Week3d Land Rent
Week3d Land Rent
The term 'rent' is an unfortunate one. Its meanings in Economics differ from the ordinary usage. In the every day speech, the term, rent is applied to the periodic payments made regularly for the hire of a particular asset. For example, the payments made by a tenant to the owner of a house, or factory or land on weekly, monthly, or yearly basis is a rent in the popular sense. In Economics: "The concept of rent or to be more precise 'economic rent' is used in a special sense. According to the classical economists, rent is a price of land. It is a payment made by a tenant farmer to the landlord for the use of original and Indestructible powers of the soil".
Example:
For example, a typist is ready to work for $4600 per month in a college but he is paid $4900 per month. This is because of the fact that the market demand for the typists is greater than its supply. So long as the supply cannot be adjusted to demand the typist will continue earning a payment in excess of $4600 of the amount which is necessary to keep him in that occupation. This monthly surplus money of $300 (4900 4600 = $300) is an economic rent.
Assumptions:
(i) Rent Under Extensive Cultivation. (ii) Rent Under Intensive Cultivation.
Schedule:
Grades of Land A B C D Yield in Quintals per Acre 50 35 20 15 Price per Quintal ($) 50 60 70 80 Total Return ($) 2500 2100 1400 1200
In the above schedule, we assume that there are four grades of land A, B, C and D in an uninhabited country. A grade land is more fertile than B grade land. B grade land is superior to C grade and so is C grade to D grade land. Following Ricardo let us assume, a batch of settlers migrate to this island. They begin cultivating A grade land which yield 50 quintals of wheat per acre. Let us suppose now that the population of that country increases and A grade land is not sufficient to meet the food requirements of the growing population. The inhabitants of that country shall then have to bring under cultivation B grade land. With the identical amounts of labor and capital. B grade land yields 35 quintals of wheat per acre. A surplus of 15 quintal of wheat {50 - 35 = 15) which arises with the same outlay on A grade land is an economic rent. B grade land being a marginal land gives no rent. When owing to the pressure of growing population and a rise in demand for food, C grade land is brought under cultivation, it yields only 20 quintals of wheat with the identical amount of labor and capital. With the cultivation of C grade land, the economic rent of A grade land is now raised to 30 quintals per acre: (50 - 20 = 30) and that of B grade land 15 quintals of wheat per acre. C grade land is a no rent land as it is cultivated at the margin. If the expenses of production on A grade of land yielding 50 quintals of wheat are $2500 and the market price of total yield on A grade land is also $2500, then A grade land only will be brought under cultivation. A grade land here is the marginal land. If the price of agricultural produce increases ($60 per quintal) and the expenses of producing wheat on B grade land are equal to the market price of the produce i.e.. $2100, then B grade of land which was hitherto neglected would be brought under cultivation. B grade land then becomes the marginal land. Similarly, D grade land will be the marginal land when it
compensates the cultivator by giving a yield of $1200, and enjoys no surplus over cost. Marginal land is thus not fixed. It varies with the changes in the price of agricultural produce. If population increase still further and the demand for food increases, then D grade land will be brought under plough. The surplus or economic rent of A grade land will go up to 35 quintals (50 - 15 = 35), of B grade 20 quintals, of C grade 5 quintals. D grade land being the marginal land yields no rent.
Diagram:
The Ricardian model is now explained with the help of a diagram:
In the figure (19.1), the various grades of land in the descending order of fertility are plotted on OX axis and yield per acre is shown on OY axis. The cultivated area due to pressure of population and the rising demand for food is pushed to D grade of land which is a marginal land. The owner of A grade of land gets a surplus, or economic rent of 35 quintals of wheat, of B, 20 quintals and on C grade, the rent is 5 quintals of wheat.
when measured from the third or marginal dose is 15 quintal on second dose (15 -10 = 5). The third dose is a no rent dose.
rent equal to the marginal revenue productively of land. The rent diminishes as more land is used due to the operation of law of diminishing returns. The demand curve of a factor is, therefore, negatively sloped which means more land will be used only at lower rents, other things of course remaining the same. Supply of a factor. The supply of land to a particular use (say industry) is quite elastic. It can be shifted to other uses by offering higher rent than that being earned by it now. The supply of a factor (to an industry) is, therefore, rent elastic. If higher rent is paid, the supply of a factor can be increased by withdrawing it from other uses. The supply curve of a factor (industry) slopes upward to the right.
Determination of rent. The economic rent is determined by the intersection of demand and supply curves for a factor. In this figure (19.2), the demand curve for a factor say labor in a particular industry is DD/ and the supply curve of workers is SS/. The wage rate or factor price of labor as determined by the market forces is OW. The total workers employed in a particular industry at OW wage rate is OL. The total earning of the workers employed is equal to the area OWEL. At wage rate OW, there are workers who would work, at lower pay but they are also paid at OW wage rate. Those workers whose transfer earnings are less than this wage rate will be getting economic rent. The total economic rent earned by all the intra marginal workers is equal in the area WES. The marginal worker i.e., Lth worker is not obtaining any rent or surplus.
In the Fig. 19.3, the supply curve SS/ is a horizontal line. Whatever the amount of factor demanded, the supply price remains at OS. Hence, it earns no surplus in the nature of rent. (ii) Totally inelastic supply. When the supply of a factor is totally inelastic, then its transfer earnings is zero. The entire income is economic rent.
In the fig. 19.4, the elasticity of the supply of factor of production is zero. It does not increase at all as its demand increases. The supply curve is vertical. The entire of factor income is a surplus which is shown by area ONST. (iii) Less than perfectly elastic supply. If the supply of a factor of production is neither perfectly elastic nor perfectly inelastic as illustrated in fig.19.5, then some part of the factor income is economic rent and the other part is transfer earnings.
