Networks of Nazi Persecution: Bureaucracy, Business and the Organization of the Holocaust
By Gerald D. Feldman and Wolfgang Seibel
()
About this ebook
The persecution and mass-murder of the Jews during World War II would not have been possible without the modern organization of division of labor. Moreover, the perpetrators were dependent on human and organizational resources they could not always control by hierarchy and coercion. Instead, the persecution of the Jews was based, to a large extent, on a web of inter-organizational relations encompassing a broad variety of non-hierarchical cooperation as well as rivalry and competition. Based on newly accessible government and corporate archives, this volume combines fresh evidence with an interpretation of the governance of persecution, presented by prominent historians and social scientists.
Related to Networks of Nazi Persecution
Titles in the series (23)
Genocide and Settler Society: Frontier Violence and Stolen Indigenous Children in Australian History Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5Networks of Nazi Persecution: Bureaucracy, Business and the Organization of the Holocaust Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsEmpire, Colony, Genocide: Conquest, Occupation, and Subaltern Resistance in World History Rating: 3 out of 5 stars3/5The Train Journey: Transit, Captivity, and Witnessing in the Holocaust Rating: 2 out of 5 stars2/5Reassessing the Nuremberg Military Tribunals: Transitional Justice, Trial Narratives, and Historiography Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsTheatres Of Violence: Massacre, Mass Killing and Atrocity throughout History Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Judging 'Privileged' Jews: Holocaust Ethics, Representation, and the 'Grey Zone' Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Nazi Genocide of the Roma: Reassessment and Commemoration Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Dark Side of Nation-States: Ethnic Cleansing in Modern Europe Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Making of the Greek Genocide: Contested Memories of the Ottoman Greek Catastrophe Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Spirit of the Laws: The Plunder of Wealth in the Armenian Genocide Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsLet Them Not Return: Sayfo – The Genocide Against the Assyrian, Syriac, and Chaldean Christians in the Ottoman Empire Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Holocaust in Bohemia and Moravia: Czech Initiatives, German Policies, Jewish Responses Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDaily Life in the Abyss: Genocide Diaries, 1915-1918 Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsMicrohistories of the Holocaust Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsProbing the Limits of Categorization: The Bystander in Holocaust History Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Herero Genocide: War, Emotion, and Extreme Violence in Colonial Namibia Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDo Not Forget Me: Three Jewish Mothers Write to Their Sons from the Thessaloniki Ghetto Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsVoices on War and Genocide: Three Accounts of the World Wars in a Galician Town Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsA Sad Fiasco: Colonial Concentration Camps in Southern Africa, 1900–1908 Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Operation Barbarossa and its Aftermath: New Approaches to a Complex Campaign Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDefeating Impunity: Attempts at International Justice in Europe since 1914 Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratings
Related ebooks
Microhistories of the Holocaust Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsGerman Colonialism: Race, the Holocaust, and Postwar Germany Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsHitler's Beneficiaries: Plunder, Racial War, and the Nazi Welfare State Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Social Outsiders in Nazi Germany Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The German Colonial Empire Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Between Mass Death and Individual Loss: The Place of the Dead in Twentieth-Century Germany Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsGermany's Underground Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsHimmler's Auxiliaries: The Volksdeutsche Mittelstelle and the German National Minorities of Europe, 1933-1945 Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsNazi Germany and the Jews: The Years of Perdecution, 1933–1939 Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Nazis' Flight from Justice: How Hitler's Followers Attempted to Vanish Without Trace Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Hitler Conspirator: The Story of Kurt Freiherr von Plettenberg and Stauffenberg's Valkyrie Plot to Kill the Führer Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Dark Side of Nation-States: Ethnic Cleansing in Modern Europe Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe German Right in the Weimar Republic: Studies in the History of German Conservatism, Nationalism, and Antisemitism Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Gestapo on Trial: Evidence from Nuremberg Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Hitler Assassination Attempts: The Plots, Places and People that Almost Changed History Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsAdolf Hitler: Trial in Absentia in Nuremberg Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsHome after Fascism: Italian and German Jews after the Holocaust Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsAfter the Black Death, Second Edition: A Social History of Early Modern Europe Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Compromise of Return: Viennese Jews after the Holocaust Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsAmoral Communities: Collective Crimes in Time of War Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsA Jewish Kapo in Auschwitz: History, Memory, and the Politics of Survival Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsHitler, Stalin and I: An Oral History Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsDance with Death: A Holistic View of Saving Polish Jews during the Holocaust Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsFinal Solutions: Mass Killing and Genocide in the 20th Century Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Summary of Adrian Weale's Army of Evil Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe End of the Holocaust Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Annals of the Turkish Empire: 1591 - 1659: The Most Important Events in Affairs of East & West Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsBad News for Labour: Antisemitism, the Party and Public Belief Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Vél d'Hiv Raid: The French Police at the Service of the Gestapo Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5
Holocaust For You
THE DIARY OF ANNE FRANK Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Choice: Embrace the Possible Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Happiest Man on Earth: The Beautiful Life of an Auschwitz Survivor Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Killing the SS: The Hunt for the Worst War Criminals in History Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Ordinary Men: Reserve Police Battalion 101 and the Final Solution in Poland Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Blitzed: Drugs in the Third Reich Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Resistance: The Warsaw Ghetto Uprising Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5King Leopold's Ghost: A Story of Greed, Terror, and Heroism in Colonial Africa Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Rise and Fall of the Third Reich Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5They Thought They Were Free: The Germans, 1933–45 Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Doctors From Hell: The Horrific Account of Nazi Experiments on Humans Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Violinist of Auschwitz Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Boy Who Followed His Father into Auschwitz: A True Story of Family and Survival Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Secret Holocaust Diaries: The Untold Story of Nonna Bannister Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Beyond the Tracks: Beyond the Tracks, #1 Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsSummary and Analysis of Man's Search for Meaning: Based on the Book by Victor E. Frankl Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Holocaust Industry: Reflections on the Exploitation of Jewish Suffering Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5Swingtime for Hitler: Goebbels’s Jazzmen, Tokyo Rose, and Propaganda That Carries a Tune Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Banality of Evil: N.A. Rating: 0 out of 5 stars0 ratingsThe Nazis Next Door: How America Became a Safe Haven for Hitler's Men Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Irena's Children: The Extraordinary Story of the Woman Who Saved 2,500 Children from the Warsaw Ghetto Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5All But My Life: A Memoir Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Light of Days: The Untold Story of Women Resistance Fighters in Hitler's Ghettos Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5The Dressmakers of Auschwitz: The True Story of the Women Who Sewed to Survive Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Five Chimneys: A Woman Survivor’s True Story Of Auschwitz [Illustrated Edition] Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Commandant of Auschwitz: The Autobiography of Rudolf Hoess Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5The Lampshade: A Holocaust Detective Story from Buchenwald to New Orleans Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Fragments of Isabella: A Memoir of Auschwitz Rating: 4 out of 5 stars4/5Fall and Rise: The Story of 9/11 Rating: 5 out of 5 stars5/5
Reviews for Networks of Nazi Persecution
0 ratings0 reviews
Book preview
Networks of Nazi Persecution - Gerald D. Feldman
INTRODUCTION
THE HOLOCAUST AS
DIVISION-OF-LABOR-BASED CRIME—
EVIDENCE AND ANALYTICAL CHALLENGES
Gerald D. Feldman and Wolfgang Seibel
Division of Labor, Networks, and Organized Mass Crime
Organized mass crime is unthinkable without division of labor. The Holocaust is no exception to this rule but, rather, its most horrifying manifestation. Evidence related to the role of government bureaucracy was, to be sure, already part of classic Holocaust research.¹ Meta-theories of the Holocaust have drawn on the nature and consequences of modern bureaucracy as a tool of persecution and mass murder, the most prominent being Hannah Arendt's banalization theory.²
Both the planning and the implementation of genocide were carried out in accordance with conventional division-of-labor principles. From 1939 on, the Amt IV, Gegnererforschung und Bekämpfung
(Researching and Combating the Enemy) of the Reichssicherheitshauptamt (Reich Security Main Office) with its Department IV B 4, run by Adolf Eichmann, was in charge of anti-Jewish policy. The enforcement of the persecutory measures was delegated to the Staatspolizeileitstellen (State Police Head Offices) or, in the German occupied territories outside the Reich, to the Befehlshaber der Sicherheitspolizei und des Sicherheitsdienstes (SD) (Commanders of the Security Police and Security Service) (BdS). These core institutions, however, were dependent on numerous other institutions and individual participants, state and private, German and, in the occupied territories, domestic agents, for the implementation of the final solution.
