Work: A Deep History, from the Stone Age to the Age of Robots
By James Suzman
4/5
()
About this ebook
A revolutionary new history of humankind through the prism of work by leading anthropologist James Suzman
Work defines who we are. It determines our status, and dictates how, where, and with whom we spend most of our time. It mediates our self-worth and molds our values. But are we hard-wired to work as hard as we do? Did our Stone Age ancestors also live to work and work to live? And what might a world where work plays a far less important role look like?
To answer these questions, James Suzman charts a grand history of "work" from the origins of life on Earth to our ever more automated present, challenging some of our deepest assumptions about who we are. Drawing insights from anthropology, archaeology, evolutionary biology, zoology, physics, and economics, he shows that while we have evolved to find joy meaning and purpose in work, for most of human history our ancestors worked far less and thought very differently about work than we do now. He demonstrates how our contemporary culture of work has its roots in the agricultural revolution ten thousand years ago. Our sense of what it is to be human was transformed by the transition from foraging to food production, and, later, our migration to cities. Since then, our relationships with one another and with our environments, and even our sense of the passage of time, have not been the same.
Arguing that we are in the midst of a similarly transformative point in history, Suzman shows how automation might revolutionize our relationship with work and in doing so usher in a more sustainable and equitable future for our world and ourselves.
Related to Work
Related ebooks
The Place of Anarchism in Socialistic Evolution An Address Delivered in Paris Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsMorality by Design: Technology's Challenge to Human Values Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsWhatever Happened to the Life of Leisure? Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsSurviving Off Off-Grid Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Abundanomics – Unlocking the Real Wealth of Nations Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Virtue Of Prosperity: Finding Values In An Age Of Technoaffluence Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Game: How the World of Finance Really Works Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Know-It-Alls: The Rise of Silicon Valley as a Political Powerhouse and Social Wrecking Ball Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Humans Need Not Apply: A Guide to Wealth & Work in the Age of Artificial Intelligence Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Company of Strangers: A Natural History of Economic Life - Revised Edition Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Free-Market Champions: Belief? Ideology? Philosophy? Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Abilities Story Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsCourage to realise Lampsacus: THE MULICULTURAL SOCIETY OF MINORITIES - The Internet as Chance Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsBanking: The Root Cause of the Injustices of Our Time Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDigital vs Human: how we'll live, love, and think in the future Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5What's Left of the World: Education, Identity and the Post-Work Political Imagination Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsRe-designing the smart future: How new technologies are transforming businesses and the 2020 world we live in Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsLeave Me Alone and I'll Make You Rich: How the Bourgeois Deal Enriched the World Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Family Economy: Discovering the Family as It Was Designed to Work Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Spiritual Technology of Ancient Egypt: Sacred Science and the Mystery of Consciousness Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Curtains?: The Future of the Arts in America Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/52062: The World that AI Made Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Who Can Sell Ice to an Eskimo? Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsIf Not Silver, What? Rating: 1 out of 5 stars1/5Simple Prosperity: Finding Real Wealth in a Sustainable Lifestyle Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Billionaires' Manifesto Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Progress and Poverty Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsIf: Trading Your If Only Regrets for God's What If Possibilities Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratings
History For You
A Grief Observed Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Surprised by Joy: The Shape of My Early Life Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Secret History of the World Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Devil's Chessboard: Allen Dulles, the CIA, and the Rise of America's Secret Government Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Sapiens: A Brief History of Humankind Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5A People's History of the United States Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Indifferent Stars Above: The Harrowing Saga of the Donner Party Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Longitude: The True Story of a Lone Genius Who Solved the Greatest Scientific Problem of His Time Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Lies My Teacher Told Me: Everything Your American History Textbook Got Wrong Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Devil in the Grove: Thurgood Marshall, the Groveland Boys, and the Dawn of a New America Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Unhumans: The Secret History of Communist Revolutions (and How to Crush Them) Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5100 