic life is a central
issue in Islamic economics (and also in devising a suitable Muslim response to modernity in general).
Appropriate methods for ijtihad continue to be a source of substantial discussion and controversy
among Muslims. Modernist Muslims feel that the traditional rules of fiqh are not adequate to cope with
current complexities, and ask for freedom to reinterpret source materials so as to creatively adapt
them to modern conditions (instead of being bound by traditional rulings; i.e. Siddiqi, 2004a).
Traditionalists feel that existing fiqh is adequate to cope with new situations, and feel that excessive
freedom would amount to throwing out Islamic law altogether and caving in to modernity (Iftikhar
Zaman, 1985). Yousri (2004) advocates a careful middle ground.

35

36

Working Paper 22

In a seminal work, Shatibis Philosophy of Islamic Law, Masud (1995) has proposed a middle way that
remains within the Islamic tradition while allowing for the greater flexibility demanded by modernists.
Shatibi was an Islamic scholar in Muslim Spain who lived in a period of rapidly changing economic and
political conditions. Finding traditional formulations of fiqh inadequate, he analysed Islamic law to distil
the underlying philosophy of the law. Shatibi notes that it is universally agreed that the Shariah is not
an arbitrary collection of rules, but rather is designed to promote both the material and spiritual welfare
of human beings in the best possible way. Using the existing tradition to analyse this broad goal, one
can distil several specific objectives aimed at by the Shariah via a logical process. These objectives
include the preservation of life and property, and the welfare of descendants. In effect, Shatibi adds to
traditional fiqh an additional method that may be used to extend Islamic law to new situations.
By utilising the objectives of Islamic law, in conjunction with more specific and precise rulings of the
Shariah, one can derive many principles for Islamic economics. For example, we would not be able to
find analogues for fiscal and monetary policy in Islamic source materials, putting these issues outside
the scope of Islamic law at least according to traditional rules of fiqh. However, we may argue on the
basis of the source materials that the Prophet facilitated trade and business in many ways, and took
active steps to provide a means of earning a living to the unemployed. If we conclude that reducing
unemployment is an objective of the Shariah, then we may deduce that fiscal and monetary policy to
achieve this goal is recommendable according to Islamic law. In a similar way, one can argue that
price stabilization via monetary policy falls within the ambit of Islamic law. This methodology has been
advocated by numerous scholars in Islamic economics and elsewhere (for example Chapra, 1985;
Siddiqui, 2004a). In the remainder of this section, the Islamic law with respect to property, business
and labour is discussed.

4.2 Property rights


One of the major disputes between capitalism and communism was over the issue of whether the
means of production should be privately or publicly owned. Accordingly, early writers on Islamic
economics spent much time delineating an Islamic theory of property rights and differentiating it from
capitalist and communist theories. Siddiqi (1980) gives a succinct summary and essential references.
Maududi (1947, 1970) argues that capitalism leads to increasing concentration of wealth in the hands
of the owners of the means of production, which is harmful to society and against Islamic principles.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Communism, however, does not provide a solution, since government ownership in practice also
turns out be ownership by a small or limited group of people and in practice these are often more
tyrannical than private capitalists, who do not control the government. Islam provides a solution by
allowing private property but ensuring socially responsible behaviour on the part of owners of excess
wealth, by means of a number of mechanisms. Similar arguments have been formulated by a large
number of writers: Akram Khan (1983, 1991, 1998), in his extensive bibliographies, cites many
sources that systematically compare different economic systems to Islam.
Since the end of the Cold War, Islamic economists have discussed many other dimensions with
respect to which Islamic concepts of property differ from typical Western ones, and the difference this
makes for many socio-economic problems. Kahf (1998a) and Gulaid (1991) give detailed treatments25
and further references. In work commissioned by UN-Habitat, Sait and Lim (2006) explore Islamic
concepts of rights to land, as a means of providing secure access to land for the poor. They find that
Islamic property concepts form a sophisticated alternative to prevalent international norms (Sait and
Lim, 2005, Paper 1, p. 8):
Islam conceives of all property as a sacred trust but promotes private ownership with a
re-distributive ethos. Engagement with Islamic dimensions of land may potentially
support land rights initiatives in Muslim societies and has implications for programmes
relating to land administration, land registration, urban planning and environmental
sustainability.
We now elaborate on this brief but accurate sketch. While all of creation is originally and forever the
property of God, He created it for the benefit of human beings. People who utilize property to create
benefits become entitled to ownership, creating a type of private property. This private property is both
a trust from God, and a test, a conception that leads to a philosophy of property substantially different
from current Western notions26. Since property is a trust, the owner must utilize the property in ways
conducive to the common interest. For example, the property should not be destroyed or used in ways
that cause harm to the public. The idea that legitimate ownership gives a person the right to do as he
or she pleases with property is specifically and explicitly condemned in the Quran (Q11:87, cited
earlier). Similarly, property in excess of needs is regarded as a test, to see if human beings will use it
for the welfare of others, or for selfish/harmful purposes (Q68:17-27 describes people whose garden
was destroyed because they wanted to avoid giving from it to the poor). There is strong

37

38

Working Paper 22

encouragement to spend excess money on social welfare and equally strong discouragement of
accumulation and hoarding (which contrasts with the endless accumulation encouraged in capitalistic
societies). These basics of the Islamic theory of property are available in substantially greater detail
from numerous sources; see for example Kahf (1998a), Taseen (1998) or Sait and Lim (2006).
The fundamental Islamic concepts of property rights outlined above have far-ranging ethical and moral
consequences. Since the world has been created for the benefit of people, certain types of natural
resources cannot be owned privately, because private ownership would deprive the public of the
intended benefit. Most Islamic scholars hold that common lands, forests, lakes, rivers and minerals
(including oil) fall into this category. The government must hold such public property in trust and devise
mechanisms to allow the entire public to benefit from the property. As an example, water is a public
resource which is frequently and increasingly a subject of international disputes. Water Management
in Islam by Faruqui et al (2001) provides a comparison of Islamic law with international laws and
current approaches 27. These issues relate closely to ideas of sustainable development, which are
discussed in Section 6.5 below28.
A major source of injustice and oppression is concentration of wealth, often in the form of land. There
are large landholdings in many Muslim states, sometimes resulting from (possibly unjust) land grants
from colonizers, resulting in an extensive debate about property rights and limitations in Islamic law.
Hosseini (1988) has provided a literature review in the context of contemporary Iran. Mufti Shafi (1979)
discusses both the theory and the legitimacy of property ownership in India and Pakistan in the light of
historical circumstances. The majority opinion in these discussions is that there are no limits on
private property ownership, but that the state can repossess lands when required in the interests of
social justice for example, if they were acquired unjustly, or are needed for urgent and pressing
social needs of a deserving population. Siddiqi (1980) outlines the major positions taken in this
debate29. In the context of providing for the basic human right of secure access to property and
housing, Sait and Lim (2006) study the role of Islamic law in Muslim areas. They find that it has the
potential for empowering the needy, and for providing culturally sensitive solutions to many problems
of access, security and tenure of landholdings. They also find that Muslims are constructively engaged
in the process of creatively adapting Islamic law to deal with modern problems.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

The confidence that Western models provide ideal solutions to social, political, and economic
problems has often led to a disregard of traditional patterns. A foreign expert did not need to know
anything about local conditions and traditions, since these were merely obstacles to progress, defined
as the adoption of Western models (see Mitchell, 2002). Repeated failures of this approach, strong
local resistance to imposed and arbitrary interference by outsiders, and other aspects of changing
socio-political conditions have led to revisions and rethinking. It has come to be appreciated that
traditions emerge from complex interactions of religious ideals, cultural norms, historical and political
circumstances, and often embody solutions to a host of local problems based on historical
experience. Thus in the contemporary context, Sait and Lim (2005, Paper 2) write that
..land tenure concepts, categorisations and arrangements within the Islamic world are
multi-faceted, generally distinctive and certainly varied. This paper explores the sociohistorical context and development of Islamic land tenure regimes leading to the web of
tenure in contemporary Muslim societies. An appreciation of the historical context of land
tenure in Muslim societies and the range of land tenure forms contributes towards
development of authentic and innovative strategies for enhancing access to land and
land rights.

4.3 Islamic rules of business


Islamic laws about permissible transactions for trade, transfer of property and the ethical conduct of
business are quite detailed and form one of the strengths of Islamic economics. Explicit orders to fulfil
contractual obligations, recommendations to write down contracts, and exhortations to witnesses to
testify faithfully provide the basis on which the Islamic rules are built. Business Ethics in Islam by
Ahmad (1995) provides a comprehensive discussion relating practical aspects of business ethics to
the spiritual goals of Islam, while Pomeranz (1995) contains a brief discussion. The spiritual aspects
of business are covered very well in Zakariyya (1993). The Quranic verse below clearly specifies a
concern for fairness and justice over and above the idea that mutual consent of both parties is
sufficient to legitimise a trade:
Q4:29 O You who believe! Do not devour one anothers possessions wrongfully - not
even by way of trade based on mutual agreement

39

40

Working Paper 22

Ansari and Arshad (2006) provide a comparative study, with a detailed account of conventional
capitalist business ethics and how they relate to the emergence of capitalism and associated
philosophies in European history.
A key difference between Islamic and Western business ethics, which lies at the heart of the matter,
may be summarized as follows. In some European conceptions, morality is viewed as instrumental to
the procurement of freedom for individuals; freedom is also represented by wealth (which gives the
individual freedom to pursue his or her desires). More crudely, good ethics is good business. In
contrast, moral behaviour or the pursuit of virtue is the goal of an Islamic society, and the conduct of
business is also subordinated to this goal. In Islam, the value of any action is judged by its intention.
The dramatic contrast between the Islamic view and a western secular view may be illustrated by the
following Hadeeth:
A wealthy man will be called to account for his deeds on the day of Judgement. He will
say that I spent (wealth given by You) in all the ways that are pleasing to You. Allah will
say to him; You lie. You spent the wealth so that you may be called Generous (or
Virtuous or Charitable). You were so called (and there is no reward for you here). Then
the man will be sent to the Hellfire. Sahih Muslim, Book 3, Chapter 33: Al-Amarah,
Hadeeth 152.
Adopting integrity, supporting charitable causes and engaging in social welfare as a means of
enhancing company reputation and hence favourably impacting on that businesss bottom line is
explicitly condemned in Islamic teachings. Virtue must not be subordinated to making a profit. This is
also logical, since if morality is seen as a means of making money, then immoral behaviour will be
preferred if it leads to more money. This tendency can be illustrated by the actual ethical practices of
some Western businesses. For example, after learning that design defects in the Ford Pinto would
lead to deaths by burning in rear-end collisions, the Ford company calculated that the costs of a safety
recall would be more than the projected monetary value of death and dismemberment.
Islamic law as it relates to business is summarized in Mansoori (2005) and Nyazee (1997, 1998).
Akram Khan (1998, section 51:20) gives an annotated bibliography of about twenty articles related to
business organization and specific types of contracts within the framework of Islamic law (ijarah, hirepurchase, instalment sales, morabaha, modaraba, etc.). One of the key principles is that transactions
must be just, fair and equitable to both parties. One consequence is that transactions with gharar (a
large amount of uncertainty or ambiguity) are prohibited; Al-Dareer (1997) gives an extensive

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

discussion of this concept and its applications. For example, the sale of drilling rights for oil in
locations where there is large amount of uncertainty about the quantity of oil available is not
permissible in Islamic law30. Speculation, gambling and lotteries are not permissible for the same
reason (see Siddiqui, 1980, p 241, for a brief discussion and references to Islamic law sources). The
majority opinion is that insurance falls into the same category (see Atiquzzafar Khan, 2005). However,
in view of the economic utility of insurance, a minority view such a contract as acceptable within
Islamic law. Others have tried to devise alternatives to insurance that would comply with Islamic law.
This has been given the name of takaful, and will be discussed in Section 6.2 below.
A major area of difference between Islamic and conventional economics is the prohibition of interest.
Payment of extra money to owners of funds is unjust, since it does not reward any productive activity.
There is an enormous amount of literature on this issue. Siddiqi (2004b) gives a recent survey and
lists references. The debate on the exact scope of the Islamic injunction and whether or not it applies
to modern commercial interest has been resolved decisively in favour of the orthodox view that it does
apply; this contrasts with Europe, where the same debate occurred and was resolved in the opposite
manner see God and the Moneylenders: Usury and Law in Early Modern England by Norman Jones
(1989). The text of a judgement banning commercial interest written by the Shariat Appellate Bench of
the Supreme Court of Pakistan reviews and rebuts all the major arguments in favour of interest
(Usmani, 1999).
Another important set of writings addresses the issue of how to create Islamic banks that function
without interest. Ayub (2002) and Zaher and Hassan (2001) provide extensive surveys. The key
concept is that lenders must participate in the risks of business, in order to earn a reward. Thus
collateral for business loans cannot be seized in the event of business failure that is, Shylock cannot
get his pound of flesh if the ships of Antonio sink. In the literature, the technical aspects of Islamic law,
conventional banking functions, creation of suitable financial instruments, etc. tend to overwhelm the
main point, which is that Islamic laws and institutions are designed not to make profits but to promote
moral and spiritual growth. This aspect is discussed by Sait and Lim (2006), Faridi (1414H/1994),
Naylor (2007), Sachedina (n.d.) and others. Because of the conflict between Islamic spiritual
teachings and the risk-free profit-making attitudes of modern banks, some Muslims hold that the two
cannot be reconciled (for example, Vadillo, n.d.; Taseen, 2001; Ansari, 2000).

41

42

Working Paper 22

While commercial loans can be handled relatively easily, avoiding interest in microfinance, consumer
loans, mortgages, government projects and foreign debt requires different methods. Each must be
dealt with separately. Beginnings have been made in all. The potential for further work is reflected in
the following comment about Islamic microfinance, from Sait and Lim (2005, Paper 7):
Islamic jurisprudence (fiqh), with its emphasis upon partnership and a concern for
community welfare, together with the expansion in Islamic banking and microfinance,
has the ability to respond creatively to the needs of the urban poor.
The term financial engineering has been coined to deal with the issue of devising suitable financial
instruments that cater to a specific need while conforming to Islamic law - see Tariqullah Khan and
Munawar Iqbal (2005), and also Rosly (2005), for illustrations of the process for a wide range of
financial transactions.
Islamic law encourages spending on the poor and disadvantaged, based on the principle that money
that is not required to satisfy immediate needs should be spent on socially useful purposes (and not
saved or used to make more money). This is urged in numerous verses of the Quran and traditions
from the Prophet, for example Q2:219 They ask thee how much they are to spend; Say: What is
beyond your needs. This has implications for lending practices. Thus the Shariah encourages giving
loans to the needy, not pressing for repayment, giving extra time or waiving the loan when needed. All
these measures are designed to develop sympathy for those in need and a spirit of cooperation in
society (see Mufti Shafi, 1978, part 2, sections 10, 18, 19). In contrast, interest-based loans based on
collateral insulate the lender from the borrower, allowing the impersonal, self-interest based
transactions which are the basis of the capitalist system31. One can use financial engineering to
replace interest with Shariah compliant service charges, achieving conformity in form, but not in spirit,
to Islamic law. The quest to find suitable compromises which preserve the spirit of Islamic law while
being practicable in a society of ordinary human beings (not saints) is currently being carried out on
many different fronts in all Islamic societies.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

4.4 Labour
Azid (2005) surveys Islamic views of labour, while Egami (1990) and Rahman (1995) discuss labour
as worship, and suggest how such a view of labour can create meaning and motivation for work, in
contrast with the alienation and anomie in the capitalist system. Pfeifer (2006) also provides a
comprehensive survey of Islamic labour laws and how they have impacted on recent developments in
the Muslim world. She finds that Islamic rules about labour and how they have played out in Egypt,
Pakistan and Saudi Arabia have been influenced by the Islamic vision of society as a cooperative
enterprise. This contrasts with the competitive conception at the heart of the modern Western
economics. Manicas (1989) has argued that the transition in the West from a cooperative ideology
(which he terms polis) to a competitive one (termed societas) is one of the key transitions of
modernity.
As in all spheres of human relations, Islamic laws about labour are structured as interlocking sets of
complementary rights and responsibilities. The right of an individual to receive aid from society in
times of need derives from the persons responsibility to do the best to provide for him or herself (Said,
1972; Taseen, 1998). The Islamic work ethic is based on the idea that taking the property of another
unjustly is not permissible. A worker who shirks on the job earns a wage that is not justified, and this is
haram. This motivation for work is different from Webers (1930) Protestant work ethic. Workers
should be treated with dignity and respect, and equality maintained between employers and
employees in terms of their social status (in particular, clothing, housing and food). In contrast, in
capitalist societies, an employer generally has a higher status than workers, while in critiques of
capitalism, the capitalist is regarded as an exploiter who receives a financial reward for no work.
Islamic theory sees employer and employee as engaged in a cooperative enterprise, doing different
types of work but being accorded equal respect that is, entrepreneurial skills receive due recognition
in Islam, but are not given primacy. There is great emphasis on just treatment of workers, paying them
on time, not overworking or exploiting them, and not mistreating them in any way. Working conditions
should be safe from accidents and not damaging to the health of workers. There is general agreement
on these minimal rights of labourers, while some modern authors have found in Islamic teachings a
more extensive set of labourers rights, including vocational training and many other benefits. However,
these are disputed. Abdel Aziz (1992) has argued that social justice requires hiring the most
competent worker, even more so if that person is from a minority or disadvantaged group.