In the occupied territories in particular, anti-Jewish policy implied resource dependency of the occupation administration and the Berlin central offices.³ Vertical division of labor was eclipsed by the rivalry between different agencies, both German and domestic, resulting in polycracy
or even organized chaos.
⁴
Thus, anti-Jewish policy and the persecution apparatus were obviously not just an SS and Gestapo matter. What is more, coordination of the complex persecution apparatuses could not be accomplished in an exclusively hierarchical manner. As the chapters in this volume reveal, coordination took place in a hierarchical as well as a cooperative way and, just as the differentiation of power within the regime or between the occupying power and domestic authorities played a role, so did the interdependence of a variety of agencies beyond formal rules of cooperation. To a large extent, the persecution apparatus was made up of inter-organizational networks as they have been described in political science and organization sociology literature.⁵
This perspective is supported by three strands of recent Holocaust research findings.
The first aspect concerns the situation of the SS and police apparatus, without question the core institution of the persecution apparatus. The degree of hegemony of the SS and police apparatus-abundantly described in the literature⁶ -as it had been emerging in Germany since 1933 through the fusion of party organizations (SS, SD) with the state police and its independence vis-à-vis the general public administration, was, in the occupied areas, again dependent on the formal structure of the occupation regime. This, in turn, was shaped by the strategic goals of the occupying power, but it did not follow a standardized plan within these goals as is revealed by the situation even in a region so highly homogenous as German occupied Western Europe.⁷ In one way or the other, however, division of labor meant collaboration of indigenous institutions and individuals.
The second aspect concerns the range of the anti-Jewish measures, mainly the relationship between economic and repressive police persecution. The Aryanization
of Jewish-owned businesses was not controlled by the SS and Gestapo but instead took place under the jurisdiction of the Gauwirtschaftsberater (Regional Economic Advisors) of the Nationalsozialistische Deutsche Arbeiterpartei (NSDAP) in cooperation with the self-administrative chambers of industry and commerce and the free professions, as well as the local governments, law firms, banks and insurance companies.⁸ In German-occupied territories, the jurisdiction for Aryanization
and the spoliation of Jewish assets in general lay with the regular civil or military occupation administration, which was again decisively dependent on domestic agencies.⁹
Finally, the destruction of the economic existence was inseparably connected to the physical extermination of the Jews. Although organization of the deportations was the exclusive domain of the Gestapo, the plundering of the last personal assets and belongings prior to deportation required cooperation with a large number of regular authorities, for instance, as has been reported for Germany proper, with the residential registration offices (Einwohnermeldeämter), fiscal authorities, housing offices, district courts, employment offices, and further with the chambers of trade and commerce, trade guilds, savings banks and other banks, and, last but not least, with the Reichsbahn (state railroad).¹⁰ In the German occupied territories, this pattern was repeated, despite considerable regional differences. In the final phase of the victims' complete defenselessness, there was a downright enrichment race
¹¹ in both the Aryanization
and the plundering of household and other personal belongings between the Gestapo and the finance administration¹² and, under the supervision of public authorities, between companies, private individuals, and banks.¹³
The third aspect concerns the interrelation of the differing segments of tactical and strategic German warfare and occupying politics with the mass murder of the European Jews. The studies by Aly,¹⁴ Dieckmann,¹⁵ Gerlach,¹⁶Gutberger,¹⁷ Heim and Aly,¹⁸ Herbert,¹⁹ Müller²⁰ and Friedrich²¹ describe the interlocking of varying logics of action and interests within German warfare and occupation politics and their effects on the initiation and implementation of the Holocaust. This reflected the polycratic
conglomerate of, for instance, health policy, population politics, economic planning, agriculture and nutrition, and warfare. Toward the representatives of the respective spheres of interests, the SS and Gestapo apparatus acted partly as a partner in cooperation and yet partly as an opponent within the sphere of their respective interests.
However overwhelming the diversity of actors and institutions involved in the persecution, the ways in which division of labor was linked to perpetrator agency have, by and large, remained unexplored. The present volume focuses on these issues.
One important fact to be acknowledged is that the formal status of division of labor varied substantially. it ranged from highly formalized and tightly coupled relationships between participating agencies to ephemeral and loosely coupled linkages between individual actors. Weberian bureaucracy with rigid rules and hierarchies did play a crucial role in the preparation and execution of persecution and mass murder. German fiscal administration with its endeavor to confiscate as much of the Jewish assets as possible is a prominent example.²² it would be misleading to assume, however, that the machinery of public administration always acted in accordance with the conventional rules of hierarchy and regulated cooperation as far as the persecution of the Jews was concerned. A striking phenomenon is the self-initiative of local and regional authorities, which often took independent steps of anti-Jewish discrimination and persecution years ahead of central Reich regulations, and then asked for central coordination for the sake of homogeneity.²³ While this largely reflects the influence of local Nazi leaders in municipal administration, state administration, too, rigidly implemented anti-Jewish regulation without central initiation or coordination.²⁴Moreover, public authorities and the Nazi party organization were not just acting as law-abiding agencies. Bribery and corruption were an integral part of the persecution.²⁵
Other organizational forms of persecution were much more informal, and yet at least as effective as public bureaucracy. The spoliation of Jewish assets, the Aryanization
of Jewish-owned firms in particular, required a vast array of expertise and institutional assistance. Banks, brokers, law firms, investors (often former competitors), and intermediaries of the Nazi party as well as local and regional administration formed networks of spoliation and persecution whose extension and structure are illustrated in several chapters in this volume.²⁶ What made those networks stable and effective was, above all, the mutual benefit of those involved.
Networks and the presumptive source of their formation and stability make us aware that, although individuals persecuted the Jews in obedience to orders and in accordance with their own anti-Semitism, neither hierarchy nor ideology was an indispensable prerequisite for the active involvement in mass crime. As the chapters in this volume illustrate, individuals contributed to the radicalization of anti-Jewish policy without following orders or a particular commitment to anti-Semitism. Apparently, the motivational basis of persecution was much more encompassing. However extended the variety of motives of persecutors and their helpers, motivation was not just contingent. What several chapters of this book reveal is the coordinating and legitimizing role of professions and institutions. The looting of Jewish property or the Aryanization
of Jewish businesses, for instance, was certainly stimulated by crude enrichment. But many accomplices had only limited opportunities-if any-to enrich themselves personally. Rather, they fulfilled what they perceived as an obligation toward professional standards and institutional roles as bankers, insurance representatives, lawyers, civil servants of the fiscal administration, etc. Those roles and standards, however, were not strictly binding. They certainly provided strong incentives but also left considerable leeway for personal choices.