Amazing Facts About the Negro with Complete Proof Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5100 Things You're Not Supposed to Know: Secrets, Conspiracies, Cover Ups, and Absurdities Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Richest Man in Babylon: The most inspiring book on wealth ever written Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Gulag Archipelago [Volume 1]: An Experiment in Literary Investigation Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Ethnic Cleansing of Palestine Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Happiest Man on Earth: The Beautiful Life of an Auschwitz Survivor Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Whore Stories: A Revealing History of the World's Oldest Profession Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Vanderbilt: The Rise and Fall of an American Dynasty Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Time Traveler's Guide to Medieval England: A Handbook for Visitors to the Fourteenth Century Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The ZERO Percent: Secrets of the United States, the Power of Trust, Nationality, Banking and ZERO TAXES! Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Lessons of History Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Prisoners of Geography: Ten Maps That Explain Everything About the World Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5King Leopold's Ghost: A Story of Greed, Terror, and Heroism in Colonial Africa Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Great Awakening: Defeating the Globalists and Launching the Next Great Renaissance Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Ultralearning: Master Hard Skills, Outsmart the Competition, and Accelerate Your Career Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Homo Deus: A Brief History of Tomorrow Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5
Reviews for Work
32 ratings4 reviews
- Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Starts with a review of what “work” really means and then explores the history of human work. I really loved the close attention to what the daily “productive” lives of long-ago people may have been like, long before recorded history. The last few chapters, about what work has become in the last couple thousand years was weaker, I thought, or maybe just more familiar. Anyone who has enjoyed Graeber’s “Debt: The First 5000 Years” or James C Scott’s “Seeing Like a State” would probably like this book also.
- Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5This is an interesting, if maybe a bit too wide-ranging book on work and its role in our lives. Many of us take work to be essential to human life. Suzman writes that not only did work only really begin with agricultural practices, but that they way we work now is a very recent phenomenon. Even the standard workweek only came into being with consumer capitalism.
History gives us ways to reconsider our obsession with work. - Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5I started this book during my recent, thankfully brief, period of unemployment earlier this year, for perhaps obvious reasons. I was expecting a sort of sociopolitical examination of our relationship to work, but it is rather more than that. James Suzman is an anthropologist specializing in hunter-gatherers of southern Africa, and he takes a very broad perspective.
Though the book is thoroughly documented with sources in the footnotes and it is written by an academic, it was blessedly not bogged down by acadamese or jargon and was a pleasure to read. Though it can be read as an indictment of capitalism, it is far from a political screed. It is much more an examination of humanity’s relationship to work, a look at the ways various cultures approach work, and some thoughtful suggestions about better ways we could deal with “the Economic Problem.” I learned a lot about more recent economics, such as the “Great Decoupling,” when GDP became “decoupled” from the median household income, and how this means greater wealth inequality. I also learned about alternative approaches to the “Econonomic Problem.” While this is not necessarily a hopeful book, it’s also not entirely gloom and doom.
I’d recommend this to thoughtful millennials who are interested in new economic approaches for reducing inequality and hopefully healthier and more satisfying relationships to work. - Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/52021 book #50. 2020. Well written and enjoyable story of why we work and how our concept of work has changed over the ages. From stone age hand axes to the AI robot who's going to take your job.
Book preview
Work - James Suzman
INTRODUCTION
THE ECONOMIC PROBLEM
The first industrial revolution was coughed out of the soot-blackened chimneys of coal-fired steam engines; the second leaped from electric wall sockets; and the third took the form of the electronic microprocessor. Now we are in the midst of a fourth industrial revolution, born of the union of a host of new digital, biological, and physical technologies, and we are told that it will be exponentially more transformative than its predecessors. Even so, no one is yet quite sure how it will play out, beyond the fact that ever more tasks in our factories, businesses, and homes will be undertaken by automated cyber-physical systems animated by machine-learning algorithms.
For some, the prospect of an automated future heralds an era of robotic convenience. For others, it is another fateful step on the journey toward a cybernetic dystopia. But for many, the prospect of an automated future raises only one immediate question: what will happen if a robot takes my job?
For those in professions that have up to now been immune from technological redundancy, the rise of the job-eating robots manifests in the mundane: the choruses of robotic greetings and reprimands that emanate from the ranks of automated tellers in supermarkets or the clumsy algorithms that both guide and frustrate our adventures in the digital universe.
