Tech Monopoly
()
About this ebook
In recent years, the astronomical rise of tech giants like Amazon, Apple, Meta, and Microsoft has been criticized as anticompetitive, and many have wondered if antitrust law can help protect workers and consumers. In Tech Monopoly, Herbert Hovenkamp explores competition problems in a wide range of high-tech firms—from those that sell purely digital products, such as video streaming, search, software, or email services, to others that sell more traditional “tactile” products, such as hardware, clothing, groceries, or rides. He offers a realistic look at the powers and limitations of antitrust law in tech markets with an assessment that is as comprehensive as it is accessible.
After a general introduction to antitrust law, Tech Monopoly considers how competitive harm should be assessed in these markets, as well as some features that make these markets unique, including “two-sided” structures. Then Hovenkamp looks at the role of large digital platforms, including Amazon, Alphabet, Apple, Meta, and Microsoft, and considers whether their size alone is an antitrust problem or if the concern should be limited to market power. Finally, the author addresses the very difficult problem of remedies. Should we “break up” big tech, and if so, how? What kind of breakup of these firms would make users or others better off? And if breakups are not the only possible antitrust fix, are there more effective and less disruptive alternatives?
Offering simple explanations of the complex economics of digital platform markets, Tech Monopoly is an important read for anyone who wishes to understand how antitrust law works and whether it can help defend competition in the formidable era of big tech.
Related to Tech Monopoly
Related ebooks
Bit Tyrants: The Political Economy of Silicon Valley Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Open Revolution: Rewriting the rules of the information age Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsHow to Make a Fortune on the Information Superhighway (Review and Analysis of Canter and Siegel's Book) Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Internet Con: How to Seize the Means of Computation Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Platform Paradox: How Digital Businesses Succeed in an Ever-Changing Global Marketplace Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Containing Big Tech: How to Protect Our Civil Rights, Economy, and Democracy Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsYour Happiness Was Hacked: Why Tech Is Winning the Battle to Control Your Brain—and How to Fight Back Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Digital Risk Governance: Security Strategies for the Public and Private Sectors Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsConnections for the Digital Age: Multimedia Communications for Mobile, Nomadic and Fixed Devices Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Epic Struggle of the Internet of Things Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Social Media The Sum of Everything Equals Zero Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsVoices from the Valley: Tech Workers Talk About What They Do--and How They Do It Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsBranding Unbound: The Future of Advertising, Sales, and the Brand Experience in the Wireless Age Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsUnderstanding Big Data: A Beginners Guide to Data Science & the Business Applications Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5If It's Smart, It's Vulnerable Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Think Bigger: Developing a Successful Big Data Strategy for Your Business Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Software Society: Cultural and Economic Impact Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsSocial Networking Is The Greatest Con In History Or The Greatest Opportunity Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsNext Generation Democracy: What the Open-Source Revolution Means for Power, Politics, and Change Rating: 2 out of 5 stars2/5THE EVOLUTION OF ANTITRUST IN THE DIGITAL ERA: Essays on Competition Policy Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThingalytics Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Hacking for Everyone?: An Introduction to Cyber Security Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsWho Is Winning The Social Media And Crowd Funding War(s)?: The Battle For Good Vs Evil Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Road Ahead (Review and Analysis of Gates' Book) Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsBig Data for Executives and Market Professionals - Third Edition: Big Data Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe 4th Industrial Revolution: Responding to the Impact of Artificial Intelligence on Business Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Sentient Web Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsTurning Silicon into Gold: The Strategies, Failures, and Evolution of the Tech Industry Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsInvest In 6G Tech Stocks Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratings
Law For You