It is here that anti-Semitism did play a crucial role in two dimensions. One is that many peripheral but indispensable actors within the persecution apparatuses shared anti-Semitic stereotypes and approved anti-Jewish measures in general. Removing Jews from entire industries and combating them as a group of uncertain loyalty to the Reich were what many outside the orbit of the SS and Gestapo perceived as justifiable and appropriate even if they did not share the idea of physical extermination. Once anti-Jewish stereotypes had been adopted, principled resistance against more radical steps of persecution was very unlikely. A second function of anti-Semitism as state ideology was coordination regardless of personal conviction. The anti-Jewish agenda produced signals that were unmistakably simple and unambiguous and, thus, could be taken into account independently of individual persuasion. In combination with the permanent threat of violent coercion, state anti-Semitism played a powerful role in homogenizing the action of tens of thousands of helpers
who would not have taken the initiative to persecute the Jews themselves but did not hesitate to comply with the persecution once it was initiated by those in power.
The Structure of Organized Mass Crime
and Moral Responsibility
Regardless of its uniqueness in history, the Holocaust shares crucial characteristics with organized mass crime in general, of which the present volume stresses networks and division of labor as predominant structural features. Organized crime is obviously a structural phenomenon, but a merely structural perspective entails obvious risks of misinterpretation. Criminal action, like any kind of human agency, is embedded in social structures in the sense of regularities of interindividual relationship, but crime as such is committed by responsible individuals. Assessing the degree of personal responsibility is what the structural analysis of organized crime should be ultimately aiming at. As the sense of moral obligation remains the very basis for distinguishing between right and wrong, the analysis of formal and informal structures of human agency can never exculpate individuals whose wrongdoing is beyond any doubt. But the analysis will nonetheless reveal regularities of interindividual and interorganizational relationship that enhance or reduce the risk of individual wrongdoing.
Networks are a particular case in point. Interindividual and interorganizational networks are portrayed in the relevant literature as an alternative to conventional governance in terms of public and corporate bureaucracy.²⁷Deeper insight into the nature of organized crime, however, challenges such appraisals. The evidence presented in this volume, both empirical and theoretical in nature, supports the assumption that informal, network-type mechanisms of governance on the one hand and traditional bureaucracies on the other hand were equally effective in mobilizing human resources for evil purposes during the Holocaust. Certainly, one important difference between good
and evil
networks resides in the macro-political order in which they are embedded. But networks as a type of organized crime per se represent issues of judgment, leadership, and morality. The leadership of network elites may be designed either to mobilize or to demobilize human resources. The mobilization of networks of persecution, for instance, was dependent on intellectual capability, moral judgment, and ideological zeal.
However, when it comes to organized mass crime, moral judgment is obviously not only a matter of the leadership of criminal elites but also a matter of the compliance and support of rank-and-file participants. Support of participants and organizational cohesion, as described in organization-theory classics,²⁸ are fundamentally ambivalent phenomena based on an interplay of selfishness and legitimacy. On the one hand, it is precisely not the willingness to cooperate for the sake of common goals which makes organizations stable, powerful, and effective. Rather, individuals use organizations for personal purposes such as income, career promotion, etc. The decoupling of organizational performance from personal commitment to organizational goals makes organizations much more effective than cooperation on the basis of shared goals, the reason being the enormous diversification of motivational sources. Networks, reaching far beyond the boundaries of formal organization, even enlarge this diversity. On the other hand, despite the dominant role of personal purposes, individuals are not unaware of organizational goals and no sustainable integration or true leadership can be based on immoral organizational purposes.²⁹ That is why organized mass crime is intrinsically connected to legitimating concepts and ideological rationalizations.
The very ambivalence of organizations as such makes the structure of organized mass crime robust and vulnerable at the same time. The robustness stems from the decoupling of individual motivation from organizational goals, which makes organized evil
decisively more dangerous than mobilization through shared goals or beliefs. The reason is, again, the enormous diversification of motivational sources.³⁰ The opacity and blurriness of networks do not help to reduce those risks. The fact, however, that individuals (accomplices, willing executioners,
collaborators,
etc.), in spite of all their selfishness, remain aware of organizational goals implies, first, that accomplices remain accountable for what they are doing even when they act in networks that are fluid and opaque in nature and, secondly, that the separation of organizational goals and individual motivation is limited by the quest for legitimacy and identity.³¹
If there is good sense in acknowledging that moral indifference is basically an unstable mind set,³² this will also affect the moral indifference of accomplices: Hence the potential influence of moral standards and, not least, examples of civil courage and moral leadership.³³ Raising moral costs for accomplices can make the decisive difference and, therefore, is an important element of public awareness and policy. What Holocaust research reveals is not just the structural complexity of the persecution machinery but also the failure to observe the most elementary moral imperatives. Sustaining those imperatives remains as much an obligation as analyzing the linkage between agency
and structure,
without which even the highest moral standards will fail in a world of complex organizations.
Organization of the Volume
The present volume is organized according to three principal configurations of division of labor and mobilization of individuals and agencies for persecution. The three thematic parts are introduced by prominent scholars in the field, Christian Gerlach, Gerhard Hirschfeld and Wolfgang Seibel, and Michael T. Allen. A concluding part is devoted to general issues of network analysis and division of labor when it comes to Holocaust research.
Part I with chapters by Wolfgang Dierker, Dieter Ziegler, Philippe Verheyde, Martin Dean, Jonathan Petropoulos and Frank Bajohr, refers to rivalry and competition as intensifying rather than impeding forces of persecution. Precisely because the persecution machinery was neither monolithic nor exclusively hierarchical, distribution of jurisdiction and power remained often blurred and contested. However, competition among individuals and agencies and eagerness to conquer or to defend jurisdiction in Judenangelegenheiten (Jewish affairs) rarely caused persistent friction. Rather, as with competition elsewhere, the result was a growing effort to outperform rivals, which crucially radicalized the persecution.
Part II with chapters by Alfons Kenkmann, Gerard Aalders, Marc-Olivier Baruch, Isabel Heinemann and Wendy Lower provides an alternative view on the consequences of division of labor. The chapters in this section analyze how perpetrators aptly coordinated their respective interests and strategies. This may prevent us from overstating the image of organized chaos
as an ingredient of Nazi rule. Persecuting and annihilating the Jews were at the core of Nazi Germany's policy in all of Europe during World War ii. While it is undeniable that division of labor and the network-type blurriness of jurisdiction and competencies had a particular impact on the implementation of the Holocaust, the perpetrators often were smart and energetic enough to overcome the disadvantages of administrative fragmentation.