43

44

Working Paper 22

There is also a clear basis in Islam for profit-sharing schemes, although there is some dispute as to
the extent of sharing required. Some have argued (for example, Iqbal and Mirakhor, 2005) that labourowned firms would express the spirit of Islam, while others suggest that more flexibility in terms of the
preferred model for business organization is permissible. While there is dispute on details, there is no
dispute on the principle that Islamic ideals of justice and cooperation require a firm to share its good
times with its workers, just as it calls upon workers to make sacrifices during bad times.
The first wife of the Prophet was a businesswoman. Throughout Islamic history, many Muslim women
have owned property and have had the right to earn money. Islamic law also gives them the right to
inherit. These rights became available to European women only relatively recently. Iran has recently
passed a law entitling women to compensation for work done at home (childcare, cooking, etc.) the
husband is required to make such a payment in the case of divorce. This is based on the example of
the Prophet, who used to do housework, and Islamic law, which places responsibility for childcare and
housework on the husband, though some religious scholars have disputed the Iranian interpretation.
Pfeifer (2006) reviews the material discussed in this section, and provides a detailed study of how
theories in the realm of labour laws and the treatment of labour have played out in practice in Egypt,
Saudi Arabia and Pakistan. As usual in such studies, she finds that practices are conditioned by the
historical and cultural context and political considerations, as well as Islamic legal theory (which is
flexible and can be adapted to different purposes). Because pragmatic considerations substantially
constrain idealistic visions, both Muslim and non-Muslim cynics have argued that practice is
determined by the material realities, while visions, ideals and philosophies merely serve as window
dressing. However, Pfeifers earlier paper (2001) shows that Islamic firms in Egypt offer significantly
higher wages (and have lower profits) than comparable non-Islamic firms, which have higher profits
and lower wage shares. This and numerous other instances show that ideals influence practices,
even though pragmatic considerations and human failings may prevent a complete realization.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

5 Islamic states
Q22:41 (Allah will help) Those who, if We give them power in the land, establish regular
prayer and give regular charity, enjoin the right and forbid wrong.
The defining characteristic of an Islamic government is its subordination to the Sharia or Islamic law.
All principles of government to be discussed below derive from these laws, as well as historical
examples of their implementation by Islamic states. A government cannot legislate in areas where the
Sharia has provided laws32. These areas include inheritance, property rights (which also bear on
taxation), certain types of criminal law, etc. In other areas where the Sharia is silent, or else has laid
down only general guidelines, the state may legislate and operate within prescribed guidelines.
Citizens can (and are required by Islamic law to) refuse to obey the government in matters which are
against Islamic law obedience to God supersedes obedience to kings33. The judiciary, which (in
ambiguous cases) decides what is and is not against the Islamic law, is independent of the executive
body, and plays an extremely important role because of this status34. An essential feature to keep in
mind, stressed by many authors, is that an Islamic state is an effort to realise the spiritual by material
means through human organisation. For example, an early Islamic mirror for princes The Wisdom
that Conduces to Royal Glory by Yusuf Hajib (ca 1070) features a dialogue between a worldly-wise
man and an ascetic, and shows how to harmonize worldly wisdom with spiritual goals.

Below we

discuss some of the economic functions of the Islamic state, as mandated by Islamic law, including its
political organization, public finance, the judicial system, and economic security and welfare.

5.1 Political structure


Since an Islamic state came into existence during the lifetime of the Prophet (s.a.w.), Islamic theory of
the state is very well developed. The History of Islamic Political Thought: From the Prophet to the
Present by Antony Black (2001) provides a comprehensive survey.

5.1.1

Principles

Maududi (1960) discusses the basic principles of an Islamic state with a very concrete and practical
focus on creating a political framework for use in Pakistan and other Islamic countries. Summarizing
the views of one of the leading scholars of Islam, Usmani (1970) highlights three important issues:

The demands of struggles for liberation, and Islams emphasis on the rejection of secular thought, has
led some Muslims to over-emphasize the role of politics in Islam. Just as economics is a means to

45

46

Working Paper 22

achieve spirituality, Q22:41 (cited above) states that political control is a means to establish worship and
encourage good deeds.

Democracy emerged in Europe in response to historical experience of the evils of autocracy - personal
rule with unconstrained and arbitrary power. Europeans, and some Muslim followers, have generalized
from the European experience to assume that the forms of government that have evolved in
contemporary Europe (and even more recently North America) are the best models for all countries.
Islamic governments have personal rule, but with many checks and balances against the abuse of
power. In particular, a ruler is equal to his subjects before Islamic law. Rule (or leadership) is regarded as
a responsibility not a privilege. A ruler must be chosen on merit, be of exceptional character, and may be
removed for incompetence.

Since political control is a means to an end, only Islamically permissible means may be used to achieve
it. Currently, many of the methods being used by Muslims for political struggle are not permissible in
Islam. Some Muslims have argued, incorrectly, that such methods are permissible because they are
required for success. Several historical examples of how Muslims have sacrificed political success in
the interest of religious goals can be identified. For example, Mu50 4- wyah ibn Ab Sufyn, the
fifth Caliph of Islam, recalled his armies from a surprise attack (which had a very high likelihood of
success) upon learning that such a tactic was not permissible Islamically in the particular situation he
faced, immediately after expiry of a peace treaty.

5.1.2 The Ummah


Generally, government has come to be associated with the nation state. However, of relevance to the
theme of this paper is the idea, stressed in Islam, that Muslims form one community or Ummah. This
conflicts with modern concepts of the nation-state, which formulate governing arrangements on the
basis of geographical partition. The as yet unresolved tension between the concept of the Ummah and
the concept of nation has played out in many different ways in Muslim political arenas (see, for
example, Piscatori, 1986). One example is Mustafa Kemal Ataturks explicit choice of the modern
identity of a Turkish nation and his aggressive promotion of it in preference to the more general Islamic
identity of the Ottoman Empire. Although there have been attempts amongst Muslim countries to
promote closer political, social and economic ties with each other in line with the concept of Ummah,
events such as the separation of East and West Pakistan and the modest success of other initiatives

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

is an indication of the current weakness of such international religio-political ties. Yousri (2004)
discusses attempts at economic integration among Muslim countries and their relation to Islamic law
and the Ummah.

5.1.3

Decision-making processes

Arguably, the fundamental political problem is group decision-making in the absence of consensus and
in the presence of conflicting interests. The main process of decision- making in an Islamic society is
shoora or consultation. This was the practice of the Prophet Mohammad (s.a.w.) and is explicitly
mandated in the Quran, which describes believers as being
(Q42:38) Those who hearken to their Lord, and establish regular Prayer; who (conduct)
their affairs by mutual Consultation; who spend out of what We bestow on them for
Sustenance.
Usmani and Shafi (1976) and Ali (1997) contain detailed discussions of shoora, derived from original
sources and Islamic historical references. In shoora all members are encouraged to think about what
is best for the group as a whole, in preference to the interests of individuals or subgroups. This
creates a participatory form of government that differs in important ways from democracy, which often
caters to the interests of the largest subgroup and tends to generate conflicts. Shoora, like other
Islamic institutions and practices, is intended to create consensus and harmony within an Islamic
community35.

5.1.4 Citizens rights and responsibilities


An Islamic government must provide to its citizens justice, security, freedom, and equity in all spheres:
Q16:90 Allah commands justice, the doing of good, and generosity to fellow men, and He
forbids all shameful deeds, and injustice and rebellion:
In return, citizens are expected to obey the state authorities, except in cases where its orders are
contrary to Islamic law.
Q4:59 O ye who believe! Obey Allah, and obey the Messenger, and those charged with
authority among you. If ye differ in anything among yourselves, refer it to Allah and His
Messenger, if ye do believe in Allah and the Last Day: That is best, and most suitable for
final determination.

47

48

Working Paper 22

The preferred mechanism for the selection of a ruler is more like an electoral college (termed ahl-ulhall-wal-aqd) than direct election. Members of the electoral college must satisfy certain conditions, but
need not be bound to vote in any particular way. This same body may also be given the power to
remove a ruler for incompetence or other (serious) reasons. Detailed discussion with reference to
source materials is given by Ali (1997). Conditions in which revolt or rebellion are considered justifiable
(under oppressive rulers) have received extensive discussion by Islamic jurists as well as more
practically oriented politicians of the twentieth century. The principles of Islamic government require
guarantees of freedom of religion and belief, freedom of worship, freedom of movement, freedom of
expression, equality of opportunity, and the right to benefit from public services. Maududis The Islamic
Law and Constitution (1960) contains an extensive discussion.
Historically, Islamic civilizations have displayed much greater tolerance and provided much greater
freedom to minorities than has ever been achieved in the West. In particular, the concept of allowing
minorities personal law that is separate from the overall law of the state arguably achieves a level of
freedom for subcultures that is greater than in many other countries. Menocal (2002) and Lowney
(2005) describe Medieval Muslim Spain, and Akyol (2004, 2006) the Ottoman Empire, while Toynbee
(1951) wrote: The extinction of race consciousness as between Muslims is one of the outstanding
moral achievements of Islam. In the contemporary world there is, as it happens, a crying need for the
propagation of this Islamic virtue of tolerance and peace. In the Human Development Report:
Cultural Liberty in Todays Diverse World by Sakiko Fukuda-Parr (2004), the provision of cultural
liberties (of the type provided historically in Islamic civilizations) is presented as one of the pressing
needs of the world.

5.2 Public finance


Since an Islamic state came into existence in the lifetime of the Prophet (s.a.w.), objectives of public
expenditure that are legitimate according to Islamic law and legitimate means of raising revenue have
been the subject of discussion among Muslim scholars from the earliest times. Indeed, this is what is
traditionally meant by Islamic economics. This discussion, which delineates legitimate activities for a
Muslim state, and also imposes constraints on the generation of revenues and use of financial
resources, is at the heart of any conceptualisation of a modern Muslim state. Aghnides (1961) and
Siddiqi (1948) provide a comprehensive discussion of the theories and some history of early

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

administrative structures. A brief survey of modern authors is given in Ziauddin (1992). Several articles
in Readings in Public Finance in Islam edited by Gulaid and Abdullah (1995) provide more complete
discussions of the issues discussed briefly below. Financing Public Expenditure: An Islamic
Perspective by Munawar Iqbal and Tariqullah Khan (2004) provides another survey of the area, with a
very practical focus on the problems currently facing Islamic countries.

5.2.1

Revenues

Justification for any method of raising revenue for the state must be found in Islamic source materials,
which include the methods used in the period of the Khilafat-e-Rashida. Of these traditional methods,
four retain the greatest contemporary relevance. The first is zakat and ushr, which are dues on the
wealthy meant primarily for the alleviation of poverty, and ranging between 2.5 per cent and 20 per cent
for different categories of property. The rates and the potential uses of this revenue are directly
specified in Islamic law, so that a state cannot appropriate this money for other uses. Because of its
potential importance in poverty reduction, it is discussed in more detail below. The second method is a
land tax (kharaj), which is quite flexible and may be used by a state for many possible purposes. The
third method is revenue from taxing or renting natural resources, or from management of other forms
of public trust properties. The fourth is customs duties imposed on imports, in retaliation for similar
charges being imposed on Muslim traders. Most traditional Islamic scholars hold that the government
may impose no taxes other than those that are sanctioned by the tradition36.
Taxation policy in an Islamic economy by Kahf (1995b) provides an able exposition of the traditional
view, with reference to source materials. Since ownership of private property is a right of the individual
granted by Islamic law, forcibly alienating this property by taxation is not permissible except where
explicitly sanctioned by Islamic law. Thus arbitrary taxes for arbitrary purposes cannot be imposed by
a government. Many modern scholars are in favour of giving governments a large number of duties in
order to achieve development objectives, stabilize business cycles, provide social services,
redistribute income, etc. In conformity with this broad conception of government responsibilities, they
also favour giving broader powers of taxation to governments to allow for financing of these larger
projects. The Islamic Welfare State and its Role in the Economy by Chapra (1995) provides a clear
exposition of this view. Traditional scholars object to giving such a wide range of responsibilities to
governments, not finding any sanction for them in the traditions of Islam. A via media is proposed by

49

50

Working Paper 22

Ziauddin (1992), who suggests that if a society chooses (by consultation) to allocate a particular
responsibility to the government, then it would acquire the required religious sanction to legitimise
taxation for this specific purpose. Iqbal (1995), Sait and Lim (2006), Kahf (2000) and others have
noted that traditionally, welfare activities by the public have adequately provided for food, health,
education and other needs, so that in the past Islamic states did not have to provide for these needs.
As discussed elsewhere, this reliance on individual responsibility for welfare and social service
provision seems most in conformity with the Islamic tradition, in which the object of government is not
the provision of social services as such, but the creation of a cooperative spirit, compassion and
harmony. These can only be achieved by encouraging the public to take responsibility for provision of
services in their communities.
Zakat is one of the five pillars of Islam, as well as a pillar of public finance for an Islamic state. It is an
annual payment ranging from 2.5 per cent to 20 per cent of the value of specified types of property
owned by the wealthy, with the primary object of alleviating poverty. It is a clear illustration of the use of
wealth to pursue spiritual goals, since it is explicitly intended to create sympathy with and compassion
for the poor amongst the wealthy. Despite its resemblance in form, some Islamic scholars object to
the word tax for the payment of zakat, since its payment is regarded as a form of worship.
Historically, Islamic governments have collected zakat from the rich and distributed it to the needy.
Because of its religious nature, it is easy to collect, except when the public does not trust the
government to deliver it to the designated recipients. When governments do not collect and distribute
it, Muslims are individually responsible for finding the needy and distributing the zakat to them. They
are encouraged to prioritize first their next-of-kin, then the local community, and then the population
more generally. Where institutions are weak and levels of trust low, most zakat funds are distributed
individually by Muslims, based on personal searches for where the funds are most needed.
Because of its fundamental importance in Islam, zakat has been the subject of extensive research.
Islahi (2004) has prepared a bibliography listing over 250 references on all aspects of zakat, from
administrative to spiritual, including case studies of Islamic countries. Patterns of giving by the
Pakistani community in the USA are documented in Najam (2007), and substantial additional research
along these lines is under way. Literature reviews and assessment of the potential of zakat for poverty
relief are given by Ahmed (2004) and Shirazi (2006). Disregard of attention to local detail and the one

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

size fits all approach to poverty reduction of the IMF and World Bank, which has been critiqued by
Stiglitz in numerous articles and books37, is well illustrated by the case of zakat. Despite its centrality
in Islam, its specific designation as a poverty alleviation measure and its appeal to Muslims, zakat is
not, to my knowledge, mentioned in poverty reduction programmes designed by the World Bank for
Muslim countries. A large amount of work on how to revitalise this key Islamic institution, adapt it to
modern conditions, and make it more effective as a means of poverty elimination, is referenced in
Islahi (2004).

5.2.2

Responsibilities and expenditure

The responsibilities and functions of the Islamic state define categories of state expenditure that are
legitimate according to Islamic law. In addition to public administration, the state is expected to provide
justice to all (citizens and others worldwide), ensure security (including law enforcement and
defence), look after citizens physical welfare by taking care of their needs, and provide for an equitable
distribution of wealth and economic opportunities. The state is also required to look after the spiritual
welfare of citizens by playing an active role in promoting the good and prohibiting the evil, as mandated
in the Quran (Q22:41, cited earlier).
In the Economic Role of the State in Islam, Kahf (1991) describes these functions and their
implications for the economic role of the state. One subtle and important issue that he brings up is the
following: while asceticism, simplicity and other-worldliness are considered desirable personal goals,
they are not to be imposed on others the state and individuals are not permitted to duck their
economic responsibilities towards others in the name of promoting simple lifestyles or asceticism.
The debate over the functions and responsibilities of the state, summarized in Ziauddin (1992), has
some parallels to, but also some striking differences from the analogous debate between
conservatives and liberals in the west. First, it is a collective responsibility (farz-e-kifayah) of a Muslim
society to take care of the basic needs of all its members (including health, education, and provision of
opportunities for employment). Farz-e-kifayah is a special type of religious duty or obligation which
does not, to the best of my knowledge, have an equivalent or analogue in Christianity or in secular law.
If the duty is being fulfilled (in this case, the basic needs of all the members of the group are being
met), then all are absolved of this responsibility. If the duty is not being fulfilled, then all members of the
society are individually responsible to take care of whatever part they can. Responsibility is
proportional to capability those more capable of fulfilling the duty are more accountable. Since

51

52

Working Paper 22

typically the state has a lot more capability than individuals, any gaps in the fulfilment of basic needs
are the responsibility of the state. To the extent that private initiatives fail to meet this responsibility, the
state is required to step in to fill the gap. At the same time, when a state fails to fulfil this obligation, the
responsibility falls to individual citizens. A state can also be sued in an Islamic court to provide the
required services. Each of the major responsibilities of the state and its implications for economic
affairs is discussed separately below.

5.3 Justice
Islamic scholars agree that the provision of justice on all fronts is one of the main functions of an
Islamic state. Economic affairs are to be managed so as to provide social and economic justice to
citizens. There is a large literature on how the broad concept of justice translates into specific
socioeconomic and political goals; see for example Islam and Justice, edited by Aidit Ghazali (1993).
Kusha (1989) considers the political dimensions in Social Justice: From the Islamic World-System to
the European World-Economy, a Study of Power Legitimation. In the economic realm, it is quite clear
from Islamic source materials that economic justice does not mean equality of wealth and/or income.
Rather, it implies the provision of education, training, employment and equal access to economic
opportunities, as well as justice. This is discussed in greater detail in section 5.4 below.
The standards of justice required of human beings by Islam are extremely high. Muslims are required
to bear witness, even if it is against their own self-interest:
Q4:135 O ye who believe! stand out firmly for justice, as witnesses to Allah, even as
against yourselves, or your parents, or your kin, and whether it be (against) rich or poor:
for Allah can best protect both. Follow not the lusts (of your hearts), lest ye swerve, and if
ye distort (justice) or decline to do justice, verily Allah is well- acquainted with all that ye
do.
It is worth noting that such a requirement was considered too much to ask by the framers of the USA
constitution, and the Fifth Amendment allows people to abstain from bearing witness against
themselves. Similarly, Muslims are required to be just, even against an enemy:
Q5:8 O ye who believe! stand out firmly for Allah, as witnesses to fair dealing, and let not
the hatred of others to you make you swerve to wrong and depart from justice. Be just:
that is next to piety: and fear Allah. For Allah is well-acquainted with all that ye do.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

The Nuremberg trials show how difficult it is match this standard: while German war crimes were
punished, similar acts by the Allies were ignored38. Justice is regarded as a minimal requirement
Muslims are encouraged to forgive and be generous. Thus when the Prophet marched victoriously into
Mecca, he did not take revenge on the enemies who had persecuted him and his companions with
great vigour and over a long period of time. He set standards of behaviour for Muslim armies, many of
which have replicated this behaviour. For example, when Salahuddin Ayubi reconquered Jerusalem in
1187, he took no revenge on the Crusaders for their earlier massacres of the populace; instead he
housed and fed them, and provided them with ships to take them back to their countries of origin. See
also Feldman (2003) for testimony on the generally superior behaviour of Muslim conquering armies.
We note that the idea of competition versus cooperation, one of the core differences between the
capitalist and Islamic economic systems, is reflected even in the domain of justice. The explicit
command that Muslims must, if necessary, testify even against our own best interests, and be just
even to enemies, shows that we are all supposed to cooperate to arrive at a just outcome,
disregarding our personal interests. In contrast, in the US legal system, justice is an incidental byproduct of a mediated struggle between opposing interests. An excellent discussion of the ethical
issues is given by a panel of lawyers in A case of competing loyalties in Stanford Magazine (Fall
1983, p38-43). All on the panel agreed that a lawyer defending a male client known to him or her to be
guilty of rape nonetheless is obliged to destroy the reputation of the female victim if this is the best
possible defence. All agreed that the American criminal defence system is an adversarial process with
artificial boundaries, rather than a pure search for truth.
Historically, Islamic states were equipped with a range of institutions that could be coordinated and
harmonized to deliver justice in a way that is, even now, unparalleled. Naz (1999) has discussed these
institutions and their sphere of operations, providing some history and additional references. Islamic
scholars are agreed on the idea that justice delayed is justice denied, and there is great emphasis on
speedy resolution of cases. The list of institutions given below should give the reader an idea of the
framework for provision of justice in an Islamic state.