For the hundreds of millions of unemployed people scraping a living in the corrugated-iron margins of developing countries, where economic growth is driven ever more by the marriage of cutting-edge technology and capital and so generates few new jobs, automation is an altogether more immediate concern. It is also an immediate concern for ranks of semi-skilled workers in industrialized economies whose only option is to strike to save their jobs from automata whose principal virtue is that they never go on strike. And, even if it doesn’t feel like it just yet, the writing is on the wall for some in highly skilled professions too. With artificial intelligence now designing better artificial intelligence than people can, it looks like we have been tricked by our own ingenuity into turning our factories, offices, and workplaces into devil’s workshops that will leave our hands idle and rob our lives of purpose.
If so, then we are right to worry. After all, we work to live and live to work and are capable of finding meaning, satisfaction, and pride in almost any job: from the rhythmic monotony of mopping floors to gaming tax loopholes. The work we do also defines who we are; determines our future prospects; dictates where and with whom we spend most of our time; mediates our sense of self-worth; molds many of our values; and orients our political loyalties. So much so that we sing the praises of strivers, decry the laziness of shirkers, and the goal of universal employment remains a mantra for politicians of all stripes.
Beneath this lies the conviction that we are genetically hardwired to work and that our species’ destiny has been shaped by a unique convergence of purposefulness, intelligence, and industriousness that has enabled us to build societies that are so much more than the sum of their parts.
Our anxieties about an automated future contrast with the optimism of many thinkers and dreamers who, ever since the first stirrings of the Industrial Revolution, believed that automation was the key that would unlock an economic utopia. People like Adam Smith, the founding father of economics, who in 1776 sung the praises of the very pretty machines
that he believed would in time facilitate and abridge labor,
¹ or Oscar Wilde who a century later fantasized about a future in which machinery will be doing all the necessary and unpleasant work.
² But none made the case as comprehensively as the twentieth century’s most influential economist, John Maynard Keynes. He predicted in 1930 that by the early twenty-first century capital growth, improving productivity, and technological advances should have brought us to the foothills of an economic promised land
in which everybody’s basic needs were easily satisfied and where, as a result, nobody worked more than fifteen hours in a week.
We passed the productivity and capital growth thresholds Keynes calculated would need to be met to get there some decades ago. Most of us still work just as hard as our grandparents and great-grandparents did, and our governments remain as fixated on economic growth and employment creation as at any point in our recent history. More than this, with private and state pension funds groaning under the weight of their obligations to increasingly aged populations, many of us are expected to work almost a decade longer than we did half a century ago; and despite unprecedented advances in technology and productivity in some of the world’s most advanced economies like Japan and South Korea, hundreds of avoidable deaths every year are now officially accredited to people logging eye-watering levels of overtime.
Humankind, it seems, is not yet ready to claim its collective pension. Understanding why requires recognizing that our relationship with work is far more interesting and involved than most traditional economists would have us believe.
Keynes believed that reaching his economic promised land would be our species’ most singular achievement because we will have done nothing less than solve what he described as the most pressing problem of the human race . . . from the beginnings of life in its most primitive form.
The pressing problem
Keynes had in mind was what classical economists refer to as the economic problem
and sometimes also as the problem of scarcity.
It holds that we are rational creatures cursed with insatiable appetites and that because there are simply not enough resources to satisfy everybody’s wants, everything is scarce. The idea that we have infinite wants but that all resources are limited sits at the beating heart of the definition of economics as the study of how people allocate scarce resources to meet their needs and desires. It also anchors our markets, financial, employment, and monetary systems. To economists, then, scarcity is what drives us to work, for it is only by working—by making, producing, and trading scarce resources—that we can ever begin to bridge the gap between our apparently infinite desires and our limited means.
But the problem of scarcity offers a bleak assessment of our species. It insists that evolution has molded us into selfish creatures, cursed to be forever burdened by desires that we can never satisfy. And as much as this assumption about human nature may seem obvious and self-evident to many in the industrialized world, to many others, like the Ju/’hoansi Bushmen
of southern Africa’s Kalahari, who still lived as hunter-gatherers through to the late twentieth century, it does not ring true.