Part III with chapters by Wolf Gruner and Gerald D. Feldman, sheds new light on the relationship between decentralized initiatives and central coordination when it comes to anti-Jewish policy in Nazi Germany. In the domains of both police repression and the economy local or nongovernmental actors either initiated measures against the Jews or skillfully anticipated and operationalized what they perceived as the will of the ruling clique. The vertical axis of division of labor and reintegration is of particular interest. in some instances, as in the case of the municipal administration, decentralized agencies used traditional techniques of self-coordination in an effort to homogenize and thus radicalize anti-Jewish policy. In other instances, as in the case of the German insurance industry, anticipatory obedience led to flexible adaptation vis-à-vis the regime's anti-Jewish agenda at the expense of moral and professional standards.
In the concluding part IV, Jörg Raab and Wolfgang Seibel provide a discussion of networks, division of labor and the Holocaust from a social science perspective. Networks are more than just a metaphor. In recent decades, research has made considerable progress in the measurement and visualization of the informal relationship between individuals and institutions. Making networks of persecution measurable and visible is a most challenging task. Moreover, taking individual intention and its impact on the persecution seriously requires a reconciliation of methodological individualism with structural analysis. This implies building hypotheses on how division of labor and the differentiation of power within the persecution apparatus affected both the room to manoeuvre and the incentive structure of the perpetrators and their helpers.
Building and testing those hypotheses remains a challenge to future interdisciplinary research.
Acknowledgments
This volume originated from an international conference held at the University of Konstanz, Germany, in September 2000, which was generously supported by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG). The University of Konstanz sponsored the preparation of the present publication, including the translation of several contributions into English, through additional research funds. Final editing was made at the Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton, where Wolfgang Seibel was a member of the School of Historical Studies in the second term of the academic year 2003–2004. The editors wish to thank James Fearns for translating the German papers selected for publication. Jürgen Klöckler and Insa Meinen, with the assistance of Anja Bertsch, Till Blume, Julia Galka, Katrin-Isabel Krähling and Tina Schmidt-Böhringer, assumed the tedious task of revising the manuscripts according to the publisher's formal demands.
The volume is dedicated to the memory of Roger V. Gould (1962–2002), a pioneer of historical network analysis, who served admirably as a general commentator to the conference from which this book emerged.
Notes
1. Raul Hilberg, The Destruction of the European Jews, 3 vols. (New York, 1985); Uwe Dietrich Adam, Judenpolitik im Dritten Reich (Düsseldorf, 1973); Hans G. Adler, Der verwaltete Mensch. Studien zur Deportation der Juden aus Deutschland (Tübingen, 1974); Lucy S. Dawidowicz, The War Against the Jews 1933–1945 (Toronto/New York, 1975); Gerald Reitlinger, The Final Solution. The Attempt to Exterminate the Jews of Europe, 1939–1945 (London, 1953).
2. Hannah Arendt, Eichmann in Jerusalem. A Report on the Banality of Evil (New York, 1963); see further Guy B. Adams and Danny L. Balfour, Unmasking Administrative Evil (London, 1998), pp. 15–19, 53–72; Zygmunt Bauman, Modernity and the Holocaust (Ithaca, 1989); Hans Mommsen, Die Realisierung des Utopischen. Die Endlösung der ‘Judenfrage’ im Dritten Reich,
Geschichte und Gesellschaft 9 (1983): 381–420; J.C. Scott, Seeing like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed (New Haven London, 1998), pp. 76–83.
3. Cornelis J. Lammers, The Interorganizational Control of an Occupied Country,
Administrative Science Quarterly, 33 (1988): 438–457; idem, Macht und Autorität des Deutschen Besetzers in den Niederlanden während des Zweiten Weltkrieges. Ansätze zu einer Soziologie der Besatzung,
Journal für Sozialforschung, 31 (1991): 401–415; idem, Levels of Cooperation: A Comparative Study of German Occupation Regimes during the Second World War,
in Robert Bohn, ed., Die deutsche Herrschaft in den ‘germanischen’ Ländern 1940–1945 (Stuttgart, 1997), pp. 47–69.
4. See Wolfgang Seibel in the present volume.
5. Patrick Kenis and Volker Schneider, Policy Networks and Policy Analysis: Scrutinizing a New Analytical Toolbox,
in Bernd Marin and Renate Mayntz, eds., Policy Networks (Frankfurt on Main/New York, 1991), pp. 25–59; David Knoke, Political Networks: The Structural Perspective (Cambridge/New York, 1990); Renate Mayntz, Policy-Networks und die Logik von Verhandlungssystemen,
in Renate Mayntz, ed., Soziale Dynamik (Frankfurt on Main/New York, 1993), pp. 239–262; Walter W. Powell, Neither Market Nor Hierarchy: Network Forms of Organization,
Research in Organizational Behavior 12 (1990): 295–336. For an example of empirical network analysis applied to Holocaust research see Wolfgang Seibel and Jörg Raab, Verfolgungsnetzwerke. Zur Messung von Arbeitsteilung und Machtdifferenzierung in den Verfolgungsapparaten des Holocaust,
Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 55(2003): 197–230.
6. Jens Banach, Heydrichs Elite. Das Führerkorps der Sicherheitspolizei und des SD 1936–1945 (Paderborn, 1998); Richard Breitman, The Architect of Genocide. Himmler and the ‘Final Solution’ (London, 1991); Ruth Bettina Birn, Die höheren SS- und Polizeiführer. Himmlers Vertreter im Reich und in den besetzten Gebieten (Düsseldorf, 1986); George C. Browder, Foundations of the Nazi Police State: The Formation of Sipo and SD (Lexington, 1990); idem, Hitler's Enforcers. The Gestapo and the SS Security Service in the Nazi Revolution (New York/Oxford, 1996); Hans Buchheim, Martin Broszat, Hans-Adolf Jacobsen, and Helmut Krausnick, Anatomie des SS-Staates, 2 vols. (Munich, 1967); Robert Gellately, Situating the ‘SS-State’ in a Social-Historical Context: Recent Histories of the SS, the Police, and the Courts in the Third Reich,
Journal of Modern History 64 (1992): 338–365; Gerhard Paul and Klaus-Michael Mallmann, eds., Die Gestapo. Mythos und Realität (Darmstadt, 1995); Friedrich Wilhelm, Die Polizei im NS-Staat. Die Geschichte ihrer Organisation im Überblick (Paderborn, 1997); and the contribution of Wolfgang Dierker in the present volume.
7. Wolfgang Seibel, The Strength of Perpetrators-The Holocaust in Western Europe, 1940–1944,
Governance-An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions 15 (2002): 211–240.
8. Johannes Bähr, Der Goldhandel der Dresdner Bank während des Zweiten Weltkriegs (Leipzig, 1999); Avraham Barkai, Von Boykott zur ‘Entjudung’. Der wirtschaftliche Existenzkampf der Juden 1933–1943 (Frankfurt on Main, 1987); Frank Bajohr, Arisierung
in Hamburg. Die Verdrängung der jüdischen Unternehmer 1933–1945 (Hamburg, 1997); Gerald D. Feldman, Allianz and the German Insurance Business, 1933–1945 (Cambridge, 2001); Helmut Genschel, Die Verdrängung der Juden aus der Wirtschaft im Dritten Reich (Göttingen, 1966); Harold James, Die Deutsche Bank und die Arisierung
(Munich, 2001); Gerhard Kratzsch, Der Gauwirtschaftsapparat der NSDAP. Menschenführung, Arisierung
, Wehrwirtschaft im Gau Westfalen-Süd. Eine Studie zur Herrschaftspraxis im totalitären Staat (Münster, 1989); Johannes Ludwig, Boykott, Enteignung, Mord. Die Entjudung
der deutschen Wirtschaft (Hamburg, 1989); Jonathan Steinberg, Die Deutsche Bank und ihre Goldtransaktionen während des Zweiten Weltkrieges (Munich, 1999) ; Dieter Ziegler, Die Verdrängung der Juden aus der Dresdner Bank 1933–1938,
Vierteljahrshefte für Zeitgeschichte 47 (1999): 187–216; and contributions by Dieter Ziegler, Philippe Verheyde, Martin Dean, Jonathan Petropoulos, Frank Bajohr, Alfons Kenkmann, Marc Olivier Baruch, and Gerald D. Feldman in the present volume.