The Khalifa, or Governor, was often a last court of appeal. Through much Islamic history, people were
given easy access and special times to take their cases to the Khalifa, in accordance with early Islamic
traditions.

53

54

Working Paper 22

The Mufti or interpreter of Islamic law. While this was a purely scholarly position, with no immediate
executive powers, Masud (1995) has shown how the faqihs, or scholars of Islamic law, wielded great
power and enjoyed tremendous respect in early Islamic societies.

The Kadi or judge decided cases. The Islamic system is not adversarial in nature, and several examples
show that there is an emphasis on achieving a solution that is viewed as just by all parties. There are no
lawyers, although the judge may consult specialists in Islamic law and call witnesses or other interested
parties as necessary to arrive at a just outcome. There was an emphasis on speedy resolution of trials.

The institution of hisbah dealt with violations of justice in situations where there was no particular
aggrieved party or conflict of interests which would lead to a court case. In general, hisbah protected
social interests. For example, pollution or other cases which are dealt with under class action law in
some countries would, in Islamic states, have been handled by hisbah. Since hisbah also dealt with
regulation of markets and consumer protection, it is closely related to the economic realm and is
therefore treated separately in Section 6.4.

Diwan-ul-Mazalim, or the Court of Abuse, dealt with cases of the abuse of power. Here complaints
against powerful officials could be brought by ordinary citizens. Because of difficulties in prosecuting
such cases under normal procedures, this court was often given powers outside the normal juridical
ones, and could proceed in the absence of standard types of required evidence.

This recapitulation of traditional Islamic institutions does not stem from a desire to glorify or
romanticize the past. It is clear that solutions to modern problems will require creative thinking and
adaptation. Western political, social and economic institutions represent a solution to these problems
which is strongly conditioned by a worldview and a history substantially different from that of Muslim
countries. Contrary to what is widely believed, Western institutions are not universally applicable, and
in particular, are not suited to the Islamic ethos. This makes it necessary to study history to find
patterns of solutions consonant with Islamic traditions that can serve as a basis for new types of
Islamic institutions.

5.4 Economic security and welfare


As discussed earlier, a Muslim society must collectively take care of the basic needs of all its
members, including health, education, food, housing and provision of opportunities for employment. In
Guarantee of a Minimum Standard of Living in an Islamic State, Siddiqi (1995) gives a comprehensive
survey and further references relevant to most of the matters discussed in this section. It is important

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

to note that the first responsibility of an individual is to fulfil his or her own basic needs; only those who
are handicapped or temporarily unable to tend to their own needs are entitled to be assisted by others.
There are a large number of Islamic laws which relate to provision of economic security for the
disadvantaged. A comprehensive account is given in Economic Security in Islam by Qardawi (1981).
As discussed by Zarqa (1995, Section 4.3 (e)) and Siddiqi (1995, Section 2), recognition of this
responsibility goes back to the earliest times of Islam. The second Khalifa of Islam, Umar said to a
non-Muslim citizen who had paid taxes when young that he was entitled to be provided for in old age.
The first state-run hospitals and orphanages, as well as pensions for widows, the handicapped and
older people, were established in his time. Khalifa Umar bin Abd al Aziz is reported to have wept with
the worry that he was responsible for and would have to answer to God about the hungry, the poor,
the unattended sick, the prisoner in alien lands, the very old, those with many dependents but little
money, and similar people. Syed Abul Hassan Ali Nadvi (1986) writes that the idea of collective
responsibility for the needs of the entire world is one of the gifts of Islam to the civilizations of the
world.
Maududi (1960, p. 331) reports that a group of eminent Islamic scholars agreed to the following item
as essential for the constitution of an Islamic state: It shall be the responsibility of the Government to
guarantee the basic necessities of life, i.e., food clothing, housing, medical relief and education to all
citizens without distinction of race or religion, who might be temporarily or permanently incapable of
earning their livelihood due to unemployment, sickness or other reasons. Provision of economic
security will protect life, create goodwill and harmony in society, provide equality of opportunity, and
rectify many injustices. Economic security will also free individuals to turn to higher spiritual and
social pursuits. Hasanuzzaman (1980), Chapra (1993) and Taseen (1998) discuss these goals. Note
that these motives for the provision of economic security are radically different from standard secular
ones, which are based on utilitarian or Rawlsian principles. In The Islamic state and the welfare state:
similarities and differences, Kahf (1995a) discusses the concept of the welfare state as it arose in the
West and distinguishes it from the superficially similar Islamic conception.
Siddiqi (1995) gives a careful discussion of basic needs, citing sources and precedents, and also
indicating how these needs may be related to social norms, climate and other factors. The

55

56

Working Paper 22

mechanism by which Islamic societies are to look after these needs has also been spelled out. In the
first instance, as noted above, every individual is responsible for looking after himself and his family. If
a person is unable to do so, then it is expected that his or her kinfolk will take responsibility. If this does
not suffice, then neighbours and people in the near community have the responsibility. All members of
a society who have more than enough for their needs are exhorted to look after the less fortunate.
Muslims throughout the ages have responded to this call by setting aside large amounts of property
and wealth in trusts for social welfare projects (waqf; plural awqaf, discussed in Section 6.3). If an
individual slips through these social security nets, it is then, as discussed above, the responsibility of
government to provide for the unmet needs. Interestingly, this includes paying off the debts of the
indigent, which is a religious obligation. Thus the government is the insurer of debts for all citizens.
The issue of sufficiency has also been discussed by Siddiqi (1995). If resources are inadequate to
meet all the needs, then the community must prioritize according to guidelines prescribed by the
Shariah. As a last resort, a community may pool its resources and share them equally. It is narrated
that Umar R.A. said
If I had no money left to feed the people, and the only way left was to make all
households share their provisions with an equal number, with everyone being only half
fed till Allah gave us rain, I would have done so. For men could still survive on only half
the food they need.
In Islamic history, there are a number of reported cases of this last resort solution, which shows how
community needs are prioritised over individual needs. While a detailed discussion of this issue is
deferred to Section 7, we parenthetically note that it is an explicit Islamic injunction to provide for the
poor in an honourable way. In contrast, early poorhouses in England were designed to be shameful
and degrading, so as to give people little incentive to stay; such an approach is prohibited in Islam.
Among the basic needs, education deserves special attention. It is the route to equal opportunity. It
also plays a special role because it is an excellent channel through which the collective responsibility
of the state and citizens to provide for peoples moral development can be fulfilled. Islamic teachings
place extremely high importance on education. The first lines of the Quran revealed to the Prophet
state Read, in the name of thy Lord. Learning is from the cradle to the grave, according to the
Prophet. The angels were told to prostrate themselves before Adam after he displayed knowledge that
they did not possess. Writing about the culture of learning which arose in early Islam, as evidenced by

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

libraries, a variety of educational institutions, and many schools of thought of Islamic law, etc., Kazmi
(2005) states that, for an early Muslim to be a Muslim and not be interested in learning would [have
been] a contradiction in terms. Because education was considered a religious duty, and Muslims are
not permitted to charge money for performance of religious duties, in Islamic civilizations, education
was generally available to the rich and poor, as well as women and minorities. This provided for equal
opportunities for all in a way that has rarely been matched. Shalaby (1954) gives a history of
educational methods, syllabi, institutions, libraries, the inclusion of women, and other evidence of the
prevalence of education in the first 600 years of Islamic civilization. Makdisi (1990) details the rise of
institutions of higher education in Islamic civilization, and Goody (2007) documents both their imitation
in Europe, and the suppression of this information in historical accounts. Dalrymple (2006, p 95)
writes about the early period of British India that He [the Muslim man] who holds an office worth
twenty rupees a month commonly gives his sons an education equal to that of a prime minister.
After seven years of study, the young Muhammadan [is nearly the equal of] a young man raw
from Oxford. In Education in Pakistan, Qureshi (1975, p13-20) details how British colonial
educational reforms and restrictions on access to jobs led to a public education system based on lowstandard rote learning, which continues to impact adversely on educational standards in Pakistan.

5.5 Other functions of an Islamic state


In this sub-section, some of the functions that have been proposed for Islamic states, but about which
there is more controversy, are discussed. A first area of controversy, related to the welfare standards
discussed above, is the issue of the level of support for which the state is responsible. Kahf (1995a)
argues that the state is responsible only for the bare minimum necessary: adequate and comfortable
levels of support may only be provided if sufficient public funds are available. Since provision of
support above the bare minimum is not considered a responsibility of the state, it may not levy taxes to
provide such support. Other authors have argued for a broader concept of state responsibility, and
therefore also favour more extensive tax policy. Ziauddin (1992) summarizes the different points of
view and discusses the related issue of exactly how to differentiate between basic/essential needs
and less essential ones. Some authors have argued that this is not an important debate, since
historically the state has not needed to provide for meeting basic needs. Instead, the historical pattern
in Islamic societies was the free provision of education and health by private sector organisations
(awqaf) see M. Iqbal (1995) and Sait and Lim (2006).

57

58

Working Paper 22

While it is clear that Islam places a collective responsibility on a society for the fulfilment of the basic
needs of all its members, it is equally clear that the religion does not ask for equalization of incomes or
wealth. The Quran states that:
Q 43:32 Is it they who would portion out the Mercy of thy Lord? It is We Who portion out
between them their livelihood in the life of this world: and We raise some of them above
others in ranks, so that some may command work from others. But the Mercy of thy
Lord is better than the (wealth) which they amass.
Thus God Himself has created inequality of incomes for a purpose. Measures of income inequality
such as the Gini coefficient are, therefore, not of interest as measures of conformity between income
distribution and Islamic ideals. However, a different matter, the circulation of wealth, is directly
commanded by God:
Q59:7 What Allah has bestowed on His Messenger (and taken away) from the people of
the townships,- belongs to Allah,- to His Messenger and to kindred and orphans, the
needy and the wayfarer; In order that it may not (merely) make a circuit between the
wealthy among you. So take what the Messenger assigns to you, and deny yourselves
that which he withholds from you. And fear Allah, for Allah is strict in Punishment.
What emerges from this is that the wealthy are encouraged to spend, so that their wealth may
circulate freely in a society. Note how this is exactly the opposite of primogeniture, with its concern for
keeping wealth and lands concentrated. A number of moral concerns are addressed by this approach:
the rich are encouraged to be generous, to be grateful to God for his favours (rather than proud of their
acquisitive skills), and to promote the welfare of society by actively seeking out socially useful causes.
Measures to promote circulation of wealth within a society include zakat, sadaqat and inheritance laws
(see, for example, Mufti Shafi, 1978; Taseen, 1993; Siddiqi, 1980; Zarqa, 1995 and Anjum, 1995).
I conclude by noting an important tension created by the responsibility of a state to realize the spiritual
by material means, as made explicit in verse Q22:41 cited at the beginning of this section. Enjoining
the right means motivating people to do good deeds. A state which efficiently takes care of all the
needs of the public can be counterproductive in that it may relieve people of their responsibility and
promote indifference to others. Thus the primary objective of public policy is the creation of
cooperation, sympathy and generosity, rather than the elimination of poverty. To this end, the best
course of action is to encourage citizens to take on those responsibilities that they can shoulder, and

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

for governments to step into the gaps as the last resort. However, states also have direct
responsibilities towards their citizens. There is a fine line to be drawn between the two sets of
responsibilities, and Muslim authors can be found on both sides.

59

60

Working Paper 22

6 The role of Islamic institutions


Q2:177 True piety does not consist in turning your faces towards the east or the west but truly pious is he who believes in God, and the Last Day; and the angels, and
revelation, and the prophets; and spends his substance - however much he himself
may cherish - it - upon his near of kin, and the orphans, and the needy, and the wayfarer,
and the beggars, and for the freeing of human beings from bondage; and is constant in
prayer, and renders the purifying dues; and [truly pious are] they who keep their
promises whenever they promise, and are patient in misfortune and hardship and in time
of peril: it is they that have proved themselves true, and it is they, they who are
conscious of God.
There are certain uniquely Islamic institutions, based directly on Islamic law and/or well-established
historical Islamic practices, which have a strong influence on economic structures within an Islamic
society or state. Many of these institutions became defunct or marginalized in a long and complex
historical process of decay. The modern expectation that all societies will travel along the same path,
so that the Islamic heritage is only of historical value, has proven to be unfounded. An active search to
rediscover the spirit of Islamic institutions and revive them is going on in the Islamic world (the Quranic
verse cited above shows that the spirit is of the essence while the form can vary). There is also the
challenge of adapting them to contemporary requirements, or creating new institutions which conform
to Islamic laws while meeting modern needs. It is the tension between Islamic ideals and goals and
the existing unsatisfactory mlanges of colonial/modern /Islamic structures which gives impetus to
Islamic movements all over the world. Below we treat Islamic financial institutions, insurance, waqf
(trusts or endowments), hisbah or market regulation and environmental protection in separate
sections.

6.1 Islamic financial institutions


Given the clear textual prohibition of interest in Islam and the centrality of interest-based transactions
in modern capitalist economies, the first practical challenge in implementing an Islamic economic
system is the development of alternatives to interest. There is a huge amount of literature on this topic;
a recent survey has been undertaken by Siddiqi (2004b). There are three routes to a resolution, as we
discuss below.
Route 1: The simplest way out of the problem is to argue that modern banking interest is not the form
of interest that is prohibited in the Quran. This route, the equivalent to that chosen by Christians and
Jews, has not been accepted by the vast majority of Muslims, even though several attempts have

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

been made in this direction - see Usmani (1999) for a rebuttal of all the main arguments. Among many
reasons for this divergent outcome, it appears to be significant that Muslims continue to believe that
the Quran is the revealed word of God, and that the traditions encapsulated in the Hadeeth are
fundamentally sound. Jones (1989) shows that a re-interpretation of restrictions on usury as being
metaphorical rather than literal was a key step in legitimizing interest in the Christian world.
Route 2: The second route is to find equivalents of existing modern institutions which serve the same
functions and are compatible with Islamic law. This has been the most popular route, for reasons to be
discussed. Ayub (2002) and Zaher and Hassan (2001) provide extensive discussion of the issue of
how to create Islamic banks that can function without interest. Another useful and comprehensive
reference is The Encyclopedia of Islamic Banking and Insurance (IIBI, 1992). Tariqullah Khan and
Munawar Iqbal (2005) refer to the design of financial instruments that fulfil the functions of Western
institutions while being Shariah compliant as financial engineering. There are striking parallels
between this route and the ones adopted by Christians en route to the abandonment of the prohibition
of usury and its associated moral stigma - see Norman Jones (1989) God and the Moneylenders:
Usury and Law in Early Modern England.
Route 3: A third set of authors (for example, Ansari, 2000 and Taseen, 2001), believe that Islamic
institutions are radically different from existing capitalist structures, and that it will require a revolution
to put such structures in place. In fact, most Muslims agree that Muslim institutions differ radically
from their non-Muslim counterparts, but differ on the appropriate strategy for how to get from here to
there. The second route (discussed in the previous paragraph) is a way of making evolutionary
changes and modifications to existing western financial institutions and practices, to get rid of the
most egregious violations of Islamic laws and begin to develop an economic system that resembles
an Islamic system. Proponents of the revolutionary approach (e.g. Hafiz and Mahbub-al-Hassan, 2006)
believe that such methods cannot work and that settling for less than an ideal approach will frustrate
the revolutionary intent of Islamic methods. The basic ideas of the third approach and its application to
insurance in an Islamic framework are spelled out most clearly in the introduction to the third chapter
of Ghazi (1992) Report on the Islamic Insurance System. Instead of replicating or modifying capitalist
institutions, he asserts, one must think through the purpose being served by an institution. If this
purpose is in conformity with Islam, then an institution to achieve it in conformity with Islamic law must
be developed. Historical evidence (see Mirakhor, 2007 for references) suggests that suitable

61

62

Working Paper 22

modifications of traditional Islamic institutions can accomplish the desired objectives quite efficiently, in
ways quite different from their Western analogues. Modern capitalist financial systems have evolved
over centuries and today form a system of mutually supportive institutions, with both private and public
sector involvement. A major difficulty faced by Muslim reformers, pointed out by many authors, is that
a financial system is an integrated and coherent structure and piecemeal changes towards an Islamic
system are quite difficult to devise, manage and implement. Replacement of an existing system by an
Islamic system based on trust, community and no interest is a difficult job, requiring changes and
interventions on several different fronts simultaneously.
There is a large amount of literature (and many controversies) regarding proposals for central banks,
private banks, money creation and management, stock exchanges, handling government finances and
loans, creation of steady income streams without interest-based instruments, mortgages and other
consumer loans, etc. Innovative alternatives to existing capitalist instruments have been proposed and
implemented. The most recent example is that of sukuk (a lease and buy-back alternative to bonds),
which went from being a theoretical proposal to one of the largest sources of Islamic finance over a
very short period of time. Instead of surveying the relevant literature, which is voluminous, complex
and covers diverse domains of financial affairs39, we follow the third route outlined above and discuss
the main principles of a comprehensive Islamic solution to financial problems and how they differ from
the current capitalist one. First, the underlying basis for a financial system is discussed, then a way of
providing a secure home for peoples deposits, and third how those deposits might be used.