I have been documenting their often traumatic encounter with a relentlessly expanding global economy since the early 1990s. It is an often brutal story, set in a frontier between two profoundly different ways of life, each grounded in very different social and economic philosophies based on very different assumptions about the nature of scarcity. For the Ju/’hoansi, the market economy and the assumptions about human nature that underwrite it are as bewildering as they are frustrating. They are not alone in this. Other societies who continued to hunt and gather into the twentieth century, from the Hadzabe of East Africa to the Inuit in the Arctic, have similarly struggled to make sense of and adapt to norms of an economic system predicated on eternal scarcity.
When Keynes first described his economic utopia, the study of hunter-gatherer societies was barely more than a sideshow in the newly emerging discipline of social anthropology. Even if he had wished to know more about hunter-gatherers, he would not have found much to challenge the prevailing view at the time that life in primitive societies was a constant battle against starvation. Nor would he have found anything to persuade him that, despite the occasional setback, the human journey was, above all, a story of progress and that the engine of progress was our urge to work, to produce, to build, and to exchange, spurred by our innate urge to solve the economic problem.
But we now know that hunter-gatherers like the Ju/’hoansi did not live constantly on the edge of starvation. Rather, they were usually well nourished; lived longer than people in most farming societies; rarely worked more than fifteen hours a week; and spent the bulk of their time at rest and leisure. We also know that they could do this because they did not routinely store food, cared little for accumulating wealth or status, and worked almost exclusively to meet only their short-term material needs. Where the economic problem insists that we are all cursed to live in the purgatory between our infinite desires and limited means, hunter-gatherers had few material desires, which could be satisfied with a few hours of effort. Their economic life was organized around the presumption of abundance rather than a preoccupation with scarcity. And this being so, there is good reason to believe that because our ancestors hunted and gathered for well over 95 percent of Homo sapiens’ 300,000-year-old history, the assumptions about human nature in the problem of scarcity and our attitudes to work have their roots in farming.
Acknowledging that for most of human history our ancestors were not as preoccupied with scarcity as we are now reminds us that there is far more to work than our efforts to solve the economic problem. This is something we all recognize: we routinely describe all sorts of purposeful activities beyond our jobs as work. We can work, for instance, at our relationships, on our bodies, and even at our leisure.
When economists define work as the time and effort we spend meeting our needs and wants, they dodge two obvious problems. The first is that often the only thing that differentiates work from leisure is context and whether we are being paid to do something or are paying to do it. To an ancient forager, hunting an elk is work, but to many First World hunters it is an exhilarating and often very expensive leisure activity; to a commercial artist, drawing is work, but to millions of amateur artists it is a relaxing pleasure; and to a lobbyist, cultivating relationships with movers and shakers is work, but for most of the rest of us making friends is a joy. The second problem is that beyond the energy we expend to secure our most basic needs—food, water, air, warmth, companionship, and safety—there is very little that is universal about what constitutes a necessity. More than this, necessity often merges so imperceptibly with desire that it can be impossible to separate them. Thus some will insist that a breakfast of a croissant served alongside good coffee is a necessity while for others it is a luxury.
The closest thing to a universal definition of work
—one that hunter-gatherers, pinstriped derivatives traders, calloused subsistence farmers, and anyone else would agree on—is that it involves purposefully expending energy or effort on a task to achieve a goal or end. Ever since ancient humans first began to divide up the world around them and organize their experiences of it in terms of concepts, words, and ideas, they have almost certainly had some concept of work. Like love, parenthood, music, and mourning, work is one of the few concepts that anthropologists and travelers alike have been able to cling to when cast adrift in alien lands. For where spoken language or bewildering customs are an obstruction, the simple act of helping someone perform a job will often break down barriers far quicker than any clumsy utterances. It expresses goodwill and, like a dance or a song, it creates a communion of purpose and a harmony of experience.