9. See for France Commission Mattéoli [Mission d'étude sur la Spoliation des Juifs de France], Rapport final de la Mission d'étude sur la spoliation des Juifs en France,
(Paris, 2000); for Belgium Commission Buysse [Commission d'étude sur le sort des biens des membres de la communauté juive de Belgique spoliés ou délaissés pendant la guerre 1940–1945], Rapport final: Les Biens des victimes des persécutions anti-juives en Belgique (Brussels, 2001); for The Netherlands Gerard Aalders, Roof. De ontvremding van joods bezit tijdens de Tweede Wereldoorlog (The Hague, 1999).
10. See Adler, Mensch, pp. 323–437; Wolfgang Dreßen, Betrifft: Aktion 3
. Deutsche verwerten jüdische Nachbarn (Berlin, 1998); Michael Zimmermann, Die Gestapo und die regionale Organisation der Judendeportationen. Das Beispiel der Stapo-Leitstelle Düsseldorf,
in Paul and Mallmann, Gestapo, pp. 357–372.
11. Bajohr, Arisierung, p. 265.
12. Barkai, Entjudung, pp. 189–198.
13. Adler, Mensch, pp. 589–644; Bajohr, Arisierung, pp. 265–324; Barkai, Entjudung, pp. 189–203; Franziska Becker, Gewalt und Gedächtnis. Erinnerungen an die nationalsozialistische Verfolgung einer jüdischen Landgemeinde (Göttingen, 1994); Alex Bruns-Wüstefeld, Lohnende Geschäfte: Die Entjudung
der Wirtschaft am Beispiel Göttingens (Hanover, 1997); Dreßen, Aktion 3; Genschel, Verdrängung, pp. 249–255; Bob Moore, Victims and Survivor: The Nazi Persecution of the Jews in the Netherlands 1940–1945 (London, 1997), pp. 104–106; Zimmermann, Gestapo
, pp. 357–372.
14. Götz Aly, Endlösung
. Völkerverschiebung und der Mord an den europäischen Juden (Frankfurt, 1995).
15. Christoph Dieckmann, Der Krieg und die Ermordung der litauischen Juden,
in Ulrich Herbert, ed., Nationalsozialistische Vernichtungspolitik 1933–1945. Neue Forschungen und Kontroversen (Frankfurt on Main, 1998), pp. 292–329.
16. Christian Gerlach, Krieg, Ernährung, Völkermord. Forschungen zur deutschen Vernichtungspolitik im Zweiten Weltkrieg (Hamburg, 1998); idem, Kalkulierte Morde. Die deutsche Wirtschafts- und Vernichtungspolitik in Weißrußland 1941 bis 1944 (Hamburg, 1999).
17. Jörg Gutberger, Volk, Raum und Sozialstruktur. Sozialstruktur- und Sozialraumforschung im Dritten Reich
(Münster, 1996).
18. Susanne Heim and Götz Aly, Vordenker der Vernichtung. Auschwitz und die deutschen Pläne für eine neue europäische Ordnung (Frankfurt on Main, 1991).
19. Ulrich Herbert, Die deutsche Militärverwaltung in Paris und die Deportation der französischen Juden,
in Herbert, Nationalsozialistische Vernichtungspolitik, pp. 170–208.
20. Rolf-Dieter Müller, Hitlers Ostkrieg und die deutsche Siedlungspolitik. Die Zusammenarbeit von Wehrmacht, Wirtschaft und SS (Frankfurt on Main, 1991).
21. Jörg Friedrich, Das Gesetz des Krieges. Das deutsche Heer in Rußland 1941–1945. Der Prozeß gegen das Oberkommando der Wehrmacht, 2nd ed. (Munich, 1996).
22. See contributions by Martin Dean and Alfons Kenkmann in the present volume.
23. See contribution by Wolf Gruner.
24. See again Alfons Kenkmann in this volume.
25. See contribution by Frank Bajohr.
26. See contributions by Gerald D. Feldman, Jonathan Petropoulos, Philippe Verheyde and Dieter Ziegler.
27. See H. Brinton Milward, Governing the Hollow State,
Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 10, no. 2 (2000): 359–379; Mark Thatcher, The Development of Policy Network Analysis,
Journal of Theoretical Politics 10 (1998): 389–416, for recent overviews.
28. See Chester I. Barnard, The Functions of the Executive, Thirtieth Anniversary Edition (Cambridge, 1968); Herbert A. Simon, Administrative Behavior. A Study of Decision-Making Process in Administrative Organization (New York, 1945).
29. Philip Selznick, Leadership in Administration: A Sociological Interpretation (New York/Evanston/London, 1957), as the classic reference and Steven P. Feldman, Memory as a Moral Decision: The Role of Ethics in Organizational Culture (Somerset, 2002) for a recent account.
30. A similar point, emphasizing the role of exchange and interorganizational competition, is made by James Buchanan, A Defense of Organized Crime?
in Simon Rottenberg, ed., The Economics of Crime and Punishment (Washington D.C., 1973), pp. 119–132, with respect to organized crime in general and by Albert Breton and Ronald Wintrobe, The Bureaucracy of Murder Revisited,
Journal of Political Economy 94 (1986): 905–926, with respect to the Holocaust in particular. Ian Kershaw, Hitler: 1936–45: Nemesis (London, 2000), pp. 1–60 (Ceaseless Radicalization
), gives a rich account of the disastrous dynamics resulting from the diffuse linkage between the various motives at the grass-roots level that made ordinary Germans comply with dictatorship and the overarching goals of Hitler and his clique. In a similar vein, Wolfgang Seibel, A Market for Mass Crime? Inter-Institutional Competition and the Initiation of the Holocaust in France, 1940–1942,
Journal of Organization Theory and Behavior 5 (2002): 219–217, analyzes French-German collaboration in the preparation of the Holocaust in France.
31. Harrison C. White, Identity and Control. A Structural Theory of Social Action (Princeton, 1992), for identity and control in interorganizational networks.