6.1.1

The basis for financial institutions

To see how financial institutions in an Islamic economy would be structured, we must focus on the
idea that money is a means to an end, which is at the heart of an Islamic economy. This contrasts
with the idea of the endless accumulation of capital, which is at the heart of capitalism, and in which
the primary purpose of money is to make more money (e.g. Weber, 1930). Since in Islam the purpose
of money is to purchase the home of the hereafter (Q28:77), the emphasis is on using money for
social projects of value. In a society based on cooperation and trust, individuals can get by with much
less in the way of saving and personal wealth, since they can rely on others for assistance when their
rainy day occurs. Many Islamic rules are designed to produce such cooperation; for example,
strangers are entitled to hospitality as a right. Travellers through the Muslim world have often recorded

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

their experience of such hospitality; see One Thousand Roads to Mecca: Ten Centuries of Travelers
Writing about the Muslim Pilgrimage by Wolfe (1998). For example, Malcolm X. (1965) found in his
travel experience a spirit of unity and brotherhood that my experiences in America had led me to
believe never could exist between the white and non-white
A common objection to the idea of basing a financial system on cooperation and trust is that this is
only possible in small communities, where personal relationships can be sustained. In large
populations with transactions spread widely geographically, it is asserted that only modern anonymous
and contract-based institutions can function. However, there is substantial evidence that contradicts
this view. For example, Lopez (1976) shows that in the age of commercial revolution (950-1350AD)
trade flowed freely across the then known world, supported by risk sharing methods of finance, which
had been developed in Muslim countries consistent with the Shariah. Mirakhor (2007) notes that these
methods do require more trust than interest-based contractual ones, and suggests that shocks to the
system caused by the crusades, Mongol invasions and the bubonic plague, led to the evaporation of
trust and the subsequent emergence of interest-based transactions as the dominant mode of
business. For our purposes, we note that history attests to the possibility of developing a global
economy based on Islamic mechanisms of trust and cooperation, although the ways in which these
might be designed and implemented in the contemporary global economy pose many difficulties.

6.1.2

Deposits

To accomplish some of the purposes discussed above, we need to revive and modernize the
historical institution of amanah. In earlier times, people entrusted other trustworthy people with
deposits. We need an institution, say Dar-ul-Amanah, which would fulfil the function of keeping
deposits safely. This is one of the main functions of modern banks, which are, however, oriented
towards profit making. Our Dar-ul-Amanah would have an entirely different orientation. A primary
function has to be to preserve the value of the deposits of depositors. This involves some creativity in
modern times, since paper money is not equivalent to the gold of old. One idea would be to allow the
depositor a range of possibilities through which some index of the value of deposits could be
preserved. For example, deposits could be stored in a bundle of currencies optimized for stability, or in
the form of a local indexed basket of consumer goods, or could be more specifically targeted towards
particular future needs, such as the education of children. The main argument offered in favour of

63

64

Working Paper 22

bank interest by Muslims has been the propensity of inflation to reduce the real value of deposits. An
institution of the type proposed could overcome this problem without resorting to interest.

6.1.3

The use of deposits for socially profitable projects

A second important function of modern banks is that they pool surplus money and use it for
investments. These are intended to increase the value of the deposits for the benefit of both the
institution and (generally to a lesser extent) depositors; on the whole the means by which funds are
invested is regarded as the banks private concern. This system tends to lead to increasing
concentration of wealth. Our Dar-ul-Amanah could instead invest in human and social capital,
addressing social concerns and leading to the Islamically mandated circulation of wealth. An important
job of the institution would be to search out the best opportunities for social welfare (on behalf of its
depositors) and invest in such opportunities. For a start, if zakat can be levied by the institution on the
wealth deposited in it, this amount would be available to it for use for charitable purposes. In addition,
substantial amounts would be available for use as qarz-e-hasana (an interest-free loan made for
charitable purposes), just as conventional banks can get along with a small fraction of reserves/
liquidity. Such use would, of course, need to be with the consent of the depositors; however, there are
numerous parallels and precedents for such practices in Islamic history. As noted above, not only do
all Muslims have a responsibility to help the poor and work for welfare of society, but also they are
encouraged to compete with each other in seeking out the best opportunities to do so. The Dar-ulAmanah would seek out the best investments in the hereafter (the best social causes to support),
exactly as modern banks seek out the most profitable investment opportunities in this world. One
important investment could be to provide human beings with the skills needed to earn a livelihood; this
type of investment is likely to have a long-run high return.
Muslims have debated the idea that Islamic banks have social responsibilities, and some criticize this
as idealistic, romantic and impractical. In fact, large foundations and charitable organizations
performing functions of this kind already exist all over the world, although they are peripheral as
financial institutions. The Islamic ethos requires a re-orientation that would make these motivations
and practices central and modern banking practices peripheral. The importance of human beings and
social capital in the development process has been well established. The fact that human skills are
the principal component of the wealth of nations (see World Bank, 2006) suggests that institutions of

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

the type proposed above could promote economic growth more efficiently than conventional
development strategies. Moreover, historical evidence suggests that this type of activity did occur
extensively in Islamic societies in the past, at both personal and institutional levels (via waqf). The
potential for using Islamic motivation to create new types of institutions that conform with the Islamic
spirit is illustrated by the vastly successful Tabung Haji in Malaysia, which assists Muslims to perform
Hajj and mobilises savings for this purpose; see IRTI (1995) for more details.

6.1.4

Investment and business finance

The main purpose of Western financial institutions is to use money to make more money for investors/
depositors. As stressed above, Islamic financial institutions, in contrast, must conform to Islamic law
in form (in the process of accumulation, investment, and expenditure of money) and spirit (in
promoting desirable social goals, fellowship, harmony and cooperation). The principles of self-interest
and competition that underlie Western financial systems are inimical to the development of
cooperation and community harmony; see Nelson (1969) The Idea of Usury: From Universal
Brotherhood to Universal Otherhood for a historical study of the European experience. In particular, to
further develop the discussion of interest started above, two additional arguments that demonstrate
how the use of interest conflicts with Islamic principles are given below.
First, investment activities must be based on some form of partnership, of which many variants and
forms are possible. This partnership is not merely financial; partners are expected to share in the
fortunes of the business. Thus, it is not the enforcement of the legal contract by Shylock that troubles
Muslims; it is his lack of compassion for Antonio in his time of trouble. Interest-based contracts are
repugnant to the Islamic spirit because the lender gets repaid regardless of the business outcomes,
taking his pound of flesh out of the collateral if need be. In modern times, foreclosures of mortgages
create the same kind of outcome, in which big businesses take advantage of farmers and
homeowners in financial distress. Interest-based transactions promote indifference to the fate of
others and are harmful to development of cooperation and community feeling.
Second, in order to be halal, earnings must be based on productive activity or real services rendered.
Ownership of financial assets beyond ones needs is not a productive activity. However,
entrepreneurship, which involves judgment, the selection of good business opportunities, and taking

65

66

Working Paper 22

the risks entailed upon such selection, is a productive activity. Thus equity-based transactions built
around real products and services are permissible in Islam, while purely financial transactions are
not40. This Islamic spirit is in direct conflict with the spirit of modern banking, where bank involvement
in real transactions is often forbidden by law the bank can only act as a pure financial intermediary.
While conventional banks cannot be adapted to Islamic purposes, some types of western institution
are compatible with Islamic law and therefore may be used as models for an Islamic economy. For
large investors, some techniques currently in use in investment banks and by venture capital would
work and could be borrowed. Because the risk is shared by the investor, these are largely in
compliance with Islamic law. For small to medium investors, mutual funds would provide a suitable
source of funds for investment. A large number of technical issues arise in adapting current Western
financial instruments to the requirements of Islamic law; see Usmani (2000) for an accessible
summary.

6.2 Takaful (insurance)


According to Atiquzzafar Khan (2005), Muslims first became aware of the practice of insurance as a
result of trade contacts between Europe and the Ottoman Empire. We speculate that cooperative
practices in both personal and business life substantially reduce the need for insurance a society is
expected to take care of those in need. This may be why insurance was not needed and introduced in
the original Islamic Empire, despite the existence of an extensive global trade network. When
questioned about the permissibility of insurance, scholars of Islamic law have generally given negative
answers. For example, Atiquzzafar Khan (2005) gives a history of rulings on insurance made by
collective bodies of Islamic scholars in the twentieth century. While they recognized the utility of the
practice, they found that it conflicts with Islamic law on several grounds.
First, an insurance contract contains gharar (uncertainty about the product received, or the price paid):
in the case of damage, there can be a large payoff, while if there is none, such a payoff does not
occur. Arguments that the statistical law of averages eliminates or reduces the uncertainty have been
considered and rejected by Islamic scholars. In addition, an insurance contract resembles gambling,
which is prohibited in effect the insured and insurer bet on the occurrence of a random event. Also,
in the event of a payoff being necessary, the insured receives more money than paid as a premium.
This is regarded as a form of interest, which is prohibited. Finally, there is the issue of earned wages

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

the question of what (real) service is provided by the insurance company41 for which it is receiving
payment. What damage is caused by the insurance company for which it should bear liability in the
case of loss? Neither the premium payment nor the recompense in case of loss seems justifiable in
terms acceptable in Islamic law. While there has been substantial discussion back and forth on all of
these questions, the consensus opinion is as reported above: the bulk of existing insurance contracts
prevalent in the West are in conflict with Islamic law. For example, this was the decision of the
Assembly of Islamic Jurisprudence held in Mecca on 10 Shabaan 1398 (16th July 1978), with one
dissenter.
Given the nearly unanimous verdict on the conflict between existing forms of insurance and Islamic
law, the question is what alternatives might be possible. Ghazi (1992) considers some. He rejects the
approach of modifying existing institutions to conform to Islamic law, and suggests that we should give
new names to Islamic alternatives so as to clarify the radical differences between Islamic and
capitalist forms of insurance; this has been widely accepted, so that Islamic forms of insurance are
now called takaful. Ghazi considers the purpose of various different types of insurance contract,
assesses the conformity between their purpose and Islamic law, and suggests different methods to
achieve the same purpose that are within the domain of Islamic law. In general, the purposes of
insurance (which include economic security, protection against possible losses and provision for
heirs) are found to be compatible with the Shariah. However, achievement of these purposes within an
Islamic framework requires different approaches for different purposes. We discuss some of the
cases in broad outline, to give a flavour of the Islamic approach. For details, The Encyclopedia of
Islamic Banking and Insurance (IIBI, 1992) is available. Also, the annotated bibliographies of Akram
Khan (1983, 1991, 1998) provide an entry into the rapidly expanding literature.
For life insurance and pension plans, government-sponsored plans are generally acceptable, since
governments are responsible for taking care of their citizens. For most of the other purposes, private
sector insurance schemes are more appropriate. However, the general principles on which they are
based are different from conventional insurance contracts. According to Ghazi (1992):
The foundation of assurance can be based only on cooperation, mutual sympathy,
brotherhood, and mutual guarantee. Hence no system can be adopted whose real and
basic aim is business, profit-making, and money hoarding.

67

68

Working Paper 22

See Atiquzzafar Khan (2005) for more references to similar views by other scholars. Islamic law
permits only mutual insurance, where a group collectively safeguards the interests of its members
and acts to support them in the case of damage. The elements of gharar, gambling, interest and
unjustifiable payments, discussed earlier, are avoided if the intent is to help each other and there is no
profit motive involved in the insurance contract. Note that the emphasis is both on the creation of
community feeling and the intention behind the contract. Some of the problems with western forms of
insurance, which create conflict of interests between the parties, are known as moral hazard and
adverse selection in the technical literature. Thus in the case of private medical insurance, patients
may have little incentive to reduce costs, doctors can and do select expensive alternative for treatment
and order more medical tests, and insurance companies have reduced incentives for cost savings
since they can pass on costs to customers. As a result, in the USA, costs per patient with private
insurance are twice those in comparable countries where universal health care is implemented, like
the UK, France, Canada, Germany and Japan; see the report of the Lewin Group (2005), which
documents the inefficiencies of private medical insurance. Results from experimental economics
show that problems of conflicts between social and private interests can be reduced or minimized
when cooperation is encouraged and selfish behaviour that disregards group interests is discouraged.
This suggests that Islamic insurance systems, which are designed to promote cooperative social
behaviour, should lead to more efficient economic outcomes.
Another important feature of Islamic insurance is prevention of the concentration of wealth; Ghazi
(1992) states that Islam forbids concentration/hoarding of wealth. Hence, no system of insurance
may be adopted as a result of which a few persons grow rich . The reason for this concern is that
conventional forms of insurance require the insurer to be very wealthy; this was noted as early as
Adam Smith. Given the ubiquity of insurance, this provides opportunities for making profit and
increasing wealth that can only be utilized by the wealthy, leading to further concentration of wealth.
Mutual forms of insurance avoid this problem by utilising collective responsibility and sharing the
burden of insurance.
A number of different models for providing Insurance within the framework of Islamic law have been
devised and implemented in practice by takaful companies that have recently come into existence.
One model is based on the idea of a waqf that provides help to its members. Another model uses gifts

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

(tabbarru), and a number of mixtures and alternatives have been proposed. The idea of this piece of
financial engineering is to use historically acceptable forms of Islamic contracts in order to devise a
combination that parallels existing insurance schemes. Some authors have made more radical
proposals based on historical Islamic institutions; the main idea is one of widening circles of
responsibility. In times of trouble, as noted above, the family is the first source of support. If this proves
inadequate, then the extended family is expected to shoulder the responsibility. Even larger difficulties
are the collective responsibility of the entire tribe/community. Creative adaptation of these institutions
may provide an alternative to insurance. Instead of family and tribe, it might, for example, be possible
to form an association of bus owners within first a city and then a country. Generally speaking, the
individualistic bent of western institutions makes them incompatible with Islam, although in the case of
insurance, there are some western models that have potential for adaptation within Islam. For
example, the German health insurance system has some resemblance to the proposals discussed
above. Individuals are placed into groups, and all groups receive compulsory coverage of a similar
type. Also, Health Maintenance Organizations offer a model which could be adapted to Islamic models
of mutual insurance. Here a group of people make monthly payments, which cover the cost of hiring
the services of physicians and buildings, and all the required health needs of the group are met by
these hires. This type of service contract is permissible within Islamic law (subject to certain
limitations) and may be regarded as a form of an insurance contract.

6.3 Waqf (endowment/trust)


The waqf is a unique Islamic institution, which has played a tremendously important role in Islamic civil
society in the past, though it is currently marginalized, for reasons discussed later. Under Islamic law,
anyone may settle a property, its usufruct and incomes derived from it for specific projects of social
welfare. Awqaf were set up and encouraged by the Prophet (s.a.w) as a form of eternal charity. As
already discussed42, those with resources to spare have a responsibility for seeking out those less
fortunate than themselves, and giving them this excess (as a loan or as a gift) in a way that does not
damage their self-respect. The idea of making a profit from the needs of the poor is repugnant to the
spirit of Islam it sacrifices an end for a means. In contrast, the irrational pursuit of wealth for its own
sake, which according to Weber is the spirit of capitalism, has led some economists to give such
primacy to making money that even helping the poor is seen as a means to the goal of making more
money43. Traditionally, wealthy Muslims have set up awqaf, which are highly encouraged and

69

70

Working Paper 22

considered to be among the best ways of using surplus money. Since the asset (typically land) is not
used up, revenues from it can theoretically be used forever for charitable purposes; this is regarded as
one way of excelling in the competition for good deeds that is the purpose of life. There is a 45-page
bibliography of English articles on many aspects of awqaf prepared by Islahi (2004), and other
bibliographies in Arabic, referenced in Islahi, which are more extensive, since there is more material
on this topic in Arabic. Comparable western institutions are charitable foundations and perhaps NGOs,
with the difference that a waqf is subject to an extensive set of rules based on Islamic law.
Numerous authors (e.g. Kahf, 2000; Iqbal, 1995; Sait and Lim, 2006, Chapter 7) have discussed the
significance of waqf in Islamic history, and all have concluded that they formed a substantial and
significant portion of the economy and played an important role in all dimensions of civil society. It is
estimated that about one third of the land in the Ottoman Empire was devoted to such trusts.
According to Hoexter et al (2002, p. 128):
The waqfs contribution to the shaping of the urban space can hardly be overestimated
A major part of the public environment in (Islamic) towns actually came into being as a
result of endowments.
While there were a tremendous variety of charitable purposes for which millions of awqaf were used
throughout Islamic lands, the five main categories were food, housing, health, education and religion.
Kahf (2000) gives some historical details on the relative size of these various sectors and further
references. Sait and Lim (2006) indicate that the Ottomans did not see themselves as responsible
for social welfare, suggesting that the awqaf took adequate care of these needs of the population.
Thus these institutions formed an historic Islamic alternative to the current European welfare state
model for providing for peoples needs. The Islamic methodology has two distinct advantages:

The awqaf were locally based and managed. They had substantially more local information than staterun systems typically do, and could therefore perform more efficiently.

The Islamic requirement that social institutions should inculcate a sense of responsibility, reinforce social
ties and increase social awareness was also fulfilled by this system44.

Sait and Lim (2006) write that the system of awqaf succeeded for centuries in Islamic lands in
redistributing wealth, leading to equitable outcomes and the circulation of wealth in accordance with
Quranic injunctions. In addition, by providing independent incomes to numerous small persons and

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

institutions, the awqaf empowered civil society against the state. Historically, states attempted to curb
this power and regulate the awqaf in various ways, but such efforts were successfully resisted.
Women endowed or managed a significant number of awqaf and had a correspondingly significant
impact on civil society; Faizer (2007) provides a useful bibliography. Equal access to education via
awqaf and the general respect for learning in Islamic societies led to representation of all social
classes within their intellectual elites: Kahf (2000) cites Al-Syed (pp 237-258) as stating that at times,
the majority of Muslim scholars [came from] the poor and slave segments of society, and very often
they strongly opposed the policies of the rulers.
Waqf has a strong legal basis, and there is a huge literature on different types of waqf and rules
concerning their operation, the permissibility of utilizing different types of property for waqf and debates
among the different schools of Islamic law on major and minor aspects of awqaf. Once set up, a waqf
cannot easily be shut down. Furthermore, the original purpose of the creator of the waqf cannot easily
be changed. Because of these Islamic rules, some have argued that an important cause of Islamic
decline was that many awqaf were locked into uses that became dysfunctional over time (e.g. Kuran,
2004). In fact, there is substantial dynamism and flexibility in Islamic law, and creative adaptations to
changing situations can be documented in different areas, as we have discussed in different contexts
in the current paper. Rather, it is clear that Islamic society as a whole became ossified and did not
adapt to changing situations in many different dimensions. Hodgson (1974) gives a large scale view of
the Muslim decline that avoids most of the elementary errors committed by Orientalist analyses. It
appears likely that the increasing dysfunctionality45 of the awqaf was an effect of the general decline of
Muslims rather than a cause. The bibliography by Islahi (2004) lists a large number of articles dealing
with the issue of how to update and modernise the awqaf.
Because of their firm basis in Islamic law, awqaf were able to resist efforts by many Muslim rulers to
curb their influence. However colonising powers were not constrained by Islamic law. Seizure of waqf
properties occurred on a large scale not only because of their wealth, but also because their
organisational and material resources often permitted the awqaf to act as focal points of resistance to
colonisation.