Abandoning the idea that the economic problem is the eternal condition of the human race does more than extend the definition of work beyond how we make a living. It provides us with a new lens through which to view our deep historical relationship with work from the very beginnings of life through to our busy present. It also raises a series of new questions. Why do we now afford work so much more importance than our hunting and gathering ancestors did? Why, in an era of unprecedented abundance, do we remain so preoccupied with scarcity?
Answering these questions requires venturing far beyond the bounds of traditional economics and into the world of physics, evolutionary biology, and zoology. But perhaps most importantly it requires bringing a social anthropological perspective to bear on them. It is only through social anthropological studies of societies who continued to hunt and gather into the twentieth century that we are able to animate the flaked stones, rock art, and broken bones that are the only abundant material clues to how our foraging ancestors lived and worked. It is also only through taking a social anthropological approach that we can begin to make sense of how our experiences of the world are molded by the different kinds of work we do. Taking this broader approach offers us some surprising insights into the ancient roots of what are often considered to be uniquely modern challenges. It reveals, for instance, how our relationships with working machines are resonant of the relationship between early farmers and the cart horses, oxen, and other beasts of burden that aided them in their work, and how our anxieties about automation are remarkably reminiscent of those that kept people in slave-owning societies awake at night, and why.
When it comes to charting the history of our relationship with work, there are two intersecting pathways that are the most obvious to follow.
The first maps the story of our relationship with energy. At its most fundamental, work is always an energy transaction and the capacity to do certain kinds of work is what distinguishes living organisms from dead, inanimate matter. For only living things actively seek out and capture energy specifically to live, to grow, and to reproduce. The journey down this pathway reveals that we are not the only species who are routinely profligate with energy; or who become listless, depressed, and demoralized when they are deprived of purpose and there is no work to do. This in turn raises a whole series of other questions about the nature of work and our relationship with it. Do, for example, organisms like bacteria, plants, and cart horses also work? If so, in what ways does the work they do differ from the work that humans and the machines that we build do? And what does this tell us about the way we work?
This pathway begins at the moment an energy source first somehow bound together a chaos of different molecules to form living organisms. It is also a path that widens steadily and ever more rapidly as life progressively expanded across the earth’s surface and evolved to capture new sources of energy, among them sunlight, oxygen, flesh, fire, and eventually fossil fuels with which to do work.
The second pathway follows the human evolutionary and cultural journey. Its early physical milestones take the form of rough stone tools, ancient hearths, and broken beads. Later milestones take the form of powerful engines, giant cities, stock exchanges, industrial-scale farms, nation states, and vast networks of energy-hungry machines. But this is a pathway also littered with many invisible milestones. These take the form of ideas, concepts, ambitions, hopes, habits, rituals, practices, institutions, and stories—the building blocks of culture and history. The journey down this pathway reveals how, as our ancestors developed the capacity to master many new different skills, our remarkable purposefulness was honed to the point that we are now capable of finding meaning, joy, and deep satisfaction in activities like building pyramids, digging holes, and doodling. It also shows how the work they did and the skills they acquired progressively shaped their experience of, and interactions with, the world around them.
But it is the points where these two pathways converge that are most important in terms of making sense of our contemporary relationship with work. The first of these points of convergence comes when humans mastered fire possibly as long as a million years ago. In learning how to outsource some of their energy needs to flames, they acquired the gift of more time free from the food-quest, the means to stay warm in the cold, and the ability to vastly extend their diets, so fueling the growth of ever more energy-hungry, harder-working brains.
The second crucial point of convergence was far more recent, and arguably far more transformative. It began some 12,000 years ago when some of our ancestors began to routinely store food and experiment with cultivation, transforming their relationships with their environments, with each other, with scarcity, and with work. Exploring this point of convergence also reveals how much of the formal economic architecture around which we organize our working lives today had its origins in farming and how intimately our ideas about equality and status are bound into our attitudes to work.
A third point of convergence occurs when people began to gather in cities and towns. This was around 8,000 years ago, when some agricultural societies started to generate big enough food surpluses to sustain large urban populations. And it too represents a major new chapter in the history of work—one defined not by the need to capture energy by working in the fields, but rather by the demands of spending it. The birth of the first cities seeded the genesis of a whole new range of skills, professions, jobs, and trades that were unimaginable in subsistence farming or foraging societies.