The Everything Guide To Being A Paralegal: Winning Secrets to a Successful Career! Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The ZERO Percent: Secrets of the United States, the Power of Trust, Nationality, Banking and ZERO TAXES! Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Divorcing a Narcissist: The Lure, the Loss and the Law Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsLaw For Dummies Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Secrets of Criminal Defense Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Source: The Secrets of the Universe, the Science of the Brain Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Devil in the Grove: Thurgood Marshall, the Groveland Boys, and the Dawn of a New America Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Verbal Judo, Second Edition: The Gentle Art of Persuasion Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/58 Living Trust Forms: Legal Self-Help Guide Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Legal Writing in Plain English: A Text with Exercises Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Legal Words You Should Know: Over 1,000 Essential Terms to Understand Contracts, Wills, and the Legal System Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Police State: Ten Secrets The Police Don't Want You To Know! (How To Survive Police Encounters!) Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Win In Court Every Time Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Socratic Method: A Practitioner's Handbook Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Estate & Trust Administration For Dummies Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsWills and Trusts Kit For Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Paralegal Career For Dummies Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Win Your Case: How to Present, Persuade, and Prevail--Every Place, Every Time Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Critical Race Theory: The Cutting Edge Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Legal Writing: QuickStudy Laminated Reference Guide Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe LLC and Corporation Start-Up Guide: Your Complete Guide to Launching the Right Business Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5How to Think Like a Lawyer--and Why: A Common-Sense Guide to Everyday Dilemmas Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Common Law Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Paralegal's Handbook: A Complete Reference for All Your Daily Tasks Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Criminal Law Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsTrans: When Ideology Meets Reality Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5No Place to Hide: Edward Snowden, the NSA, and the U.S. Surveillance State Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5
Reviews for Tech Monopoly
0 ratings0 reviews
Book preview
Tech Monopoly - Herbert Hovenkamp
Tech Monopoly
The MIT Press Essential Knowledge Series
A complete list of books in this series can be found online at https://mitpress.mit.edu/books/series/mit-press-essential-knowledge-series.
Tech Monopoly
Herbert Hovenkamp
The MIT Press | Cambridge, Massachusetts | London, England
© 2024 Massachusetts Institute of Technology
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be used to train artificial intelligence systems or reproduced in any form by any electronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher.
The MIT Press would like to thank the anonymous peer reviewers who provided comments on drafts of this book. The generous work of academic experts is essential for establishing the authority and quality of our publications. We acknowledge with gratitude the contributions of these otherwise uncredited readers.
This book was set in Chaparral Pro by New Best-set Typesetters Ltd.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Names: Hovenkamp, Herbert, 1948– author.
Title: Tech monopoly / Herbert Hovenkamp.
Description: Cambridge, Massachusetts : The MIT Press, 2024. | Series: The MIT press essential knowledge series | Includes bibliographical references and index.
Identifiers: LCCN 2023042861 (print) | LCCN 2023042862 (ebook) | ISBN 9780262548748 (paperback) | ISBN 9780262379274 (epub) | ISBN 9780262379267 (pdf)
Subjects: LCSH: Antitrust law. | Big data. | Electronic commerce—Law and legislation. | Internet marketing—Law and legislation. | Data protection—Law and legislation.
Classification: LCC K3850 .H69 2024 (print) | LCC K3850 (ebook) | DDC 343.7307/21—dc23/eng/20231003
LC record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2023042861
LC ebook record available at https://lccn.loc.gov/2023042862
10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
d_r0
To Maddie
Contents
Series Foreword
Preface: Antitrust and Big Tech
1 Introduction: The Antitrust Laws
2 Antitrust and Power
3 Anticompetitive Conduct and Big Tech
4 Antitrust Solutions to Tech Monopoly Problems
Glossary
Notes
Further Reading
Index
Series Foreword
The MIT Press Essential Knowledge series offers accessible, concise, beautifully produced pocket-size books on topics of current interest. Written by leading thinkers, the books in this series deliver expert overviews of subjects that range from the cultural and the historical to the scientific and the technical.
In today’s era of instant information gratification, we have ready access to opinions, rationalizations, and superficial descriptions. Much harder to come by is the foundational knowledge that informs a principled understanding of the world. Essential Knowledge books fill that need. Synthesizing specialized subject matter for nonspecialists and engaging critical topics through fundamentals, each of these compact volumes offers readers a point of access to complex ideas.