71

72

Working Paper 22

In the post-colonial era, for complex reasons, several Muslim countries have abolished, nationalised or
created stringent regulations for awqaf. Sait and Lim (2005, Paper 7) write that
The eclipse of the endowment (waqf) has left a vacuum in the arena of public services,
which the State has been unable to fill easily in many Muslim countries. However, both
the idea of the endowment (waqf) and the endowment (waqf) doctrine itself remain
influential and there are clear signs of its reinvigoration. The endowment (waqf) served
and continues to serve as an instrument of public policy and impacts on all aspects of
Muslim life.
There is today widespread agreement among Muslims on the need to revive the institution of waqf and
give it the central importance that it had in the past. Discussions of how to add flexibility to the laws of
awqaf, revive the institution and adapt it to modern conditions abound in the Islamic economic
literature. Numerous conferences discussing all aspects of the issues involved have been held. Sait
and Lim (2005, Paper 7; 2006) discuss some of the required reforms, noting that Kuwait has taken a
lead in this area. Kahf (1998b) and Zarqa (1994) also discuss how to revitalise this important Islamic
institution and identify suitable old and new modes of financing.

6.4 Hisbah (audit or accountability)


In Markets and prices, Kahf (1996a) provides an elementary introduction to various types of market
failure that require regulation by the state. He also discusses the spirit of Islamic economic institutions,
which is to find a cooperative solution to such problems, while minimizing infringements on the free
operation of markets. Indeed, Islam puts a great deal of emphasis on individual freedom in all spheres
of action (including the marketplace), and regulates it only when social interest so requires. Kahf (op.
cit.) notes that the semi-judicial institution of al-hisbah, operational from the earliest days of Islam, is
charged with responsibility of carrying out the spirit of the system, setting conditions that preserve
and enhance the public health and interests, protect the consumers, solve business and labor
disputes, promote good market behavior, and ensure their observance.
Naz (1999) gives a comprehensive survey of hisbah, including its basis in Islamic law, its theoretical
and historical functions within Islamic states, and its similarities with and differences from other
judicial and executive institutions within an Islamic framework. Regulation of markets is among the
main functions of hisbah, and because of our focus on economics, we are mainly concerned with this

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

aspect. However, Naz (1999) mentions that the translation market supervisor, used by several
western authors, is too narrow to cover all the functions of hisbah, which include all aspects of public
morals. To illustrate, it was responsible for

finding mates for orphans and widows (when they could not do so themselves),

ensuring that teachers did not punish students too severely,

enforcing Islamic public codes of conduct, including those mandated by social norms, and

repairs of public property like wells, canals or city walls.

As a general rule, the hisbah protects the public interest in cases where there is no immediate
aggrieved party that can take the case to court. In the realm of the marketplace, the hisbah ensured
that weights and measures were of official standard; provided stamps of quality; ensured that goods
being sold were of standard quality by various means; took action against false advertising, hoarding
to increase prices, collusion and monopolistic actions; and generally protected the public interest.
Issues like pollution of rivers or the environment also fall under the jurisdiction of the hisbah. An
examination of these different roles and their implementation in different periods of Islamic history is
given in Chapter 5 of Naz (1999). A subtle but important issue is that hisbah is concerned solely with
the public domain: visible immorality. If people drink or gamble in private, the hisbah is not authorised
to investigate and discover this. In fact, the Quran mandates that private actions should not be
investigated (Q49:12).
To compare the hisbah with western institutions, we first note a well known deficiency of free market
mechanisms: in situations where large benefits accrue to a small group, while a small amount of harm
is distributed over a large group, free market mechanisms generally favour the small group and lead to
outcomes harmful to the public interest. The concept of the class action suit has been devised to
overcome this problem, and in recent years, substantial legislation and literature has addressed this
issue. A study of the career of Ralph Nader clearly reveals the major issues raised by taking on large
corporations in the public interest, and the non-existence of government support or protection for such
causes, at least in America. Beyond Nader: Consumer Protection and the Regulation of Advertising by
Pitofsky (1977) discusses the issues in the context of advertising, while New Zealand MCA (Ministry of
Consumer Affairs) (2005) provides a broader review and literature survey. It is therefore of great
interest to note that an official equivalent of Ralph Nader has existed as an Islamic government
institution from the beginning of Islamic states.

73

74

Working Paper 22

In general, the laissez-faire orientation of economic theorists and the presumption that market
outcomes are generally best has led to substantial delays in recognition of market failures that cause
harm to consumers and failure to develop appropriate methods of redress. An extreme position is
taken by Friedman (2005), who argues that The only business of business is to make profits,
implying that socially harmful consequences can be disregarded in the pursuit of profit. Islam takes a
clear view on this issue, assigns social responsibility to all agents including firms, and has
mechanisms for monitoring and enforcing accountability in the form of the hisbah institution and
associated administrative arrangements.

6.5 Environmental protection, ecology and natural resources.


Amongst the social consequences of irresponsible and unregulated business activities and the pursuit
of luxurious lifestyles we can include the environmental problems that have been created on a scale
massive enough to threaten human and other life on this planet. For example, Robbins (2007) writes
that about 5 hectares of productive land are required to maintain the lifestyle of an average person in a
rich country, while only 1.7 hectares per person are available worldwide. The process of fulfilling
demand for luxurious lifestyles leads to large scale destruction of planetary resources in a way that is
clearly unjust for both our contemporaries and future generations. In reaction, the concept of
sustainable development, which proposes to achieve economic growth in a manner that can be
sustained in the long run, has been developed. This is superficially similar to Islamic views in terms of
its intended results, but differs dramatically in intent, as discussed by Yousri (2005). Thus in some
views of sustainable development, although certainly not all, economic growth is the objective, and
protection of the environment is regarded as a means to ensure that growth can continue to take place
in the future.
In the Islamic view, like that of many other faith traditions, natural resources are a sacred trust, and
protecting them for future generations a primary responsibility (Birvndhavaradarajan, 1992; Foltz et. al.,
2003; Sidek, 1989). Economic growth is not (directly) a goal at all, though it may be desirable as a
means to (say) poverty alleviation. Fahim Khan (2003) discusses the relevance of these issues to
theories of consumer behaviour. While some aspects of environmental protection fall under hisbah,
environmental issues more generally are the collective responsibility of society as a whole, and
measures to ensure environmental protection, natural resource conservation and the maintenance of
biodiversity can be taken by the state, specific institutions, or individuals.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

The Quran talks about people who are fair in speech, but make mischief on earth and destroy crops
and progeny (Q2:204-5). The Prophet s.a.w. established a green belt of twelve miles around Medina,
and prohibited people from cutting trees or hunting in this area. He prohibited pollution of drinking
water, and Muslim jurists have deduced, therefore, that it is not permissible to dump garbage and
waste products into rivers. He also encouraged revival of barren land by assigning property rights to
those who did so. On the basis of these traditions, Muslim jurists in the Middle Ages legislated against
industrial activities that pollute the environment (see Iqbal, 2005).
It is clear that if an exhaustible natural resource is private property, then the owner generally has an
incentive to exploit it fully in his or her lifetime, and no incentive to save it for future generations. Islam
considers that all natural resources are held in trust and has banned private ownership of them.
Instead, states are supposed to hold natural resources in trust for future generations and must ensure
that all can benefit from them. Justice to those not born requires the conservation of natural resources
and their utilization in a way that is fair to all. For example, the Prophet commanded us not to waste
even a few drops of water, even if we are next to a river. Armies were instructed not to burn trees or
destroy agricultural land. Destruction of the natural habitat of animals, and of flora or fauna, is not
allowed. There is emphasis on planting of trees and flowers, and these are treated as acts of virtue.
Hadeeth says that if you are in process of planting a tree and Judgement Day arrives, keep on
planting. Justice applies not just to humans but also to animals, and humans are prohibited from
torturing animals or hunting them purely for pleasure. Animals used for service must be treated fairly
and not hurt or punished severely.
In addition, Muslims have been commanded not to emulate luxurious lifestyles (see Akram Khan,
1989, p18-20). Ironically, as a large amount of recent research shows (for example, Lane, 2001;
Layard, 2005), extravagant consumption does not lead to additional happiness, satisfaction with life, or
a sense of wellbeing; pursuit of wealth turns out to be an illusion, as the Quran states (Q3:185).
Statistics detailing the current state of affairs in Muslim societies and resulting policy priorities are
given in Kahf (2003). For a practical illustration of the Islamic approach in the context of Malaysia, see
Choudhury and Salleh (1993). The farsightedness of the Islamic perspective is astonishing given the
formulation of Islamic principles in an era of a far simpler economy.

75

76

Working Paper 22

The role of Muslim individuals


Q13:11 Verily, God does not change mens condition unless they change their inner
selves

In many parts of the preceding discussion, it has been emphasized that Islamic institutions must be
built around individuals who share a Muslim ethos and are united in the common purpose given by
Islam. It is widely acknowledged that such individuals are currently scarce in Islamic societies. Some
Muslims have taken the view that first we must change individuals, and then institutions and societies
the grassroots or bottom-up approach. Others advocate a top-down approach, suggesting that the
persuasive and coercive powers of governments will provide a faster vehicle to achieve the desired
social transformation. Islamic history and source materials provide support for both points of view.
Reconciliation is possible when we realise that Islam asks Muslims to engage with the world as a
means of achieving inner spiritual transformation. The struggle to create a just, cooperative and caring
community, and the Islamic institutions which support such a society, will also bring about the
changes in individuals that are required by Islam. Islamic teachings provide a series of principles on
which Muslims are exhorted to base their lives. In this section, those relevant to the economic sphere
are summarized. As clarified by our discussion of methodology earlier, descriptive accuracy is not
relevant. Rather, these principles and norms provide goals towards which all Muslims are expected to
strive, both individually and collectively, and which can also be used for the purpose of training
children.

Productivity: In general, Muslims should be productive and earn enough to cover their sustenance.
Akram Khan (1989, p. 36, 3.3-4) cites sayings of the Prophet praising those who make an effort to earn
a living for themselves and their dependents. Earning less than one needs necessarily makes one
dependent on others. The act of begging or asking others is, however, very much disliked and
discouraged in Islam. At the same time, neither is too much engagement with the world, in the form of
earning more than necessary, recommended. The best form of sustenance is to earn just enough for
ones needs. Needs are defined sufficiently broadly in Islam that one is not commanded to lead an
austere and ascetic lifestyle: Q7:32 Say: Who has forbidden the beautiful (gifts) of God which He has
produced for His servant and tayyibat (things clean and pure) (which He has provided) for sustenance?
Good general discussions of consumer behaviour in Islamic theory are given in Kahf (1996b), Taseen
(1998) and Fahim Khan (2003).

Spending on others: In Islam, there is a tremendous emphasis on infaq or spending in the path of
Allah. Kahf (undated) writes that infaq means giving away for the betterment of society and its members

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

(including the giver and his family). More than 150 ayat of the Quran encourage spending, more than
those devoted to the famous five pillars of Islam. One is Q3:92 By no means shall ye attain
righteousness unless ye give (freely) of that which ye love. Among the countless traditions regarding
infaq, Kahf (1996b) cites: The creatures are all dependent on Allah, and the most beloved by Him are
those who are most beneficial to His dependents. Knowing the propensity for avarice, greed and love of
hoarding within the hearts of men, spending is encouraged first on ones immediate family, second on
neighbours, and then in a widening circle of responsibilities. Such spending can be compulsory or
voluntary. As discussed above, compulsory categories include the zakat and some similar
requirements. There is also an obligation for community responsibility where, if needs are not met, then
spending becomes obligatory for all. Finally there are voluntary categories, for which there is substantial
encouragement. There are two types of voluntary spending. One is a one-shot act designed to take care
of a particular need. The second is a long-term planned contribution to the welfare of the society, which
usually takes the shape of a waqf (discussed above).

Equality: Islam carries a very strong message of the equality of all human beings in front of God.
Superiority comes only from closeness to God. The Prophet gave an example of a poor man who,
because of his relationship to God, was much more important than a world full of rich men. Formal
relationships like servant/master, teacher/student, king/people should not fill people with pride and make
them think that they are superior or inferior. An important consequence is the Islamic emphasis on the
dignity of the poor. This is to be contrasted with class-based attitudes that associate superiority and
inferiority with social group or wealth. In Islam, several measures are taken to ensure that the poor are
not treated disrespectfully in the process of charitable giving. The Quran commands Muslims not to spoil
our charity by saying hurtful words indeed, it is better not to give than to give abusively: Q2:262 Those
who spend their substance in the cause of Allah, and follow not up their gifts with reminders of their
generosity or with injury,-for them their reward is with their Lord: on them shall be no fear, nor shall they
grieve. The rich are told that the poor have rights in their wealth. Further, they are obliged to seek out
needy people. The poor are told not to ask for help; instead they are urged to conceal their needs. The
Quran tells us that the needy will not reveal their needs, and that they may be recognised by certain
signs: Q2:273 (Charity is) for those in need, who, in Allahs cause are restricted (from travel), and cannot
move about in the land, seeking (For trade or work): the ignorant man thinks, because of their modesty,
that they are free from want. Thou shalt know them by their (Unfailing) mark: They beg not importunately
from all the sundry. And whatever of good ye give, be assured Allah knoweth it well. It is then up to the
rich to find ways of giving that will not offend the dignity of the poor.

77

78

Working Paper 22

Moderation: Islam commands Muslims to be moderate in spending (Q25:67) and not to pursue
ostentatious and luxurious lifestyles. Some sayings of the Prophet recommending simplicity are given by
Akram Khan (1989, p77, 7.1-7). At the same time, asceticism is not encouraged. A man who was
dishevelled and in rags was told to display the wealth that Allah had given him by the Prophet; see Akram
Khan (1989, p. 83, 7.11). Two types of spending are specifically forbidden: israf, which is to spend
extravagantly, and tabzeer, which is to spend on that which is forbidden, like wine or gambling. Taking
loans is also discouraged, except for worthwhile purposes. In particular, loans for stylish consumption
(and thus the credit card-based consumer culture) are very much against the Islamic ethos and spirit. A
detailed discussion with references to source materials is given in Taseen (1998, p. 141-158). As
indicated in Section 6.5, moderating consumption is an essential element of any strategy of sustainable
development; see also Fahim Khan (2003).

Prohibition of envy: Islam prohibits Muslims from envying others and teaches strategies to prevent
envy. The Prophet told us to look at people less fortunate than ourselves in worldly affairs, so that we feel
thankful for what we have. The Quran states:
(Q4:32) Hence, do not covet the bounties which God has bestowed more abundantly on
some of you than on others. Men shall have a benefit from what they earn, and women
shall have a benefit from what they earn. Ask, therefore, God [to give you] out of His
bounty: behold, God has indeed full knowledge of everything.
Making others envy us, via conspicuous consumption, is also prohibited in Islam.. The rich should
conceal their riches to prevent envy the exact opposite of conspicuous consumption. At the same
time, the poor are encouraged not to envy the rich, but to be content with their lot. True richness is that of
a heart with a generous disposition. Taseen (1998, p. 153-156) cites the Quran and Hadeeth in support
of these principles. From Veblen (1899) to Lane (2001) and Layard (2005), many have identified envy as
an important source of waste and unhappiness in capitalist economies.

Compassion: The development of feeling for others is stressed in Islam. The Quran writes about the
Prophet that heavily weighs upon him (the thought) that you might suffer, full of compassion and mercy
towards the believers. In other verses, the Prophet is described as being Mercy for all mankind. The
Quran praises those who feed others while being themselves hungry: (Q59:9) who love all that come to
them in search of refuge, and who harbour in their hearts no grudge for whatever the others may have
been given, but rather give them preference over themselves, even though poverty be their own lot. The
second caliph of Islam, Umar Farooq R.A., ate coarse bread, because he felt ashamed to eat refined
bread when not all of the public could do so. It is the spread of sentiments like this that can solve the
problems facing the world today.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Concluding remarks
Allahs Apostle said, If Adams son had a valley full of gold, he would like to have two
valleys, for nothing fills his mouth except dust (of the grave). Al-Bukhari: Vol. 8,
Ch.76, No. 447:

The fundamental economic problem is a normative one: what should an individual (and a society) do
with surplus wealth? Islamic teachings, in common with other faith traditions1, ask us to purchase
paradise by spending on others. There exists a substantial amount of data to show that, contrary to
the pessimistic views of Malthus and his followers, there are sufficient resources to provide for the
basic needs of everybody on the planet. However, modern western commitments to individual
freedom lead to idle desires of the wealthy and corporate greed being placed on a par with the needs
of the hungry and sick. There is general agreement with the Hadeeth cited above that wants are
unlimited. Since all wants cannot be fulfilled with available resources, a political commitment to
consumer sovereignty leads to the view that the fundamental economic problem is that of scarcity:
there is not enough fulfil all wants. The solution is then sought in increasing wealth and material
resources to fulfil these wants. A clear-sighted view of the issues is presented by Keynes, one of the
architects of modern economic institutions as well as economic thought. He thought that the pursuit of
wealth for its own sake was a disgusting morbidity, but considered it to be necessary at the time he
was writing. It is worth quoting Keynes in full:
When the accumulation of wealth is no longer of high social importance, there will be
great changes in the code of morals. We shall be able to rid ourselves of many of the
pseudo-moral principles which have hag-ridden us for two hundred years, by which we
have exalted some of the most distasteful of human qualities into the position of the
highest virtues. We shall be able to afford to dare to assess the money-motive at its true
value. The love of money as a possession as distinguished from the love of money as
a means to the enjoyments and realities of life will be recognised for what it is, a
somewhat disgusting morbidity, one of those semi-criminal, semi-pathological
propensities which one hands over with a shudder to the specialists in mental disease ...
But beware! The time for all this is not yet. For at least another hundred years we must
pretend to ourselves and to everyone that fair is foul and foul is fair; for foul is useful and
fair is not. Avarice and usury and precaution must be our gods for a little longer still. For
only they can lead us out of the tunnel of economic necessity into daylight (Keynes,
1930 cited in Skidelsky, 2001).
Unfortunately this Keynesian solution, currently being pursued with vigour all over the world in the form
of policies for growth and development, is failing because wants increase with increases in wealth, as
the Hadeeth cited above indicates. For example, Layard (2005) and Robbins (2007) document that
substantial increases in wealth in western societies have not led to the desired consequences in
terms of increases in happiness, satisfaction, contentment or a sense of wellbeing. Douthwaite (1992)