The emergence of large villages, then towns, and finally cities also played a vital role in reshaping the dynamics of the economic problem and scarcity. Because most urban people’s material needs were met by farmers who produced food in the countryside, they focused their restless energy in pursuit of status, wealth, pleasure, leisure, and power. Cities quickly became crucibles of inequality, a process that was accelerated by the fact that within cities people were not bound together by the same intimate kinship and social ties that were characteristic of small rural communities. As a result, people living in cities increasingly began to bind their social identity ever more tightly to the work they did and find community among others who pursued the same trade as them.
The fourth point of convergence is marked by the appearance of factories and mills belching smoke from great chimneys as populations in Western Europe learned to unlock ancient stores of energy from fossil fuels and transform them into hitherto unimaginable material prosperity. At this point, which begins early in the eighteenth century, both pathways expand abruptly. They become more crowded, accommodating the rapid growth in the number and size of cities, a surge in the population of both humans and the animal and plant species our ancestors domesticated. They also become far busier as a result of the turbocharging of our collective preoccupation with scarcity and work—paradoxically as a result of there being more stuff than ever before. And while it is still too early tell, it is hard to avoid the suspicion that future historians will not distinguish between the first, second, third, and fourth industrial revolutions, but will instead consider this extended moment as critical as any other in our species’ relationship with work.
PART ONE
In the Beginning
1
TO LIVE IS TO WORK
On this particular afternoon in the spring of 1994, it was so hot that even the children with their rawhide feet winced as they darted across the sand from one patch of shade to the next. There was no breeze and the dust clouds kicked up by the missionary’s Land Cruiser as it thundered up the rough sand track toward the Skoonheid Resettlement Camp in Namibia’s Kalahari Desert hung in the air long after the vehicle had come to a halt.
For the nearly 200 Ju/’hoansi Bushmen sheltering from the sun, occasional visits from missionaries were a welcome break from the monotony of waiting for government food handouts. They were also far more entertaining than traipsing across the desert from one vast cattle ranch to the next in the hope of persuading a white farmer to give them some work. Over the preceding half-century of living under the whip of the ranchers who had robbed them of their land, even the most skeptical among this community—the remnants of the most enduring hunter-gatherer society on earth—had come to believe it was common sense to pay attention to the ordained emissaries of the farmers’ God. Some even found comfort in their words.
As the sun dropped toward the western horizon, the missionary climbed out of his Land Cruiser, set up an improvised pulpit at the base of the tree trunk, and summoned the congregation. It was still meltingly hot, and they sluggishly convened in the dappled shade of the tree. The only drawback of this arrangement was that, as the sun fell lower, the congregation had to periodically rearrange itself to remain in the shade, a process that involved much getting up, sitting down, elbowing, and nudging. As the service progressed and the tree’s shadow lengthened, the majority of the congregation shifted progressively further and further away from the pulpit, forcing the missionary to deliver much of his sermon in a sustained bellow.
The setting added a certain biblical gravitas to the proceedings. Not only did the sun provide the missionary with a squint-inducing halo, but like the moon that would soon rise in the east and the tree the congregation sat beneath, the sun had a starring role in the tale he had to tell: Genesis and the Fall of Man.
The missionary began by reminding his congregation that the reason why people came together to worship every Sunday was because God had worked tirelessly for six days to make the heavens, earth, oceans, sun, moon, birds, beasts, fish, and so on, and only rested on the seventh day when his work was done. He reminded them that because humans were created in His image, they too were expected to toil for six days and on the seventh to rest, and offer gratitude for the uncountable blessings that the Lord had bestowed upon them.
The missionary’s opening declaration generated some head nodding as well as an amen or two from the more enthusiastic congregation members. But most found it a challenge to identify exactly what blessings they should be grateful for. They knew what it meant to work hard, and they understood the importance of having time to rest, even if they had no idea how it felt to share in the material rewards of their labors. Over the preceding half century, it was their hands that did the heavy lifting that transformed this semi-arid environment into profitable cattle ranches. And over this period the farmers, who were otherwise not shy of using the whip to cure
Ju/’hoan workers of idleness, always gave them time off on Sundays.