Preface
Antitrust and Big Tech
The subject of this book affects everyone, often in ways that people do not realize. Our lives are shaped by big tech. Even the vanishingly small number of people who have never used a computer or cellular phone are affected by tech products and services, including television and other media, or by family members who use them. Most Americans deal every day with at least one of the five largest tech companies, Amazon, Alphabet (formerly Google), Apple, Meta (formerly Facebook), or Microsoft. All are among the ten largest firms in the world. But the term big tech
applies to many others, including Uber, Tesla, eBay, Samsung, Adobe, Oracle, IBM, Texas Instruments, and Intuit. Others, including Intel, Qualcomm, AMD, Micron, and TSMC (Taiwan Semiconductor), deal mainly with other business firms. Not to be forgotten are large media or social networking companies whose products are heavily digital, including Netflix, Disney, Viacom, Comcast, MSNBC, Fox, Spotify, Twitter, and TikTok. Finally are financial services firms that operate on digital platforms, including Fidelity, Schwab, PayPal, Visa, American Express, and many others.
Virtually every firm today uses tech in some way, so identifying tech firms by use is not helpful. Rather, a tech firm is one that either develops digital technology or uses it as an important part of its production or distribution. Some firms, such as Spotify, sell digital content exclusively. Others, such as Amazon, Apple, or Texas Instruments, sell a mixture of digital and traditional tactile
content. For example, Amazon streams music and movies but also sells toasters, bicycles, and wrenches. It will either stream you a movie or sell it to you on DVD. Others, such as Uber, sell nondigital services but operate on a digital network for coordinating rides.
The term monopoly
almost always refers to products, not to firms. Only a few of the products sold by these firms are monopolies. Likely examples are Google Search, which controls more than 90 percent of consumer search on personal computers and mobile devices. Amazon controls nearly 70 percent of ebooks, although ebooks are only 20 percent of the overall book market. Microsoft Windows is the operating system for more than 70 percent of desktop and laptop computers, but Microsoft has a much smaller share for tablets, and its market share for smartphones is less than 1 percent. That market is dominated by Alphabet’s Android and Apple’s iPhone.¹ Meta (Facebook) may or may not be a dominant firm, depending on which firms are included as competitors. Netflix is very large, but it streams programming in competition with Amazon Prime, Disney+, Hulu, Apple TV, MAX (formerly HBO+), and others.
In most cases size is a poor measure of market dominance. Most firms sell multiple products. Amazon in particular sells 12 million of them. That explains why its overall size is very large, while its share of individual products is often quite small. Importantly, you as a customer are typically looking for a single product. The question for you is the number of realistically available alternatives for your search. For example, if you want to buy groceries, the fact that Amazon’s grocery share is 2.5 percent gives a much better reading of the extent of the competition than does the fact that it is the largest online retailer. There may be situations in which size is more important, but one needs to be careful. In most cases market share of a particular product tells you much more about competitive alternatives than does the absolute size of the seller.
Tech markets have some features that distinguish them from old economy
markets. For competition policy, these features pull in different directions. First, much of their output is digital. This means that the cost of selling one additional unit—such as one additional copy of an ebook or a streamed video—is very low. Second, digital output is nonrivalrous,
which means that the sale of one unit does not reduce the amount that is left over. You can stream Taylor Swift on Spotify as much as you want without reducing the amount available to others. For successful products, nonrivalrous digital output can make firms larger because there are few limits on the firms’ capacity to produce more.