79

80

Working Paper 22

has also evaluated growth on many dimensions and found it wanting. In the meantime, the disastrous
consequences of pretending that fair is foul have manifested themselves in all dimensions of human
existence. The trillions of dollars being spent on killing and destruction testify that it is not material
resources but the will to do good that is scarce. Environmental and ecological catastrophes resulting
from the senseless pursuit of money for its own sake have been documented by many. The Quran
states that
30:41 Corruption has appeared on land and sea because of (the evil) which mens hands
have done, that He may make them taste a part of that which they have done, in order
that they may return.
Current solutions to the economic problems arising out of encouraging greed, avarice and usury as a
means of leading us out of the tunnel of economic necessity are not working. Islam provides an
alternative by clearly distinguishing between needs and wants, and encouraging social responsibility
for the needs of all while discouraging fulfilment of idle desires. This basis for solving the economic
problems of humankind differs radically from any currently on the conventional economic menu (e.g.
the World Bank website). Islam offers a vision of a society based on cooperation and community
harmony, people who take care of each other in times of need, and an economic system to match.
Historically, Islamic civilization has taken much better care of its disadvantaged and poor, as well as
minorities (by offering them religious and cultural freedom), than others, including current European
civilization. Is it not worth struggling to create such a world? That is what Islamic economics is about.
Within each human being, God has placed the potential to rise above the angels. He has shown each
of us the two paths (Q90:10) the high road as well as the low and left us free to choose: (Q73:19)
Let whosoever wills, choose the path to His Lord. As Muslims, we engage in a struggle to make the
world a better place for humans, as a means to find the way to our Lord. We are all given only one
chance to live. I conclude with the prayer that God guides us to the straight path and fulfilment of the
potential for excellence that He has placed within us all.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Notes
1

3
4

7
8
9

10

11

12

13

14

It is part of Islamic etiquette to invoke peace and blessings upon the prophet Mohammad whenever
his name is mentioned.
In the end, then, despite the inevitable parochialism of our attachments to national societies and
cultures, the change most required is the gradual acceptance of the realities of a common
experience, ... all of us are now children of the revolutionary insight of seventeenth century Europe
(Rostow, 1978, p 657).
See, for example, Edward Said (1978) Orientalism.
While the mathematical approach nearly extinguished qualitative alternatives in economics
(although they have re-emerged from hiding in the recent past), the same battle has had somewhat
different outcomes in political science. See, for example, Monroe (2005), who appeals for a live
and let live approach which would permit qualitative and historical analyses alongside the dominant
formal and mathematical ones.
Van Fraassen (1980, p. 2) who is himself a staunch empiricist, writes: Logical positivism, even
if one is quite charitable had a rather spectacular crash.
Quoted from entry on Michel Foucault in Stanford Encyclopaedia of Philosophy (accessed 23
February 2008): http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/foucault/
From Sahih Tirmizi, Book 4, Chapter 14, Kitab-ul-Ilm.
May Allah shower his mercy and blessings upon him.
Schumpeter (1974) suggests that economic thoughts did not occur to mankind during the five
hundred years between the Greeks and the Renaissance the so-called great gap. Mirakhor
(1983) fills this gap with the economic thought of Muslims; see also Ahghari (1991) and Ghazanfar
(2003). Khan (1983, 1991, 1998) provides many more references in his annotated bibliographies.
There is no doubt that historical circumstances have strongly impacted on modern formulations of
Islamic economics, as well as political theories. This has led some observers to the mistaken belief
that these theories are additions to the corpus of Islamic beliefs for example, Kuran (1997, p. 306)
writes that Bringing economics within the purview of religion was, then, central to Mawdudis
broader goal. In fact, economics has always been within the purview of Islam, but has never been
separated out as a distinct sub-domain or isolated from spiritual and social concerns.
This runs counter to the belief that European colonization brought civilization to primitive cultures.
The facile assumption that conquest proves superiority runs counter to historical evidence that
savage tribes have often over-run more advanced civilizations. Evidence for this point of view is
provided in Marglin (2007) and Mitchell (2002). Syed Hussain Ahmed Madani (1953) documents the
destruction of numerous welfare and educational institutions in India and the spreading of corrupt
practices among the populace due to British rule.
I refrain from using the simpler word democracy, since it tends to be interpreted as elections/
voting and imitation of Western political institutions.
While most Muslim authors argue for a distinct Islamic economic system, some have gone against
this current. For example, Sibai (1982) argues that Islam is a variant of socialism, and advocates
nationalization and other socialist economic strategies. See Mintjes (1978) for a survey of the
discussions about Islamic socialism. Weber (1930) and his followers argued that Islam is
fundamentally incompatible with capitalism. Rodinson (1966) argued against this view, suggesting
that by creative adaptation and interpretation of Islamic law, Muslims could choose freely among
economic systems.
Muqorobin (2008) categorizes by language 5,000 publications available at the International Islamic
University of Malaysia; this provides some idea of the relative quantity of publications in different
languages. Many Arabic publications and guides to the literature are available from the Islamic
Economics Research Center of King Abdul Aziz University: http://islamiccenter.kau.edu.sa/english/
index.htm

81

82

Working Paper 22

15
16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29
30

His works are easily available from his website http://www.monzer.kahf.com


Nearly all of the IRTI/IDB publications are available for downloading from www.irtipms.org/
PubAllE.asp
However, a collection of articles on different initiatives is available from various websites, including
the Dow-Jones website at: http://www.djindexes.com/mdsidx/
index.cfm?event=showIslamicArticles (See also http://www.nubank.com/islamic/index.html
and http://islamic-finance.net/elief.html)
The goals of the International Islamic University of Islamabad include To re-construct human
thought in all its forms on the foundations of Islam while the International Islamic University of
Malaysia aims to Integrate Islamic revealed knowledge and values in all academic disciplines and
educational activities.
The Arabs went from being near-savages, who buried their infant daughters alive and killed each
other for trivialities, to models of civilized behaviour for all times. Hart (2000) ranks the Prophet as
the single most influential man in all of human history.
Contrary to Adam Smith, Marshall (cited in Ali Khan, 2004)) thought that businessmen were not
primarily motivated by the sordid and ignoble love of money.
A number of articles showing greater selfishness on the part of economists, who are trained to think
of selfishness as socially beneficial, have been published; see Kirchgssner (2005) for a survey.
Perhaps the strongest evidence of the impact of economic training is furnished by responses to
behaviours observed in Experimental Economics. Since the most fundamental axiom of economic
thought, people prefer more money to less, is routinely violated in many situations, economists
cannot help but be puzzled by observed behaviour (see Camerer, 2003, p 60). No one else finds it
surprising.
Similar ideas occur in all religious traditions; see Wilson (1991). For example, the Bhagavad Gita
compares a man controlled by his desires to a carriage controlled by the horses instead of the
driver.
An important utopian was Karl Marx, whose vision of a classless society where everybody would
receive what he or she needed from a benevolent state, and labourers would receive dignity and
respect, motivated and changed the lives of millions in the last century. Ironically, this provides a
powerful illustration of the power of ideas, visions, and philosophies to dramatically change the
material world, contrary to one of his own central theses.
Masud (1995) has described, inter alia, the conflict between the Sufis and the ulama in Islamic
Spain.
Property rights do not receive much attention in conventional economic literature, since the idea of
private property is accepted by all. See, however, Coase (1960) and related literature and also de
Soto (2000), who argues that property rights are the key to the success of capitalism.
The theory of property rights in Islamic law is substantially different from Western theories. The
European history of conquests, revolutions, and appropriations and seizures of property and
subsequent reversions, led to the development of philosophies that sought to rationalize, justify or
modify the existing structures of property rights; see, for example, the article on property in
Wikipedia for a brief summary of this history, different schools of thought and further references.
The website of the International Development Research Center also provides a large bibliography
on the topic: http://www.idrc.ca/en/ev-9425-201-1-DO_TOPIC.html
Iqbal and Mirakhor (2005) have argued that the Islamic idea that the right to property derives from
making it useful leads naturally to a stakeholder model of the firm.
He also lists 18 references (numbers 224 to 242).
Such sales led to the coining of the term winners curse, see Capen et al (1971). Also see Kagel
and Roth (1995, Chapter 7) for a survey and update.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

31

32

33

34

35

36

37
38

39
40

41

42

For this same discussion in the historical context of the widespread adoption of interest in Christian
societies, see The Idea of Usury: From Universal Brotherhood to Universal Otherhood by Nelson
(1969).
This contrasts with modern European conceptions, according to which a government is
responsible for creating and enforcing a social contract, which may consist of any set of mutually
agreed upon rules. Hegel, building on political theories initiated by Machiavelli, argued that since a
government is responsible for creating and maintaining the law, it is outside the law and not subject
to it. Such a rationale for political authority was responsible for the extraordinary cruelty of the
fascist states see Manicas (1989) and also Harrington (1985) Politics at Gods Funeral.
Note the implication that in an Islamic state, no one is justified in implementing a cruel and unjust
policy (such as burning of the Jews) on the grounds that I was just carrying out orders for the full
import of this, see Arendts (2006) Eichmann in Jerusalem: A Report on the Banality of Evil.
Rulings by Islamic scholars on the legitimacy of governments have played an important role in
Islamic history. For example, rulings in favour of British rule in India helped legitimize it, and rulings
against the British supported the War of Independence in 1857. Many British policies in the Middle
East were formulated in response to their fear that a ruling by the Ottoman Empire saying that
Islamic law requires Muslims to act against the British could lead to widespread revolt in their
Muslim colonies; see Fromkin (1991).
Traditional conceptions of the state, according to some, are based on a natural community with a
common ethos and shared goals. Modern conceptions of the state, in contrast, are based on a
social contract, agreement to a set of rules for resolving conflicting interests. Manicas (1989)
writes in this context that the only thing which people have in common is the government and,
paradoxically, their private interests! and describes the history of the transition from the traditional
polis to the modern societas form of political organisation in Europe. Islamic principles of
government are based on the traditional form, but make explicit allowance for minorities which may
not share the same goals as the main community, permitting them far more liberty to self-regulate
(through personal law) than is allowed in many states.
The resemblance between these traditional methods for generation of revenue in an Islamic state,
and the tax proposals of Henry George (1879) in his classic, controversial, and now almost
forgotten Progress and Poverty, is quite striking.
See http://www.globalpolicy.org/socecon/bwi-wto/critics/stiglitzindex.htm
For example, the fire-bombing of Dresden and the British blockade of food to Germany, which led to
the death by starvation of an estimated 800,000 civilians, were ignored, while much lesser crimes
by Germans were prosecuted (Glover, 2001, p. 66).
Akram Khan (1983, 1991, 1998) has provided comprehensive annotated bibliographies.
We illustrate the difference by the example of murabaha. A business purchases goods on credit,
planning to repay after the goods are sold at a profit. The bank extends credit (using the goods as
security) and requires a fixed repayment. The banks transaction is purely financial it gives the
loan to the business and gets back the principal plus interest at a later date. The Islamic alternative
is for the bank to buy the goods and resell them to the business at a profit, with deferred payment
due upon sale. In appearance this transaction is quite similar, but it means that the bank bears
some extra risks associated with the real part of the transaction, which would not be present in a
purely financial transaction. There is a corresponding reduction in the risk to the business. If banks
are large and businesses small, such a re-allocation of risks may actually promote economic
efficiency.
If the insurance company actually transports goods, and provides guarantee of safe delivery, this
may provide Islamically valid justification for an insurance payment upon loss.
Q2:219 They ask thee how much they are to spend; Say: What is beyond your needs.

83

84

Working Paper 22

43

44

45

46

For example, a leading economics textbook (Samuelson and Nordhaus, 1985) mentions poverty
only tangentially, and states that economists should study how to help the poor without harming
production efficiency. In the Reagan era in the USA, tax cuts for the rich were justified on the
grounds that they would invest and create more wealth, while the poor would only consume the tax
cuts . Theories of human capital view humans as inputs to production of wealth, rather than
wealth as an input to human welfare. Nobel Laureate Milton Friedman (2005) argues that it is the
responsibility of firms to pursue wealth, not social goals.
The gradual abdication of social responsibilities to the state has led to major problems for welfare
systems. The state cannot efficiently assess local needs and provide for them. Moreover, taxes to
finance needs are often viewed as unjust and unfair, since they are often not targeted to the social
needs perceived as the most urgent by those being taxed. In this context, it is interesting to note
that an attempt was made by the Reagan administration in the USA to put the responsibility for old
age parental care back on children. However, changes in social norms are hard to reverse.
No evidence is offered for whether or not this increasing dysfunctionality actually took place. An
alternative view more in accordance with history is that dismantling of Islamic legal structures
allowed opportunistic governments to seize assets of Awqaf, which led to breakdowns in their
functionality.
Some secular traditions also provide strong support for this idea of spending excess wealth on
others in need. See Singer (1972) for a powerful argument based on utilitarian ethics, which has
been very influential.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

References
Aghnides, Nicolas P. (1961) Mohammedan Theories Of Finance - With An Introduction To
Mohammedan Law And A Bibliography, Lahore: The Premier Book House.
Ahghari, Zohreh (1991) The Origin and Evolution of Islamic Economic Thought, Florida: Florida State
University, unpublished Ph.D. Thesis.
Ahmed Madani, Syed Hussain (1953) Naqsh-e-Hayat [Autobiography]. Delhi: Al-Jameeah Press.
Ahmad, Mushtaq (1995) Business Ethics in Islam, Islamabad: IIIT and IRI Press.
Ahmed, Habib (2004) Role of Zakah and Awqaf in Poverty Alleviation, Jeddah: IRTI Press.
Downloadable from IRTI/IDB website.
Akram, Shaikh Muhammad (1975) Ab-e-Kausar, Moj-e-Kausar, Rod-e-Kausar, [Religious and
Educational History of Muslims in India-Pakistan, 3 volumes] Karachi: Ferozsons.
Akyol, Mustafa (2004) Whats right with Turkey. Front Page Magazine, December.
www.thewhitepath.com/archives/2004
Akyol, Mustafa (2006) Symposium on Islam and religious freedom. Front Page Magazine http://
www.frontpagemag.com/Articles/ReadArticle.asp?ID=24999
Alam, M. S. (Spring 2002) Bernard Lewis: scholarship or sophistry? Studies in
Contemporary Islam, 4(1) pp. 53-80.
Al-Attas, Syed Muhammad Naquib (1984) Islam and Secularism. Delhi: Hindustan Publications.
Al-Dareer, Siddiq (1997) Al Gharar in Contracts and Its Effect on Contemporary Transactions,
Eminent Scholars Lecture Series, Jeddah: IRTI/IDB Press
Al-Faruqi, Ismail (1982) Islamization of Knowledge. Herndon, VA: International Institute of Islamic
Thought (IIIT).
Al-Sadr, Muhammad Baqir (1961) Iqtisaduna translated as Our Economy, London: Bookextra, 2000.
Ali Thanvi, Maulana Ashraf (1931) Tareeq-ul-Qalandar, Karachi: Kutub Khana Mazhari.
Ali Saheb Bijnori, Maulana Riyasat (1997) Shoora ki Shari Haysiat, [The Legal Status of
Consultation], Sadiqabad, Pakistan: Ahsan-ul-Mataba
Anjum, M. Iqbal (1995) An Islamic scheme of equitable distribution of income and wealth, American
Journal of Islamic Social Sciences, 12(2), pp. 224-39.
Ansari, Javed Akbar (2000) Islamising capitalist finance. Business and Finance Review, Monday,
August 7.
Ansari, Javed Akbar and Arshad, S. Zeeshan (2006) Business Ethics in Pakistan. Karachi: Royal Book
Company.
Arendt, Hannah (2006) Eichmann in Jerusalem: A Report on the Banality of Evil, Harmondsworth:
Penguin Classics.
Ariff, Mohamed (1419H/Nov 1998) The Malaysian economic experience and Its relevance for the OIC
member countries. Rajab, 6(1), pp. 1-42.
Arrighi, Giovanni (1997) Globalization, state sovereignty, and the endless accumulation of Capital
(Revised version of a paper presented at the Conference on States and Sovereignty in the World
Economy, Irvine: University of California, Feb. 21-23. http://www.binghamton.edu/fbc/gairvn97.htm
Ayub, M.N. (2002) Islamic Banking and Finance: Theory and Practice. Karachi: SBP Press.
Ayub, M.N. (2007) Islamic banking in Pakistan: an appraisal in historical perspective. Birmingham:
Religions and Development Research Programme (mimeo).
Azid, Toseef (2005) The concept and nature of labor in Islam: a survey, Review of Islamic Economics,
9(2), pp. 1-27
Aziz, Abdel (1992) Firm level decisions and human resource development in an Islamic economy. In
Ahmed, Ehsan (Ed) Economic Growth and Human Development in an Islamic Perspective:
Proceedings of the Fourth International Islamic Economics Seminar, Issues in Contemporary
Islamic Thought, Herndon, VA: The International Institute of Islamic Thought, 11, pp. 45-59.