32. Thomas M. Scanlon, What We Owe to Each Other (Cambridge, 1998).
33. See Martin Gilbert, The Righteous. The Unsung Heroes of the Holocaust (New York, 2003).
PART I
RIVALRY AND COMPETITION
CHAPTER 1
INTRODUCTION: RIVALRY AND COMPETITION
Christian Gerlach
Research about National Socialism in the 1970s and early 1980s showed results on the structures of the regime that were surprising at the time. It turned out that instead of a monolithic bureaucratic machinery working from top to bottom there were several sources of political power. An increasing number of rival agencies, institutions and organizations had overlapping or unclearly defined responsibilities. According to the theory of polycracy, they competed for influence and more competence.¹ In the absence of clear legal and administrative norms, high-ranking Nazis struggled for Hitler's favor, one trying to outdo the other in what they thought was expected. According to the interpretation of structuralist
or functionalist
scholars, it was more this struggle than Nazi ideology that brought about a radicalization of Nazi policy, leading ultimately to the Holocaust. And Hitler in fact supported the most radical figures.² One of the effects of the Nazi system, as seen by this school, was consequently that rivalry absorbed political energies, led increasingly to inner tensions, and favored a tendency of the system toward self-destruction, which may have accelerated its end.³
Some aspects of this model have turned out to be too simple or overly theoretical. There was criticism that the importance of ideology had been neglected, that the impression of a paralyzing chaos was misleading, and that radicalization
was sometimes imagined as having been produced by anonymous structures in a process in which any real actors had vanished. New empirical studies, based on much richer source material, have demonstrated that historical dynamics were much more complex. It has been underscored that different German institutions acted in a much more consensual way, especially in the occupied territories, where lack of manpower forced them to cooperate. one could even say that the crucial focus of recent works has been on cooperation rather than competition (see part II of the present volume). While there is no doubt about the correctness of the idea that the rivalry of different institutions did spur on German mass crimes, it has to be kept in mind that this was no more than one of the roots of violence.
All the chapters of the following section except one deal with the expropriation, the plundering and the utilization of property, focusing on Jewish property. Thus it seems to be appropriate to discuss the issue of rivalry, competition, and efficiency primarily with regard to the looting of property only—all the more so because wealth, money, and valuables are among the strongest incentives for competition that can be imagined (and among the strongest incentives for violence).
In recent years there has been a wave of research on the plundering of Jewish assets (as well as forced labor), fueled by growing public interest. National governments, several banks, and business companies employed historians in order to explore their past when they came under pressure. An increasing number of the resulting works have become part of the current debate in the scholarly field. However, the contributions to the present section view the issue of competition for Jewish property from different angles. Martin Dean emphazises official cooperation and control of expropriated assets, while Frank Bajohr stresses individual gains and corruption. Where Jonathan Petropoulos sees a race between several institutions and organizations for works of art with an open ending, Dean analyzes an exclusive conflict between the SS and state financial institutions. Dieter Ziegler argues that big German private banks competed in the Aryanization
business, struggling for shares of the market, whereas Philippe Verheyde comes to the conclusion that, despite efforts of German private firms, German occupational institutions in France restricted their attempts to take over French-Jewish capital. Ziegler points to state influence on big business as a result of the global economic crisis of the early 1930s; Verheyde and Dean see state and party institutions in control of the expropriation process, while Bajohr and Petropoulos argue that individual or particularist initiatives made any control an illusion. This reflects the complex and contradictory picture of recent Holocaust research. Especially if one changes the perspective and tries to take on the view of the victims, competitive initiative from below contributed to a complete and merciless persecution. This point is stressed by Petropoulos, Bajohr and Wolfgang Dierker below. It is particularly obvious in Martin Dean's analysis of the cooperation between tax offices, the Gestapo and private banks when robbing Jews who wanted to emigrate by using the instrument of the Flight Tax
(Reichsfluchtsteuer).⁴ Also, Dierker's analysis of the rivalry between the Security Service of the SS (Sicherheitsdienst or SD) and the Gestapo demonstrates that inter-agency competition had an radicalizing effect even in the inner circles of the persecutors.
The issue of corruption recently discussed in an important study by Frank Bajohr⁵ is an aspect crucial to the understanding of the process of redistribution of Jewish property. Corruption contradicted the principal interest of state authorities in seizing the property of enemies
for the state and, from 1939, for the support of the war effort. Bajohr suggests that a clear distinction between what he calls official, tolerated, and prosecuted corruption is hardly conceivable; the official reaction to, say, black-market activities could change over time and furthermore depended on place, on the persons involved, and on the situation. This means that the system tolerated several exceptions to state control over expropriated assets. Bajohr presents impressive material, emphasizing how common personal gain was and how big the sums of money involved were. Bajohr can even point to several cases in which functionaries pressed for the Jewish victims of their blackmail to be killed or deported to be sure that they would not claim their money back. He presents the Nazi Party as an important driving force behind corruption, calling their activities an economic assistance program
in which Aryanization,
corruption, and the Party's illegal funding could hardly be distinguished. The Reichsrechnungshof (German Auditor General) could not prevent large sums being embezzled. It is sadly ironic and an absurd example of German bureaucracy that in July 1945, when the city of Potsdam, where this institution was located, had already been under Soviet administration for two months, the Reichsrechnungshof considered investigating the activities of Eichmann's Reichszentrale für jüdische Auswanderung (Reich Central Office for Jewish Emigration), once again because of indications of financial irregularities.⁶
Still, the question remains how useful it is to define corruption
in such a broad way that it includes, for example, no less than much of the financing of the Nazi Party.⁷ This normative term, which is commonly associated with chaos and devious practices, may obscure the view on negotiations to balance out different group interests. In principle, the assets of persons who were expropriated in Nazi Germany were to be appropriated by the state, which was to utilize them for the benefits of the national community.
Four types of competitors could come into conflict with national interests defined that way: first, private individuals (including, most importantly, public officials trying to set aside their personal share) and companies; secondly, nongovernmental organizations pursuing their particular interests, that is, mainly Nazi Party suborganizations; thirdly, public institutions (for example, regional bodies) that placed their institutional interests above the national
interest; and, fourthly, foreign institutions, groups, or individuals whose demands were to be met.
The most important nongovernmental organization involved in the plunder of Jewish property, aside from regional Nazi Party offices inside Germany, was, not surprisingly, the SS. Correcting outdated images of an SS victorious
in the administrative struggle in the East, Martin Dean concludes in this section that finally, by and large, the civil administration in the German-occupied Soviet territories achieved the control over the property of Soviet Jewry that it had claimed from the very beginning. The idea that the property of Jews was to be secured for the Reich remained stronger than particularism, though only after a long struggle on the upper administrative levels (whereas cooperation usually worked better at ground level). A similar development could be observed in the General Government of Poland, where the civil administration kept their hands on the real estate of murdered Jews, which the SS tried to get at least until early 1944.⁸ This was a setback for the ambitions of the Reich Commissioner for the Strengthening of Germandom, an organization under the control of the SS, to organize a more systematic settlement policy in the General Government than the civil administration endorsed. The latter went to the limit in robbing the Jews. On 28 July 1942, six days after the huge deportations from the Warsaw ghetto to the Treblinka death camp had started, the Finance Department of the General Government even tried to collect the tax arrears of the murdered Jews from the organizer of the deportations, the SS and Police Leader of the District of Lublin, Odilo Globocnik. The Finance Department blackmailed Globocnik with demands that otherwise he would have to pay sales tax in retrospect for the SS-owned industrial enterprise Deutsche Ausrüstungswerke (DAW) at Lublin.⁹
Another example of rivalry between different public institutions is presented by Jonathan Petropoulos. After the annexation of Austria and the nationwide pogrom in 1938, the German state tried to control the plunder of art. But the many rival agencies—often acting in the name of highest-ranking Nazis, such as Hitler, Göring, and Himmler, but also including municipal museums—competed for the best booty in the occupied territories too. Cooperation or even alliances
between agencies were often necessary to succeed. Art historians and art dealers constituted a network, one knowing the activities of the other and all of them gaining much for themselves. In the absence of a central institution organizing the robbery and distribution of art, such rival networks determined the outcome.