The missionary then told his congregation how after the Lord had instructed Adam and Eve to care for the Garden of Eden they were seduced by the serpent into committing mortal sin, as a result of which the Almighty cursed the ground
and banished the sons and daughters of Adam and Eve to a life of toil in the fields.
This particular Bible story made more sense to the Ju/’hoansi than many others the missionaries told them—and not just because they all knew what it meant to be tempted to sleep with people they knew they shouldn’t. In it they saw a parable of their own recent history. All the old Ju/’hoansi at Skoonheid remembered when this land was their sole domain and when they lived exclusively by hunting for wild animals and gathering wild fruits, tubers, and vegetables. They recalled that back then, like Eden, their desert environment was eternally (if temperamentally) provident and almost always gave them enough to eat on the basis of a few, often spontaneous, hours’ effort. Some now speculated that it must have been as a result of some similar mortal sin on their part that, starting in the 1920s, first a trickle then a flood of white farmers and colonial police arrived in the Kalahari with their horses, guns, water pumps, barbed wire, cattle, and strange laws, and claimed all this land for themselves.
For their part, the white farmers quickly learned that farming in an environment as hostile to large-scale agriculture as the Kalahari would take a lot of labor. So they formed commandos to capture and force into work the wild
Bushmen, held Bushman children hostage to ensure their parents’ obedience, and meted out regular whippings to teach them the virtues of hard work.
Deprived of their traditional lands, the Ju/’hoansi learned that to survive, like Adam and Eve, they must toil on farms.
For thirty years, they settled into this life. But when in 1990 Namibia gained its independence from South Africa, technological advances meant that the farms were both more productive and less dependent on labor than they had been. And with a new government demanding that ranchers treat their Ju/’hoan laborers as formal employees and provide them with proper salaries and housing, many farmers simply chased them from their land. They reasoned that it was far more economical and far less trouble to invest in the right machinery and run their farms with as few staff as possible. As a result, many Ju/’hoansi had little option but to camp by the side of the road, squat in the fringes of Herero villages to the north, or move to one of the two small resettlement areas where there was little to do but sit and wait for food aid.
This is where the story of the fall ceased to make much sense to the Ju/’hoansi. For if, like Adam and Eve, they were banished by God to a life of toil in the fields, why had they now been banished from the fields by farmers who said they no longer had any use for them?
Sigmund Freud was convinced that all the world’s mythologies—including the biblical story of Adam and Eve—held within them the secrets to the mysteries of our psycho-sexual development.
By contrast, his colleague and rival Carl Gustav Jung considered myths to be nothing less than the distilled essence of humanity’s collective unconscious.
And to Claude Lévi-Strauss, the intellectual touchstone of much twentieth-century social anthropology, all the world’s mythologies combined to form an immense and intricate puzzle box that if properly decoded would reveal the deep structures
of the human mind.
The diverse mythologies of the world may or may not offer us a window into our collective unconscious,
explain our sexual hang-ups, or let us peer into the deep structures of our minds. But there is no doubt that they reveal some things that are universal to human experience. One is the idea that our world—no matter how perfect it was at the moment of creation—is subject to chaotic forces and that humans must work to keep these in check.
Among the missionary’s congregation at Skoonheid that hot afternoon were a handful of old-time people.
They were the last Ju/’hoansi here to have spent much of their lives as hunter-gatherers. They bore the trauma of being violently wrenched from their old lives with the kind of stoicism that characterized traditional hunter-gatherer life, and as they awaited death they found comfort in retelling one another the stories of the beginning
—the Creation myths—they learned as children.