85

86

Working Paper 22

Aziz, T. M. (1993) An Islamic perspective of political economy: The views of (late) Muhammad Baqir alSadr. Al-Tawhid Islamic Journal, 10(1)
http://www.al-islam.org/al-tawhid/politicaleconomy
Beinin, Joel (2004) Political Islam and the new global economy: The political economy of Islamist
social movements in Egypt and Turkey. Paper to the conference on French and US Approaches to
Understanding Islam, France-Stanford Center for Interdisciplinary Studies, September 12-14.
Benard, Cheryl (2004), Civil Democratic Islam: Partners, Resources, and Strategies, Washington
D.C.:RAND report MR-1716-CMEPP.
Bendjilali, Boualem and Khan, Tariqullah (1995) Economics of Diminishing Musharka, Jeddah: Islamic
Research and Training Institute Research Paper.
Birvndhavaradarajan, D. (1992) Moral dimensions of resource utilization, Journal of Objective Studies,
4(20) pp. 1-9.
Black, Antony (2001) The History of Islamic Political Thought: From the Prophet to the Present,
Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
Blaug, Mark (1998) Disturbing currents in modern economics, Challenge, May-June.
Camerer, Colin F. (2003) Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction, Princeton
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Capen, E.C., Clapp, R.V. and Campbell, W.M.(1971) Competitive bidding in high risk situations,
Journal of Petroleum Technology, June, pp. 641-53.
Chapra, M. Umer (1985) Towards a Just Monetary System, Leicester: The Islamic Foundation.
Chapra, M. Umer (1993) Islam and Economic Development, Islamabad: IIIT, IRI Press.
Chapra, M. Umer (1995) The Islamic welfare state and its role in the economy, in Gulaid, M.A. and
Abdullah, M.A. (Eds) Readings in Public Finance in Islam, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training
Institute.
Chapra, M. Umer (2000) The Future Of Economics: An Islamic Perspective, Leicester : The Islamic
Foundation.
Chapra, M. Umer (2004) Mawlana Mawdudis contribution to Islamic economics, The Muslim World,
94(April), pp. 163-180.
Choudhury, M. A. and Salleh, M. S. (1993) Grassroots approach to sustainable development: Dar alArqam Way in Malaysia. Paper presented at Canadian Economic Association, the Learned
Societies Conference, Carleton University, Ottawa, Canada, June 6, 1993.
Coase, Ronald (1960) The problem of social cost, The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, pp.1-44.
Dalrymple, William (2004) The hidden truths about Muslims, New York Review of Books, November 4,
pp. 31-34, http://www.nybooks.com/articles/17516
Dalrymple, William (2006) The Last Mughal: The Fall of a Dynasty. Delhi. 1857, London: Bloomsbury
Publishing.
de Soto, Hernandez (2000) The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails
Everywhere Else. London: Black Swan.
Douthwaite, Richard (1992) The Growth Illusion, Bideford: Green Books.
Egami, T. (1990) Labor and Action in Islam: Searching for an Outlook on Lost Labor, International
University of Japan, Institute of Middle Eastern Studies, Unpublished Masters dissertation.
El-Gamal, Mahmoud Amin (2000) A Basic Guide to Contemporary Islamic Banking and Finance,
Houston, Texas: Rice University, June http://www.ruf.rice.edu/elgamal
Elhiraika, Adam B. (2003) On the Experience Of Islamic Agricultural Finance In Sudan: Challenges
And Sustainability, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute.
Elhiraika, Adam B. (2004) On the Design and Effects of Monetary Policy in an Islamic Framework:
The Experience of Sudan, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Elhiraika, Adam B. and Ismail, Khalid Abu (2000) Financial Sector Policy and Poverty Reduction In
Sudan, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute, Working Paper 0411.
El-Ghazali, Abdel Hamid (1994) Man is the Basis of the Islamic Strategy for Economic Development.
Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute.
Faizer, Rizwi S. (2007) Rizwis Bibliography for Medieval Islam: Waqf, Mosque and Madrassah in
Medieval Islam, http://us.geocities.com/rfaizer/biblio/islam_inst_6.html
Farhadian, Mahdy (2002) Economic Reconstruction of Iran: From Monarchist
Modernization to Socio-Islamic Liberalism. Germany: University of Regensburg, Ph.D. Thesis.
http://ssgdoc.bibliothek.uni-halle.de/vlib/ssgfi/infodata/003522.html
Faridi, F.R. (1414H/1994) A case for Islamic economics: an Indian perspective.
Journal of Objective Studies, 6(I), pp. 157 168
Faruqui, Naser I., Biswas, Asit K. and Bino, Murad J. (Eds) (2001) Water Management In Islam,
Tokyo: UNU Press.
Feldman, Noah (2003) After Jihad: America and the Struggle for Islamic Democracy, New York:
Farrar, Straus and Giroux
Foltz, Richard C., Denny, Frederick M. and Baharuddin, Azizan (Eds) (2003) Islam and Ecology: A
Bestowed Trust. Cambridge, USA: Harvard Center for the Study of World Religions.
Friedman, Milton (2005) Rethinking the social responsibility of business: A Reason debate featuring
Milton Friedman, Whole Foods John Mackey, and Cypress Semiconductors T.J. Rodgers.
October Print Edition http://www.reason.com/news/show/32239.html
Fukuda-Parr, Sakiko (2004) Human Development Report: Cultural Liberty in Todays Diverse World,
New York: Oxford University Press.
Fukuyama, Francis (1992) The End of History and the Last Man, London: Hamish Hamilton.
Fromkin, David (1991) A Peace to End All Peace, Harmondsworth: Penguin.
George, Henry (1879) Progress and Poverty: An Inquiry into the Cause of Industrial Depressions and
of Increase of Want with Increase of Wealth: The Remedy, republished NY: Cosimo Classics 2006.
Ghazali, Aidit Bin Hj (Ed) (1993) Islam and Justice, Kuala Lumpur: IKIM
Ghazanfar, S.M. (Ed) (2003) Medieval Islamic Economic Thought: Filling the Great Gap in European
Economics. London: Routledge/Curzon.
Ghazi, Mahmood Ahmad et. al. (1992) Report on Islamic Insurance System, Islamabad: Government
of Pakistan, Council of Islamic Ideology.
Glover, Jonathan (2001) Humanity: A Moral History of the Twentieth Century, Yale: Yale University
Press.
Goody, Jack (2007) The Theft of History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Gordon, Scott (1991) The History and Philosophy of Social Science: An Introduction, New York:
Routledge.
Grace, L. and Al-ZamZami, A. (2001) Islamic Banking Principles Applied to Microfinance Case Study:
Hodeidah Microfinance Program, Yemen. United Nations Capital Development Fund (UNCDF).
Gul, Faruk and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang (2007) Welfare without happiness, American Economic
Review, 97(2), pp. 471-476.
Gulaid, Mahmoud A. (1991) Land Ownership in Islam, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute.
Gulaid, M.A. and Abdullah, M.A. (Eds) (1995) Readings in Public Finance in Islam, Jeddah: Islamic
Research and Training Institute.
Hacking, Ian (1983) Representing and Intervening: Introductory Topics in the Philosophy of Natural
Science, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
Hafiz, Mohammad Ahmed and Mahboob-ul-Hasan, Syed (Eds) (2006) Sarmayadarana Nizam: Aik
Tanqeedi Jaiza [Capitalism: A Critical Analysis], Karachi.

87

88

Working Paper 22

Hajib, Yusuf Khass (ca. 1070), Wisdom of Royal Glory (Kutadgu Bilig): A Turko-Islamic Mirror for
Princes, translated 1983, with an introduction and notes, by Robert Dankoff. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Harrington, Michael (1985) Politics at Gods Funeral, Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Hart, Michael (2000) The 100: A Ranking Of The Most Influential Persons In History, Citadel.
Hasanuzzaman, S.M. (1980) The objectives of economic policy in the early Islamic period. In The
Economic System of Islam, Karachi: National Bank of Pakistan, Karachi.
Hasanuzzaman, S.M. (1981) The Economic Functions of the Early Islamic State. Karachi:
International Islamic Publishers.
Hasanuzzaman, S.M. (1999) Economic Guidelines in the Quran, Islamabad: IIIT and IRI Press,
Islamization of Knowledge, vol 21.
Hegel, G. W. F, (1837) Lectures on the Philosophy of World History, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, reprinted 1981.
Himmelfarb, Gertrude (1996) The De-moralization Of Society: From Victorian Virtues to Modern
Values, New York: Vintage (Random House).
Hirsh, Michael (2004) Bernard Lewis revisited: what if Islam isnt an obstacle to democracy in the
Middle East but the secret to achieving it? Washington Monthly, Nov http://
www.washingtonmonthly.com/features/2004/0411.hirsh.html
Hodgson, Marshall (1974) The Venture of Islam: Conscience and History in a World Civilization, in
three volumes. Chicago, ILL: University of Chicago Press.
Hodgson, Marshall and Burke, Edmund (1993) Rethinking World History: Essays on Europe, Islam
and World History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Hoexter, Miriam, Eusenstadt, Schmuel N. and Leutzion, Nehemia (2002) The Public Sphere in Muslim
Societies, New York: State University of New York.
Hosseini, Hamid (1988) Notions of private property in Islamic economics in contemporary Iran: a
review of literature. International Journal of Social Economics, 15(9), pp. 51-61.
Hosseini, Hamid (1992) From homo economicus to homo Islamicus: the universality of economic
science reconsidered. In Bina, Cyrus and Zanganeh, Hamid (Eds) Modern Capitalism and Islamic
Ideology in Iran. New York: St. Martins Press.
IIBI (Institute of Islamic Banking and Insurance) (1992) Encyclopaedia of Islamic Banking and
Insurance, London: IIBI.
IRTI (Islamic Research and Training Institute) (1995) Tabung Haji as an Islamic Financial Institution:
The Mobilization of Investment Resources in an Islamic way and the Management of Haj, Jeddah:
IDB Press, downloadable from IRTI/IDB website.
Iqbal, Munawar (1995) Distributive Justice and Need Fulfillment in an Islamic Economy, Islamabad:
International Islamic University of Islamabad, International Institute of Islamic Economics.
Iqbal, Munawar (Ed) (2005) Islamic Perspectives on Sustainable Development. Basingstoke: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Iqbal, Munawar and Khan, Tariqullah (2004) Financing Public Expenditure: An Islamic Perspective
Jeddah: IRTI, IDB
Iqbal, Zamir and Mirakhor, Abbas (2005) The stakeholders model of governance in an Islamic
economic system. In Iqbal, M. (Ed) Islamic Perspectives on Sustainable Development,
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Islahi, Abdul Azim (2003) Waqf: A Bibliography, Jeddah: King Abdul-Aziz University, Scientific
Publishing Center http://islamiccenter.kaau.edu.sa/english/Publications/Islahi/
Waqf%20A%20Bibliography.pdf

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Islahi, Abdul Azim (2004) Zakah: A Bibliography, Jeddah: King Abdul-Aziz University, Scientific
Publishing Center. http://islamiccenter.kaau.edu.sa/english/Publications/Islahi/
Zakah%20A%20Bibliography.pdf
Islahi, Abdul Azim (2008) Thirty Years of Research on History of Islamic Economic Thought:
Assessment and Future Directions, Conference Papers, The 7th International Conference in
Islamic Economics: Thirty Years of Research in Islamic Economics, Jeddah: 1-3 April 2008, pp.
123-134 www.islamiccenter.kaau.edu.sa/7iecon/English/Englisg%20Papers/
%5B25%5D%20A.Islahi.pdf
Issawi, Charles (1984) The adaptation of Islam to contemporary economic realities. In Haddad, Y. et al
(Eds) The Islamic Impact, Syracuse NY: Syracuse University Press, pp. 27-45.
Jones, Norman (1989) God and the Moneylenders: Usury and Law in Early Modern England. Oxford:
Blackwell.
Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E. (Eds) (1995) The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton,
USA: Princeton University Press.
Kahf, Monzer (1991) The economic role of the state in Islam. Lecture presented at the seminar on
Islamic Economics, Dacca, Bangladesh. www.monzer.kahf.com
Kahf, Monzer (1995a) The Islamic state and the welfare state: similarities and differences. In Gulaid,
M.A. and Abdullah, M.A. (Eds) Readings in Public Finance in Islam. Jeddah: Islamic Research and
Training Institute.
Kahf, Monzer (1995b) Taxation policy in an Islamic economy. In Gulaid, M.A. and Abdullah, M.A. (Eds)
Readings in Public Finance in Islam. Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute.
Kahf, Monzer (1996a) Market and prices, Chapter 6 in Principles of Islamic Economics, Kuala
Lampur: International Islamic University Malaysia.
Kahf, Monzer (1996b) The demand side or consumer behaviour, Chapter 4 in Principles of Islamic
Economics, Kuala Lampur, International Islamic University Malaysia.
Kahf, Monzer (1998a) Concept of ownership in Islam. In Kahf, M. (Ed) Lessons in Islamic Economics,
Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute.
Kahf, Monzer (1998b) Financing the development of awqaf property. Paper prepared for Seminar on
Development of Awqaf, Kuala Lumpur: Islamic Research and Training Institute, March 2-4.
Kahf, Monzer (2000) Waqf and its Sociopolitical Aspects. www.monzer.kahf.com
Kahf, Monzer (2003) Sustainable Development in the Muslim Countries, Jeddah: Islamic Research
and Training Institute.
Kahf, Monzer (2004) Islamic economics: what went wrong? Paper presented at Islamic Development
Bank Roundtable on Islamic Economics: Current State of Knowledge and Development of the
Discipline, Jeddah May 26-27.
Kahf, Monzer (undated) Infaq in the Islamic Economic System, Undated. Available from
www.monzer.kahf.com
Kalin, Ibrahim (2002) Three views of science in the Islamic world, In Peters, R. Iqbal, Muzaffar and
Haq, Syed Nomanul (Eds) God, Life and the Cosmos: Christian and Islamic Perspectives,
Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 43-75.
Kazmi, Yedullah (2005) The rise and fall of culture of learning in early Islam, Islamic Studies, 44(1), pp.
15-52.
Khan, Ali (2004) Self-interest, self deception, and the ethics of commerce. Paper presented at Islamic
Development Bank Roundtable on Islamic Economics: Current State of Knowledge and
Development of the Discipline, Jeddah May 26-27
Khan, Atiquzzafar (2005) Insurance aur IjtimaI Fiqhi Idaron ki Ara [Insurance and the Opinions of
Collective Institutions of Fiqh], Paper presented at Seminar on Collective Ijtihad, Evolutionary
Change and Practical Methods, held at IRI, Islamabad.

89

90

Working Paper 22

Khan, Mohammad Akram (1983) Islamic Economics: Annotated Sources in English and Urdu (vol 1),
Leicester: Islamic Foundation.
Khan, Mohammad Akram (1989) Economic Teachings of Prophet Mohammad, International Institute of
Islamic Economics and Institute of Policy Studies, Rawalpindi: Pap-Board Publishers.
Khan, Mohammad Akram (1991) Islamic Economics: Annotated Sources in English and Urdu (vol 2),
Leicester: Islamic Foundation.
Khan, Mohammad Akram (1998) Islamic Economics: An Annotated Bibliography (vol 3), International
Institute of Islamic Economics, International Islamic University, Islamabad: IRI Press.
Khan, M. Fahim (2002) Fiqh foundations of the theory of Islamic economics: a survey of selected
contemporary writings on economics - relevant subjects of fiqh. In Ahmed, H. (Ed) Theoretical
Foundations of Isamic Economics, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute Book of
Readings No 3.
Khan, M. Fahim (2003) Consumer Behavior, Sustainable Development, and Islam, Jeddah: Islamic
Research and Training Institute (mimeo).
Khan, Tariqullah and Iqbal, Munawar (Eds) (2005) Financial Engineering and Islamic Contracts.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Khan, Waqar Masood (2002) Transition to a Riba Free Economy, Islamabad: International Institute of
Islamic Thought and Islamic Research Institute.
Kirchgssner, Gebhard (2005) (Why) are economists different? European Journal of Political
Economy, 21(3), pp. 543-562.
Kuhn, T.S. (1970) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 2nd. ed., Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press.
Kuran, Timur (1997) The genesis of Islamic economics: a chapter in the politics of Muslim identity.
Social Research, 64(2), pp. 301-338.
Kuran, Timur (2004) Why the Middle East is economically underdeveloped: historical mechanisms of
institutional stagnation, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), pp. 71-90.
Kusha, H.R. (1989) Social Justice: From the Islamic World-System to the European WorldEconomy, a Study of Power Legitimation, Kentucky VA: University of Kentucky, PhD thesis.
Lane, Robert E. (2001) Loss of Happiness in Market Economies, Yale: Yale University Press.
Lau, Martin (2006) Role of Islam in the Legal System of Pakistan. Leiden: Martinus Nijhoff, LondonLeiden Series on Law, Administration and Development.
Layard, Richard (2005) Happiness: Lessons from a New Science, Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Ledyard, John O. (1995) Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In Kagel, John H. and Roth,
Alvin E. (Eds) The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Lewin Group (2005) The Health Care For All Californians Act: Cost and Economic Impacts, January
19.
Lewis, B. (2003a) The Crisis of Islam: Holy War and Unholy Terror, New York: Modern Library.
Lewis, B. (2003b) What Went Wrong?: The Clash Between Islam and Modernity in the Middle East,
London: Harper Perennial.
Lopez, Robert S. (1976) The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages 950-1350, Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Lowney, Chris (2005) A Vanished World: Medieval Spains Golden Age of Enlightenment, New York:
Free Press.
Makdisi, George (1990) The Rise of Humanism in Classical Islam and the Christian West: With
Special Reference to Scholasticism, Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
Manicas, Peter T. (1989) A History and Philosophy of the Social Sciences, Oxford: Blackwell
Publishers.
Mansoori, Mohammad Tahir (2005) Ahkaam Bai [Commandments for Sales], Islamabad: International
Islamic University of Islamabad, Islamic Research Institute, February.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Marglin, Frederique Appfel (2007) Dominating Knowledge: Development, Culture and Resistance,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Masud, Khalid (1995) Shatibis Philosophy of Islamic Law, Islamabad: International Islamic University of
Islamabad, Islamic Research Institute.
Maududi, Sayyid Abul Ala (1947 [1041]) Insan ka Maashi Masalah aur us ka Islami Hal, [Economic
Problem of Man and its Islamic Solution], Lahore: Islamic Publications, download from: http://
www.millat.com/quranpak/modoodi/index.shtml
Maududi, Sayyid Abul Ala (1960) Islamic Law and Constitution, In Ahmad, Khurshid (Trans. and Ed),
Lahore: Islamic Publications
Maududi, Sayyid Abul Ala (1963) Economic and political teachings of the Quran. In Sharif, M.M. (Ed) A
History of Muslim Philosophy, Wiesbaden: Low Price Publications, vol. 1, pp. 178-198.
Maududi, Sayyid Abul Ala (1969) Quran ki Maashi Talimat (Economic Teachings of the Quran),
Lahore: Islamic Publications
Maududi, Sayyid Abul Ala (1970) Maashiyat-e Islam [Economic System of Islam], Lahore: Islamic
Publications. http://www.teachislam.com
index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=135&Itemid=121
McCloskey, D.N. (1984) The Rhetoric of Economics, Wisconsin: University of Wisconsin Press, 2nd
edition (1998)
Menocal, Maria Rosa (2002) The Ornament of the World: How Muslims, Jews and Christians Created
a Culture of Tolerance in Medieval Spain, USA: Little, Brown and Co.
Mill, John Stuart (1859) On Liberty, republished by Harmondsworth: Penguin Classics. 1984.
Mintjes, H.J. (1978) The debate on Islamic socialism in Pakistan, Al-Mushir, Rawalpindi, 20(1,2,4) pp.
24-44, 48-72, 152-169,.
Mirakhor, Abbas (1983) Muslim contribution to economics. Paper presented at the annual meeting of
the South-Western Economic Association, March 1983; reproduced in Essays on Iqtisad; Nur
Corp. (1989); Republished by Global Scholarly Publication, New York, NY (2003).
Mirakhor, Abbas (2005) A Note on Islamic Economics, writeup of presentation at Jeddah: Islamic
Research and Training Institute (April).
Mirakhor, Abbas (2007) Globalization and Islamic finance In Munawar Iqbal, Salman Syed Ali, and
Dadang Muljawan (Eds) Advances in Islamic Economics and Finance Vol. 1, Proceedings of The
6th International Conference on Islamic Economics and Finance., Jeddah: Islamic Research and
Training Institute.
Mirowski, Philip (1989) More Heat than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Natures
Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mitchell, Timothy (2002) Rule of Experts: Egypt, Techno-Politics, and Modernity, Berkeley: University
of California Press.
Monroe, Kirsten Renwick (ed.) (2005) Perestroika!: The Raucous Rebellion in Political Science, Yale:
Yale University Press.
Mortazavi, Saeed (2004) Islamic economics: a solution for environmental protection, paper presented
at conference on Trade, Growth and the Environment at Oxford University, August 8 August 13.
http://hdl.handle.net/2148/220
Muqorobin, Masyhudi (2008) Journey of Islamic economics in the modern world, Proceedings of The
Seventh International Conference on Islamic Economics, pp. 385-404.
Nadvi, Maulana Syed Abul Hassan Ali (1980) Muslim Mamalik main islamiat or maghribiat ki
Kashmakash The struggle between Islamization and Westernization in Muslim Countries.
Karachi: Majlis-e-Nashriyate Islam.
Nadvi, Maulana Syed Abul Hassan Ali (1986) Tahzeeb aur Tamaddun par Islam kay Ihsanat aur Asarat.
[The Gifts and Effects of Islam on World Culture and Civilization], Karachi: Majlis-e-Nashriat-eIslam.