Corruption was indeed part of the Nazi system. But it would be misleading to conclude that this made it impossible for German politicians or functionaries to pursue ideological or economic plans—in regard not only to mass murder but also to the control and redistribution of property. Corruption both limited and increased the efficiency of Aryanization.
It is correct that very many of the German representatives, soldiers, police, and others in the occupied territories tried to profit for themselves, hunting for money or valuables. This is of special importance here because 95 percent of all victims of the extermination of European Jewry lived outside Germany and Austria. What happened in many places resembles the story of the Spanish forcing Inca Atahualpa to fill a room with gold items three times before killing him.
Yet the lion's share of the loot from the Holocaust consisted of real estate and land property, confiscated bank accounts, shops and factories, furniture, and household equipment. Most of this remained out of reach for corrupt officials. There was a general German policy according to which the bulk of Jewish property was to fall into the hands of the national administration, at least in most occupied countries, rather than directly into German hands, in order to cushion the burdens of the occupation and maintain some social stability. The case of French-Jewish businesses analyzed by Philippe Verheyde in this section is one example. From his sample of 175 big business companies, there was German interference in 41 cases, and only 4 percent of the capital of his sample actually fell into German hands. The reason was, verheyde argues, not only French [passive, C.G.] resistance…but also a sort of self-limitation of German greed.
The expropriation was based on French anti-Jewish laws of 1940–1941, stimulated or inspired by the Germans, who noted that such a policy strengthened participation in anti-Jewish persecution. verheyde notes that, while the Germans determined the actions or gave the impulse, it was the French who organized the expropriation, creating an institution of more than 1,000 employees in 1944. Following a pattern observed in other occupied European countries as well, 97 percent of the small Jewish enterprises in France were closed to the benefit of their Aryan
competitors.
Another example of this approach can be found in Borisov, Byelorussia, in the German-occupied Soviet territories: after the 8,000 Jews of this town with an overall population of 30,000 had been shot in October 1941, clothes, shoes, and furniture were distributed among the local Byelorussians, who lived in disastrous need of such articles. Nearly 70 percent were not given away freely but sold in order to absorb purchasing power. Finally, the German Economic Inspectorate of the Army Group Center received the proceeds of 300,000 rubles, whereas the local Byelorussian financial administration received 1.57 million Rubles.¹⁰ The inhabitants of Borisov also benefited from empty flats and houses where the Jews had lived. In many European countries parts of the local population profited from and were corrupted by taking over large parts of the Jewish property.
The example of Hungary under German occupation in 1944 demonstrates that some dimensions of the problem of mass involvement in the Holocaust can hardly be understood if one does not take these beneficial effects into consideration. Especially the role of the state—in this case the Hungarian and, indirectly, the German state via the occupation costs —has often been neglected, a role that was invisible from the victim's perspective and for most other observers. The Hungarian state redistributed property by selling the belongings of Jews, absorbing purchasing power, and taking land and real estate to include in its budget, thus considerably contributing to the funding of the war effort, combatting imminent inflation, expanding social services for non-Jews, and mobilizing the population, satisfying it with accommodation and consumer goods. only when the SS took over 51 percent of the shares of Hungary's biggest armament company, through blackmailing the Jewish owner family, did a substantial conflict with the Hungarian government occur, which forced Hitler personally to require Himmler to cooperate with the Hungarians.¹¹ In other words, the Nazi state—though not in total control—was partly able to accept and integrate corruption of its own officials, able to corrupt many people in occupied countries, and still able to take massive financial benefits from Jewish property for itself. Corruption and the ideological aims of the Nazis represented less of a contradiction than one might think, and, by and large, it seems that corruption did not paralyze the system. New questions in this direction will be needed in future research.
A comparative view on genocide and its economic underpinning may help to further elucidate the pecularities of the Nazi system of appropriation, as well as that of one of her allies (Hungary). The expropriation of Armenian property was one of the driving forces behind the destruction of the Armenians in the Ottoman Empire during World War I. As in the cases of Germany and Hungary—and in fact with measures that were amazingly similar to those of the Hungarians—the Ottoman government tried to lay hands on all of the Armenian property. However, the ability of this state to take control, to collect, to register, and to protect the loot was much more limited. It did use Armenian farms to resettle hundreds of thousands of refugees and put former Armenian hospitals or schools at public disposal. And yet the idea of utilizing such values for general social policy purposes was less influential. Instead, the Ottoman government supported the redistribution of the most important part of Armenian property—businesses in commerce, finance, and trade—to local elites, which consisted of Muslim businessmen, party members of the Committee for Union and Progress, and the traditional elites (dignitaries and big landowners) in order to create a new commercial Muslim bourgeoisie that was considered reliable.
The method of achieving this was channelized corruption, with some control exerted by local party bureaus and new business associations.¹² By contrast, in Hungary and in Nazi Germany, economic elites took their profits from the expropriation of Jews, too, yet both states – commanding much stronger bureaucratic machineries and equipped with a different philosophy on social policy – redistributed larger sums to workers and the petite bourgeoisie in order to keep the lower classes under control.
In what has been the most extreme argument made about this to date, Götz Aly has recently argued that Nazi Germany's tax policy tended to burden the wealthy and benefit the socially weak, making use of resources gained through mass murder, the expropriations of Jews, and exploitation of occupied countries. According to Aly, who plays down the responsibility of big business for exploitation and expropriation, this made Germany Hitler's Volksstaat
, or a redistributive state par excellence
( Umverteilungsstaat).¹³
A further important task for future research is reflected in Frank Bajohr's and Dieter Ziegler's demand that the usual administrative perspective on persecution and expropriation of the Jews be enlarged by the dimension of social history. It is necessary to reconstruct the perspective of more or less ordinary individuals, to differentiate between the opportunities they had for action and all the—perhaps contradictory—motives for the way in which they finally acted. The empirical basis for this undertaking, however, is problematic. New sources and a new look at them will be needed for a comprehensive understanding of the plunder of Jewish property and of the Holocaust, in order to understand it as a process created and sustained by individuals.
Notes
1. See Peter Hüttenberger, Nationalsozialistische Polykratie,
Geschichte und Gesellschaft 2 (1976): 417–442.
2. Hans Mommsen, Hitlers Stellung im nationalsozialistischen Herrschaftssystem
and Die Realisierung des Utopischen: Die ‘Endlösung der Judenfrage’ im ‘Dritten Reich’,
in Hans Mommsen, Der Nationalsozialismus und die deutsche Gesellschaft (Reinbek, 1991), pp. 67–101 and pp. 184–232 (the articles were first published in 1981 and 1983, respectively).
3. One recent example is in Ian Kershaw, Hitler: 1936–1945: Nemesis (London, 2000).
4. See also Susanne Heim, Vertreibung, Raub und Umverteilung: Die jüdischen Flüchtlinge aus Deutschland und die Vermehrung des Volksvermögens,
in Flüchtlingspolitik und Fluchthilfe (Beiträge zur nationalsozialistischen Gesundheits- und Sozialpolitik, vol. 15, Berlin, 1999), pp. 107–138; Hans-Dieter Schmid, ‘Finanztod’: Die Zusammenarbeit von Gestapo und Finanzverwaltung bei der Ausplünderung der Juden in Deutschland,
in Gerhard Paul and Klaus-Michael Mallmann, eds., Die Gestapo im Zweiten Weltkrieg: Heimatfront
und besetztes Europa (Darmstadt, 2000), pp. 141–154.