Before Christian missionaries showed up with their own version of the tale, the Ju/’hoansi believed the creation of the world happened in two distinct phases. In the first phase their creator God made himself, his wives, a lesser trickster god called G//aua, the world, rain, lightning, holes in the ground that collected rainwater, plants, animals, and finally people. But before completing the job, he spent time on something else, leaving the unfinished world in a state of chaotic ambiguity. There were no social rules, no customs, and people and animals alike shape-shifted from one bodily form to another, variously intermarrying and eating one another as well as engaging in all sorts of outlandish behavior. Fortunately, the creator didn’t abandon his creation forever and eventually returned to finish the job. He did so by imposing rules and order on the world, first by separating and naming the different species and then by endowing each with its own customs, rules, and characteristics.
The stories of the beginning
that delighted the old men of Skoonheid are all set during the period when the creator, leaving his work incomplete, took his extended cosmic sabbatical—perhaps, as one man suggested, because he needed to take a rest just as the Christian God did. Most of these stories tell of how in the creator’s absence the trickster thrived, causing mayhem and chaos wherever he went. In one story, for example, G//aua cuts out, cooks, and serves his own anus to his family, and laughs hysterically at the brilliance of his own joke when they compliment him on the tastiness of the dish. In others, he cooks and eats his wife, rapes his mother, steals children from their parents, and callously commits murder.
But G//aua did not rest when the creator returned to finish his work, and ever since has picked mischievously and unrelentingly at the world’s orderly seams. Thus where the Ju/’hoansi associated the creator God with order, predictability, rules, manners, and continuity, G//aua was associated with randomness, chaos, ambiguity, discord, and disorder. And the Ju/’hoansi detected G//aua’s devilish hand at work in all sorts of different things. They noticed it, for instance, when lions behaved uncharacteristically; when someone fell mysteriously ill; when a bowstring frayed or a spear snapped; or when they were persuaded by a mysterious inner voice to sleep with someone else’s spouse while being only too aware of the discord this would cause.
The old-time people were in no doubt that the serpent who tempted Adam and Eve in the missionary’s story was none other than their trickster G//aua in one of his many disguises. Spreading lies, persuading people to embrace forbidden desires, and then cheerfully witnessing the life-shattering consequences play out was exactly the sort of thing G//aua liked to do.
Ju/’hoansi are but one of many peoples to have discovered their own cosmic troublemakers lurking beneath the skin of Eden’s smooth-talking serpent. Tricksters, troublemakers, and destroyers—like Odin’s wayward son Loki, the coyote and raven in many indigenous North American cultures, or Anansi, the short-tempered, shape-shifting spider that scuttles through many West African and Caribbean mythologies—have been creating work for people to do since the beginning of time.
It is no coincidence that tension between chaos and order is a feature of the world’s mythologies. After all, science also insists that there is a universal relationship between disorder and work, one that was first revealed during the heady days of the Enlightenment in Western Europe.
Gaspard-Gustave Coriolis loved the game of table billiards—a hobby to which he devoted many happy hours of practical research,
the results of which he published in the Théorie mathématique des effets du jeu de billiard, a book still invoked with biblical solemnity by aficionados of billiards’ descendants, snooker and pool. He was born in the revolutionary summer of 1792, the same year that France’s Citizens’ Assembly abolished the monarchy and dragged King Louis XVI and Marie Antoinette from the Palace of Versailles to await their appointment with the guillotine. But Coriolis was a revolutionary of a different sort. He was one of the vanguard of men and women who had turned their back on theological dogma and instead embraced reason, the explanatory power of mathematics, and the rigor of the scientific method to make sense of the world, and who as a result ushered in the industrial age after unlocking the transformative energy of fossil fuels.
Coriolis is now best remembered for formulating the Coriolis Effect,
without which meteorologists would have no sensible way of modeling the swirling forms of weather systems or the vagaries of ocean currents. More importantly for us he is also remembered for introducing the term work
into the lexicon of modern science.
Coriolis’s interest in table billiards extended beyond the satisfaction he gained from the predictable click-clack of ivory balls as they collided with one another, or even the thrill he experienced when one, guided by his cue, slipped off the table into a pocket. To him, billiards revealed the infinite explanatory power of mathematics, and the billiard table was a space where people like him could observe, tinker, and play with some of the fundamental laws that governed the physical universe. Not only did the balls evoke the