In Fig. 19.5, the supply curve SS/ of a factor, say labor, is positively sloped. A firm must pay at least OS price to attract OL units of labor to the given use. If supply of a factor is to rise, the factor must be paid higher and higher wages to attract more units. The demand curve DD / (measuring the marginal revenue product of the labor) interests the supply curve at point R. Now at OT equilibrium price, Quantity of the Factor ON units of labor are demanded and supplied. Since all the units of the Fig. 19.5 factor up to ON are paid the market price OT, the intra marginal units earn surplus above their supply price. The marginal unit i.e., Nth is not getting any rent. Here the total income of the factor is equal to the area OTRN. It is made up of its economic rent equal to the area STR and its transfer earnings equal to the area OSRN.
Example:
For instance, the cost of production of wheat per quintal in A, B, C and D grades of land is $30, $40, $50 and $60 respectively. Let us suppose that the price of wheat in the market is $40 per quintal. At this price only A and B grades of land will be brought under cultivation. The owner of A grade land will earn a surplus of $10 per quintal. If due to greater demand of wheat, price rises to $50 per quintal in the market, the owner of A grade land will earn $20 as rent and the owner of B $10, and the C grade land will be norent-land. If price happens to rise to $60, then D grade land will be cultivated and the rent per quintal of wheat for A, B and C grades of land will be $30, $20 and $10. Thus, we conclude, that higher the price, the higher is the rent and wee versa. In the words of Ricardo: "Corn is high, not because rent is paid, but rent is paid because corn is high". Or, in other, words, we can any that the prices of commodities are not high because the rents are high. The correct statement would be that rents are high because prices are high. Rent in brief is price determined and not price determining.
Modern View:
The modern economists, however, do not agree with the above view of Ricardo that rent does not enter into the price of land. They say that this inclusion (rent not entering into price) is valid only if we took at land from the point of view of the community as a whole; Ricardo did not consider the question of rent payment from the point of view of a single industry or in particular use. If we look at rent from the point of view of particular use, rent does become a part of price. This is evident from the concept of transfer earnings. A plot of land, as we know, has an alternative uses. It can be used for growing wheat, cotton, rice, sugar-cane, maize, etc. If it is put to one use, it cannot be used for any other purpose at the same time. We can either grow wheat or sugar-cane in it. The choice is before us. If we utilize it for growing wheat, then we will have to make payment at least equal to the amount which it would have brought when sugar-cane was to be grown in it. If the sum equal to the amount of transfer earning is not paid to the owner of sugar cane plot, then this land will not be available for growing wheat. The minimum price or payment that must be paid to the owner of plot for inducing him to make the land available for a growing of wheat is called transfer payment or transfer earning or transferring cost. Since transfer payments are part of the supply price from the point of view of an industry, therefore these enter into the cost of. production and determine the price of the product.
"Marshall is of the view that a differential surplus which arises from a factor of production, whose supply is fixed for all times to come should be named as rent but a temporary gain which a factor or production earns due to temporary limitation of its supply should be called quasi-rent".
Example:
For instance, the demand for shaving blades suddenly goes up in Canada and the price of a packet containing 10 blades rises from $15 to $20, The entrepreneurs lured by high profits will naturally try to produce more blades. They may try to meet the demand by working the factory for 24 hours. Let us suppose, the supply is still short of demand and the price remains at $20 per packet. The new entrepreneurs attracted by high profits will establish new factories. A factory cannot be established in a day. It needs time for installing new machinery. When new plants are set up, the supply of blades will increase and the price comes down to the level of their costs of production ($15). The temporary gain which the old factories have earned during the period when new factories were not installed, is regarded as earned during the period when new factories were not installed is regarded as quasi-rent. "Quasi-rent is, thus, a temporary gain which is earned by a factor of production due to the temporary limitation of its supply".
How does rent of Land differ from rent of; (a) Fisheries, (b) Mines and (c) Buildings?
(a) Rent of Land and Fisheries. If proper care of fisheries is taken and fishing is not done in the breeding season, then the rent of land and fisheries is very similar to each other. A fishery which is well located near the market will be in an advantageous position. Its produce will be marketed at a lesser cost than the other fisheries which are situated at some distance from the market. If the price of fish per kilo in the market is equal to the cost of operating it in the distant fisheries, then the fisheries which are situated near the market will earn a surplus. This differential gain or rent is all due to the factor of situation. If a fishery is more productive in the supply of fish than the other fisheries, then it will enjoy rent in the same way as a superior land enjoys over an inferior land. If fishing is done throughout the year, then the resources of the fisheries will be soon exhausted and the rent will be analogous to mines. (b) Rent of Land and Mines. Rent of mines stands on a different footing from rent of land. There is no doubt that mines are a part of free gift of Nature but they do not posses the quality of being indestructible. As mines are worked out, they soon get exhausted. It is not possible to gain its content by managing it as we do in the case of agricultural land. So the owner of the mines demands of reward, firstly, for the differential gain enjoyed by the mines over other mines and secondly, the compensation for the exhaustion of mine. This compensation is called "royalty". Thus, we find that the rent of land differs from mines as the owners of mines get rent proper as well as royalty.
(c) Rent of land and urban site land. Rent of land and rent of urban site do not differ fundamentally from each other. In the case of agricultural land, the fertility of the soil plays a very important part in the determination of rent. As regards urban site rent, it is situational advantage which plays the decisive role. For instance, if two houses quite similar to each other are situated at two different places, one in the heart of the city and the other in the suburb, the former will enjoy more rent than the later.