5. Frank Bajohr, Parvenüs und Profiteure: Korruption in der NS-Zeit (Frankfurt on Main, 2001); see also Bajohr's contribution to this section.
6. See German Federal Archives (BA) file R 2301, No. 8420.
7. See the definition in Bajohr, Parvenüs und Profiteure, pp. 7–11.
8. Peter Witte et al. eds., Der Dienstkalender Heinrich Himmlers 1941/42 (Hamburg, 1999), p. 647, n. 77.
9. I refer to our conversation on 28 July 1942, and ask you to pay the tax arrears of the Jews (especially of the Jews from Warsaw) from the assets seized during their resettlement. Then I shall decide about an exemption [of the DAW, C.G.] from the sales tax for the period from 1 January 1942 to 30 June 1942.
Copy of an undated letter to Globocnik; see also Globocnik to Finanzamt Lublin, 21 July 1942; Generalgouvernement, Stadthauptmann Lublin, Finanzinspekteur, to Regierung des Generalgouvernements, Abteilung Finanzen, 24 July 1942; and Regierung des Generalgouvernements, Hauptabteilung Finanzen, 29 August 1942, all in Archivum Akt Novych (Warsaw), 111, no. 1188, pp. 155, 158–159 (back side). Globocnik had requested a tax exemption for the DAW because they were a political
and armaments
institution rather than a business run for profit. It had been decided that the DAW had to pay the tax for the period after 1 July 1942, in any case.
10. Rayon-Leiter Borissow to Wirtschaftskommando Borissow, letter of 5 May 1942 and account 8 September 1941 to 1 April 1942, Oblast Archive Minsk 624-1-8, p. 128 and p. 131; Economic Inspectorate Center, Situation Report of 7 March 1942, German Federal Military Archive Freiburg (BA-MA) F 42858, p. 824.
11. Christian Gerlach and Götz Aly, Das letzte Kapitel: Realpolitik, Ideologie und der Mord an den ungarischen Juden 1944/45 (Stuttgart/Munich, 2002), pp. 186–239, 319–321.
12. See Christian Gerlach, Nationsbildung im Krieg: Wirtschaftliche Faktoren bei der Vernichtung der Armenier und beim Mord an den ungarischen Juden,
in Hans-Lukas Kieser and Dominik Schaller, eds., The Armenian Genocide and the Shoah (Zurich, 2002), pp. 347–422.
13. Götz Aly, Hitlers Volksstaat,
Süddeutsche Zeitung, 10 May 2002.
CHAPTER 2
THE SS SECURITY SERVICE AND THE GESTAPO IN THE NATIONAL SOCIALIST PERSECUTION OF THE JEWS, 1933–1939
Wolfgang Dierker
The SS and the police under the command of Heinrich Himmler were among the chief actors in National Socialist extermination policy. Historians of the Holocaust often tend to regard the two different parts of the SS and police apparatus, the Security Service of the Reichsführer-SS (Sicherheitsdienst—SD) and the Gestapo (Geheime Staatspolizei—Secret State Police), as a single unit.¹ This is entirely justified for the Second World War. The union of their central offices in the Reich Security Main Office (Reichssicherheitshauptamt—RSHA) on 27 September 1939 and their operations in the conquered areas of Europe led to a fusion of SD and Gestapo personnel and institutions; the respective memberships, offices, tasks, and activities became increasingly difficult to separate. But in the prewar years it was a different matter, and the present contribution consequently takes a step back in time. Studies of the ideological policy of the SD Main office are used² to show how the combination of the SD and the Gestapo crystallized and then developed into an instrument of surveillance and coercion based on a division of labor by the beginning of the Second World War. The example of SD Jewish policy shows especially clearly how specific functional assignments and organizational forms influenced both the relationships of the two persecutory organs and the fundamental ideological motivation of persecutory praxis.³ Within a few years the SD became the most efficient, sober, and radical advocate of the "dejewification (Entjudung) of Germany."⁴ A complex relationship to the Gestapo, characterized by both conflict and cooperation, was constitutive of the Security Service. The development of the SD in the pre-war period will be examined from this viewpoint: first the specific features of its functions and organizational structure (I), then its working relationships with the Gestapo (ii), and finally the relationship of National Socialist ideology and political practice in the Jewish policy of the SS intelligence Service (SS-Nachrichtendienst) (III).
I
In August 1931 the retired lieutenant (Oberleutnant zur See a.D.), Reinhard Heydrich was appointed to take over intelligence duties in the SS Reich High Command (Reichsführung SS).⁵ Filled with ambition and a thirst for action, he built up an independent, centrally organized intelligence service and in July 1932 was appointed by Himmler to serve as head of what then was called the Security Service
(Sicherheitsdienst).⁶ As part of the SS, which was based on principles of racial-biological selection, political-ideological radicalism, and military orientation,⁷ the Security Service's mission was to ferret out actual and alleged adversaries of National Socialism. The enemy's fighting methods
were already a central issue in a speech given by the newly commissioned Intelligence Officer Heydrich to SS leaders on 26 August 1931. He warned against the treasonous subversion and spying by the Party's enemies and called for extreme caution in the way members spoke among themselves about matters of concern to the Party.
⁸ The Intelligence officer fanned his audience's fears of hidden traitors in their ranks and simultaneously drew their attention to the need for an effective counterintelligence service such as the one he had just taken over.
In the early period of NS rule the Security Service was politically rather unimportant. Its most important allies were Rudolf Hess, the Deputy of the Führer,
his Chief of Staff, Martin Bormann, and a few NSDAP Reich leaders, who had come to appreciate Himmler's intelligence service as a useful instrument in disputes with the Gauleiter (regional party leaders) and other forces struggling for autonomy in the NSDAP. The regime crisis of early 1934, fostered by dissatisfaction brewing in the SA, assisted the political establishment of the SD. On 9 June 1934 Hess named it the party's sole intelligence and counter-intelligence service and instructed the Gauleiter to pay a certain sum to the Reich leadership to finance it.⁹ Three weeks later the alliance of the Party leadership with Himmler's security organs proved its value, as they played a considerable role in the murders of 30 June 1934.¹⁰After the Röhm affair
the Schutzstaffel (Protection Squad
), formerly subordinate to the SA, was elevated to an independent NSDAP organization, and in the following years it enjoyed a vast expansion in its political power. This finally led to the building up of a huge system of concentration camps and industrial enterprises, its own auxiliary army in the form of the Waffen- SS and a unified Reich Police, linked together with the SS and SD. Against the resistance of NS leaders like the Reich Minister of the Interior, Frick, who stood up for the primacy of regular state authorities, Himmler succeeded in establishing a vast power apparatus, which he increasingly detached from traditional government and administrative networks.
Himmler managed to prevail because his political maneuvers were always tied to ideological goals. The persistent expansion of his power was inseparably linked with a conviction that National Socialism was engaged in a secular struggle with its adversaries, with ultra-Montanism
and Bolshevism,
Jews and Free