91

92

Working Paper 22

Najam, Adil (2007) Portrait of A Giving Community: Philanthropy by the Pakistani-American Diaspora,
Harvard: Harvard University Press, 2007.
Naylor, R.T. (2007) Satanic Purses: Money, Myth, and Misinformation in the War on Terror. Montreal:
McGill-Queens University Press.
Naz, M.S. (1999) Islami Riyasat main Muhtasib ka Kirdar [The Role of the Muhtasib in an Islamic
State] Islamabad: International Islamic University of Islamabad, Islamic Research Institute.
Nelson, Benjamin (1969) The Idea of Usury: From Universal Brotherhood to Universal Otherhood,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press
Nelson, Robert H. (2001) Economics as Religion: From Samuleson to Chicago and Beyond,
Pennsylvania: Pennsylvania State University Press.
New Zealand MCA (2005) Review of the Enforcement of Consumer Protection Law: An Initial Think
Piece, Auckland: Ministry of Consumer Affairs (July).
Niblock, Tim and Wilson, Rodney (Eds) (1999) The Political Economy of the Middle East. Volume 3
Islamic economics. Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Elgar Reference Collection.
Noori, Yahya (1986) Legal and Political Structure of an Islamic State: The Implications for Iran and
Pakistan. Glasgow: Royston.
Nyazee, Imran Ahsan Khan (1994) Theories of Islamic Law: The Methodology of Ijtihad, Islamabad:
International Islamic University of Islamabad, Islamic Research Institute and IIIT, Perspectives on
Islamic Thought, volume 3.
Nyazee, Imran Ahsan Khan (1997) Islamic Law of Business Organizations: Partnerships, Islamabad:
International Islamic University of Islamabad, Islamic Research Institute and IIIT, Islamic Law and
Jurisprudence Series, volume 1.
Nyazee, Imran Ahsan Khan (1998) Islamic Law of Business Organizations: Corporations, Islamabad:
International Islamic University of Islamabad, Islamic and IIIT, Islamic Law and Jurisprudence
Series, volume 2.
Olson, Richard (1990) Science Deified and Science Defied: The Historical Significance of Science in
Western Culture, volume 2, Berkeley: University of California Press.
Pfeifer, Karen (1996) Is there an Islamic economics? In Beinin, Joel and Stork, J. (Eds) Political
Islam, Berkeley: University of California Press.
Pfeifer, Karen (2001) Islamic business and business as usual: a study of firms in Egypt. Development
in Practice, 11(1), pp. 20-33.
Pfeifer, Karen (2006) Islam and labor law: some precepts and examples. In Sohrab Behdad and
Farhad Nomani (Eds) Islam and Every Day Life: Public Policy Dilemma London: Routledge Curzon
Press, pp. 113-140
Piscatori, James (1986) Islam in a World of Nation States, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Pitofsky, Robert (1977) Beyond Nader: consumer protection and the regulation of advertising,
Harvard Law Review, 90(4), pp. 661-701.
Pomeranz, Felix (1995) Business ethics: the perspective of Islam. The American Journal of Islamic
Social Sciences, 12(3), pp. 400-404.
Qardawi (1981, republished 1997) Economic Security in Islam, USA: Islamic Book Services
Qureshi, Ishtiaq Hussain (1975) Education in Pakistan, Karachi: Maref Printers.
Rahman, A.R.A. (1995) An Islamic perspective on organizational motivation. American Journal of
Islamic Social Sciences, 12(2) pp. 115-124.
Reuben, Julie A. (1996) The Making of the Modern University: Intellectual Transformation and the
Marginalization of Morality, Chicago: University of Chicago Press
Robbins, Richard (2007) Global Problems and the Culture of Capitalism, Boston, MA: Allyn and Bacon.
Rodinson, Maxime (1966) Islam et le Capitalisme, Paris: Editions du Seuil, translation by B. Pearce:
Islam and Capitalism, Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1977.

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Rosly, Saiful Azhar (2005) Critical Issues on Islamic Banking and Financial Markets: Islamic
Economics, Banking and Finance, Investments, Takaful and Financial Planning, Indiana:
AuthorHouse (21 Feb).
Rostow, W.W. (1978) The World Economy: History and Prospect, Austin: University of Texas.
Sachedina, Abdulaziz (n.d.) The issue of Riba in Islamic faith and law, University of Virginia http://
people.virginia.edu/~aas/article/article7.htm , accessed 9 July 2007.
Sadeq, A.H.M. and Ghazali, Aidit (Eds) (1992) Readings in Islamic Economic Thought, Kuala Lumpur:
Longman Malaysia.
Said, Edward (1978) Orientalism, London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Said, Hakim Mohammad (1972) The Employer and the Employee: Islamic Concept. Karachi: Dar AlFikr Al-Islami .
Sait, Siraj and Lim, Hilary (2005) Islamic Land and Property Research Series, Nairobi: UN-Habitat,
Series of Eight Position Papers. 1: Islamic Land theories and Applications. 2: Islamic Land
Tenure and Reforms. 3: Islamic Law, Land and Methodologies. 4: Islamic Human Rights and
Land. 5: Muslim Womens Right to Property. 6: Islamic Inheritance Laws and Systems. 7:
Islamic Endowments (Waqf) and Indigenous Philanthropy, 8: Islamic Credit and Microfinance
Sait, Siraj and Lim, Hilary (2006) Land, Law and Islam: Property and Human Rights in the Muslim
World, London: Zed.
Samuelson, P.A. and Nordhaus, W. (1985) Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill, 12th ed.
Schumpeter, J.A. (1974) History of Economic Analysis, London: George Allen and Unwin.
Sen, Amartya (1999) Development as Freedom, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Shafi, Mufti Muhammad (1978) Distribution of Wealth in Islam, translated into English by: Askari, M.
Hasan and Husain, Karrar, Karachi: Aisha Bawani Waqf and Ashraf Publications.
Shafi, Mufti Muhammad (1979) Islam ka Nizam-e Arazi, [The System of Land-Tenure in Islam],
Karachi: Idara-tul-Maarif.
Shalaby, Ahmed. 1954. History of Muslim Education. Ph.D. Thesis Cambridge University.
Republished: Beirut, Lebanon: Dar al-Kashaf. Urdu translation by M. Hussain Zubairi: Tareekh-eTaleem o Tarbiyat-e Islamia Lahore: Idara Saqafate Islamiya,1989
Shirazi, Naseem Shah (2006) Reducing poverty through the institution of Zakat, Islamabad:
International Institute of Islamic Economics and Birmingham: Religions and Development Research
Programme (mimeo).
Sibai, Mustafa (1982) Islamic socialism. In Donohue, J.J. and Esposito, J.L. (Eds) Islam in Transition,
New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 120-2.
Siddiqi, Mohammad Nejatullah (1980) Muslim economic thinking: A survey of contemporary literature.
In Ahmad, Khurshid (Ed) Studies in Islamic Economics, Leicester: Islamic Foundation.
Siddiqi, Mohammad Nejatullah (1995) The guarantee of a minimal standard of living in an Islamic state.
In Iqbal, Munawar (Ed) Islamic Perspectives On Sustainable Development, Basingstoke: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Siddiqi, Mohammad Nejatullah (2004a) Keynote Address at Islamic Development Bank Roundtable on
Islamic Economics: Current State of Knowledge and Development of the Discipline, Jeddah, May
26-27.
Siddiqui, Mohammad Nejatullah (2004b) Riba, Bank Interest and the Rationale of its Prohibition,
Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute.
Siddiqui, S.A. (1948) Public Finance in Islam, Lahore: Ashraf Press, 1st edition.
Sidek, M.S.B. (1989) Islam and Development: An Ethical Analysis with Special Emphasis on Public
Resource Utilization in Malaysia. Philadelphia: Temple University, PhD thesis.
Sikand, Yoginder (2004) Reforming the Indian madrassas: contemporary Muslim voices. In Limaye,
Satu, Wirsing, Robert and Malik, Mohan (Eds) Religious Radicalism and Security in South Asia,
Honolulu: Asia Pacific Center for Security Studies http://www.apcss.org/text/text_research.htm

93

94

Working Paper 22

Singer, Peter (1972) Famine, affluence, and morality, Philosophy and Public Affairs 1, No. 3, reprinted
in William Aiken and Hugh LaFollette (Eds) World Hunger and Morality, Upper Saddle River:
Prentice Hall, 2nd ed. 1996.
Skidelsky, Robert (2001) Keynes and the Ethics of Capitalism, Paper presented at Boston
College,Chestnut Hill, MA http://www.geocities.com/monedem/keyn.html (Cites from The
future, Essays in Persuasion (1931) Ch. 5, John Maynard Keynes, CW, IX, pp. 329 - 331, from
Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren (1930)
Tahir, Sayyid (2007) Islamic banking theory and practice: a survey and bibliography of the 1995-2005
literature. Journal of Economic Cooperation among Islamic Countries. 28(1), pp. 1-72.
Tahir, Sayyid et. al. (1999) IIIEs Blueprint of Islamic Financial System, Islamabad: International Islamic
University of Islamabad, International Institute of Islamic Economics, Report of the IIIE Workshop on
Islamization of the Financial System.
Taseen, M. (1993) Islam ka Maashi Nizam [Economic System of Islam], Fikro Nazar, 30(3), pp. 79112.
Taseen, M. (1998) Quran aur Hadeeth ki Roshni main Islami Mashiat ka adilana Nizam [Just
Economic Teachings of Islam in Light of Quran and Hadeeth]. Karachi: Majlis-e-Ilmi Foundation
(September).
Taseen, M. (2001) Mutabadil Soodi Nizam Ke Daway [Claims of the (Islamic) Alternative to InterestBased Banks], Karachi: Gausha-e- Ilm-o-Tahqeeq.
Tawney, R.H. (1926) Religion and the Rise of Capitalism, New York: Harcourt, Brace & World, Inc.
Timberg, Thomas A. (2000) Islamic Banking in Indonesia, Jakarta: Partnership for Economic Growth.
Toynbee, Arnold (1951) Civilization on Trial, Oxford: Oxford University Press
Usmani, Habibur-Rahman and Shafi, Mufti Mohammad (1976) Islam main Mashwere ki Ahmiat [The
Importance of Consultation in Islam] Lahore: Alameen Publications.
Usmani, Maulana Taqi (1970) Hakeem-ul-Ummat kay Siyasi Afkar [Political Thought of Maulana
Ashraf Ali Thanvi], Karachi: Jamia Darul-Uloom.
Usmani, Maulana Taqi (1999) Text of the Historic Judgement Against Riba (23 December 1999) given
by the Supreme Court of Pakistan. www.failaka.com/Library/Articles/
Prohibition%20of%20Interest%20in%20Pakistan.pdf
Usmani, Maulana Taqi (2000) Introduction to Islamic Finance, Karachi: Idaratul Maarif.
Vadillo, Umar Ibrahim (n.d.) The fallacy of the Islamic bank, unpublished essay http://
www.geocities.com/Athens/Delphi/6588/bfallacy.html (accessed 22nd August 2007)
Van Fraassen, Bastiaan C. (1980) The Scientific Image , New York: Oxford University Press
Veblen, Thorstein (1899 [1924]) Theory of the Leisure Class, London: Allen and Unwin.
Walbridge, John (2002) Islamic concept of asking questions: Ilm-ul-Ikhtilaf, the institutionalization of
disagreement. Islamic Studies, 41(1) pp. 69-86.
Waliullah, Shah (1750, trans. 1995) Hujjat Allah Al-Baligha Hujjat, translated as The Conclusive
Argument from God by Marcia K. Hermansen, Leiden: Brill Academic Publishers.
Wallerstein, Immanuel (Ed) (1996) Open the Social Sciences: Report of the Gulbenkian Commission
on the Restructuring of the Social Sciences, Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Wallerstein, Immanuel (2006) European Universalism: The Rhetoric of Power, New York: New Press.
Weber, Max (1918) Science as a vocation, reprinted in (Transl. Gerth, H. H. and Mills, C. Wright) From
Max Weber: Essays in Sociology, Oxford: Oxford University Press,1958.
Weber, Max (1930) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, Transl. Parsons, Talcott, London:
Allen and Unwin.
Wilson, Andrew (Ed) (1991) World Scripture: A Comparative Anthology of Sacred Texts, International
Religious Foundation. http://www.unification.net/ws/ (accessed 22nd August, 2007)

Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

Wilson, Rodney (1998) The contribution of Muhammad Baqir Al-Sadr to contemporary Islamic
economic thought, Journal of Islamic Studies, 9(1), pp. 46-59.
Wolfe, Michael (1998), One Thousand Roads to Mecca: Ten Centuries of Travelers Writing about the
Muslim Pilgrimage, Tennessee: Grove Press.
World Bank (2006) Where is the Wealth of Nations, Washington DC: World Bank.
X, Malcolm with Haley, Alex (1965) The Autobiography of Malcolm X. New York: Grove Press.
Yousri Ahmad, Abdurrhaman (2004) Islamic economics: its development as a scientific discipline.
Paper presented at Islamic Development Bank Roundtable on Islamic Economics: Current State of
Knowledge and Development of the Discipline, Jeddah, May 26-27.
Yousri Ahmad, Abdurrhaman (2005) Sustainable development: an evaluation of conventional and
Islamic perspectives. In Iqbal, M. (Ed) Islamic Perspectives on Sustainable Development,
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Zaher, Tarek S. and Hassan, M. Kabir (2001) A comparative literature survey of Islamic finance and
banking, Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments, 10 (4), pp. 155199.
Zakariyya Kandehlvi, Shaikh-ul-Hadeeth Maulana Mohammad (1938) Al-Aitdal fil Maratib Al-Rajjal,
Lahore: Maktaba Zakariyya
Zakariya Kandehlvi, Shaikh-ul-Hadeeth Maulana Mohammad (1993) Virtues of Halal Earning and Trade
,South Africa: Ilmi Publications.
Zaman, Arshad (1989) Why development fails, Pakistan Administration, Pakistan Administrative Staff
College, Lahore, XXIV(1), pp. 27-44.
Zaman, Iftikhar (1985) Towards Islamic ways of Islamization: Problems in the modernization of the
Ahkaam of Shariah and Dawah, Pakistan Administration, XXII(2).
Zarqa, Anas (1994) Financing and investment in Awqaf projects: a non-technical introduction, Islamic
Economic Studies, 1(2), pp. 55-62.
Zarqa, Anas (1995) Islamic distributive schemes. In Gulaid, M.A. and Abdullah, M.A. (Eds) Readings in
Public Finance in Islam. Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training Institute (also in Iqbal, Ed, 2005).
This is a translation of original article in Arabic in Journal of Research in Islamic Economics Vol 2
No 1.
Ziauddin, Ahmad (1992) Public finance and fiscal policy in an Islamic perspective, In Ahmad, Ausaf and
Awan, Kazim Raza (Eds) Lectures on Islamic Economics, Jeddah: Islamic Research and Training
Institute.

95

Religions and Development


1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
16
17
18
21
22

Working Papers

Shah, R., Larbi, G. and Batley, R. Religion and Public Management Literature
Review
Nkurunziza, E. An Overview of Development Studies: Background Paper for
the Religions and Development Research Programme
Jackson, P. and Fleischer, C. Religion and Economics: A Literature Review
Tomalin, E. Sociology, Religion and Development: Literature Review
Bradley, T. The Relationships Between Religion and Development: Views
from Anthropology
Tomalin, E. Religious Studies and Development: A Literature Review
Alhassan Alolo, N. , Singh, G. and Marquette, H. Political Science, Religion and
Development: A Literature Review
Tomalin, E. Gender Studies Approaches to the Relationships between
Religion and Development
Rakodi, C. Understanding the Roles of Religions in Development: The
Approach of the RaD Programme
Religions and Development Research Programme, University of Birmingham.
(Editors) India: Some Reviews of Literature Related to Religions and
Development
Mhina, A. (Editor) Religions and Development in Tanzania: A Preliminary
Literature Review
Bano, M. with Nair, P. Faith-based Organisations in South Asia: Historical
Evolution, Current Status and Nature of Interaction with the State
Bano, M. Allowing for Diversity: State-Madrasa Relations in Bangladesh
Bano, M. Contesting Ideologies and Struggle for Authority: State-Madrasa
Engagement in Pakistan
Kim, K. Concepts of Development in the Christian Traditions: A Religions and
Development Background Paper
Alhassan Alolo, A. African Traditional Religions and Concepts of
Development: A Background Paper
Tomalin, E. Buddhism and Development: A Background Paper
Tatla, D. S. Sikhism and Development: A Review
Zaman, A. Islamic Economics: A Survey of the Literature

2007
2007
2007
2007
2007
2007
2007
2007
2007
2008
2007
2007
2008
2008
2007
2007
2007
2008
2008

ORDERING PUBLICATIONS
Publications can be obtained by either telephoning Carol Fowler on 44 (0) 121 414 4986
or Email: [email protected] and also downloaded as a PDF file from
www.rad.bham.ac.uk

You might also like