Third, tech firms are often organized as networks, in which firms interconnect in order to share information or intellectual property, or to engage in operations that involve many participants. One example is blanket licensing of copyrighted music. ASCAP, the American Society of Composers, Authors and Publishers, for example, has some 875,000 owner members who collectively control over 16 million digital musical works. Copyright owners grant ASCAP nonexclusive licenses, which it relicenses as a bundle to radio stations or distributors such as Spotify, which then relicense them to subscribers. Spotify alone had 489 million listeners in 2023. With blanket licensing you can subscribe to a music streaming service and have immediate access to this entire library. This market could not exist if each artist had to license her songs individually to listeners. Other networks of competitors involve the cross-licensing of patents for shared technology such as is used in cell phones or driverless cars. Still others are the old economy
networks of teams that make up professional and amateur athletics. Ours is a world of networks, many of which are privately owned and operated. While we benefit greatly from them, they can also do anticompetitive things. For example, in 2021 the Supreme Court applied section 1 of the Sherman Antitrust Act against an agreement among NCAA colleges to limit the compensation of student athletes.²
Network effects
can make networks more valuable as the number of participants is larger. For example, a dating site such as Match.com or a ride-hailing site such as Uber becomes more attractive as it grows. As a rider, you want access to as many drivers as possible, and as a driver you are drawn to sites with more potential riders. Indirect
network effects refer to the increased value on one side (e.g., riders) as the number on the other side (drivers) increases. The gold standard in networks is the phone system, where everyone on the system can talk to everyone else. A dominated
network is one that is controlled by a single firm, such as Uber or the Apple operating system. But networks can also be competitive,
such as the telephone system, email system, or sports leagues in the nondigital world. These do not have a dominant firm but rather many members of various sizes. They typically act both as collaborators in the operation of the network and as competitors with one another for your business. For example, when you set up an email account you have a competitive choice among Gmail, Outlook, Yahoo, and many others. Nevertheless, these firms also collaborate to ensure interoperability.
Tech firms are often organized as networks, in which firms interconnect in order to share information or intellectual property, or to engage in operations that involve many participants.
Another feature of networks is that they are often two-sided
markets. That means that they often obtain users and revenue from two (or more) sides. For example, a magazine, whether digital or traditional, gets revenue from both subscribers and advertisers. Too high a subscription price and it will lose readers, and then it will also lose advertisers. But too low a subscription price and it may need to sell excessive amounts of advertising to survive. As a result, it engages in participation balancing
to find the right distribution.³ A ride-sharing app like Uber may have to adjust its fares by the minute, with higher rush hour prices to bring in enough drivers to satisfy the number of riders and lower prices during off hours. Some two-sided markets are completely free on one side. That is true of Facebook and Google search technologies, but also of older technologies such as over-the-air radio and television.
Collectively, big tech firms have produced economic growth about three times greater than the growth rate of the economy as a whole. They have educated workforces, and produce outsize growth rates in the job market. Firms in these markets also innovate much more than the economy as a whole. Indeed, in recent years the ten firms that obtained the most patents were all tech companies. New entry into tech markets is relatively common, and even the largest tech firms appear to be competing aggressively with each other. On the buying side, consumers often have a wider variety of choices. If you are unhappy with Walmart’s toaster selection you can exit the store and drive somewhere else. If you have the same experience on Amazon, you can switch with a mouse click. Information is usually more readily available on the internet, and comparison shopping is often easier. These facts lead one to wonder whether an antitrust policy of targeting
big tech, as reflected in some journalistic writing and proposed legislation, is a good idea.
Offsetting this competition, which helps consumers, big tech firms also engage in practices that have legitimately aroused antitrust concern. They are involved in many mergers. The networks that occur so frequently in tech markets often require agreements among competitors—something that can arouse the suspicion of antitrust law enforcers.
Tech firms have also displaced many firms that were dedicated to older technologies or methods of doing business. For example, the rise of Amazon has been a brutal experience for Main Street retailers. Netflix and other video streamers have been devastating for the DVD business and traditional movie theaters. Uber and Lyft have caused serious damage to the traditional taxicab industry. The digital camera killed the film camera, and today the smartphone camera is killing the dedicated digital camera. Firms that lose out in market battles, perhaps because their business method or technology is obsolete, may continue to have influence in political institutions. To that extent the political process may lead to misguided antitrust enforcement.
Chapter 1 of this book gives an introduction to the history, capabilities, and limits of antitrust regulations. Chapter 2 discusses the problem that is sometimes characterized by the press as bigness.
Should antitrust law focus on large firms, or should it instead be concerned with high prices in consumer markets, low innovation, or harm to labor markets? Chapter 3 focuses more narrowly on the activities of technology companies themselves: What are the unique promises and threats to competition that they present? A closely related question is how much should the problems be addressed by antitrust law, or when should we turn to other areas of law, which are frequently more specific? Finally, chapter 4 examines the difficult problem of remedies. Once we have decided that Meta (Facebook) or Amazon have been behaving anticompetitively, what should we do