Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

From $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Beggar Thy Neighbor: A History of Usury and Debt
Beggar Thy Neighbor: A History of Usury and Debt
Beggar Thy Neighbor: A History of Usury and Debt
Ebook623 pages9 hours

Beggar Thy Neighbor: A History of Usury and Debt

Rating: 3 out of 5 stars

3/5

()

Read preview

About this ebook

The practice of charging interest on loans has been controversial since it was first mentioned in early recorded history. Lending is a powerful economic tool, vital to the development of society but it can also lead to disaster if left unregulated. Prohibitions against excessive interest, or usury, have been found in almost all societies since antiquity. Whether loans were made in kind or in cash, creditors often were accused of beggar-thy-neighbor exploitation when their lending terms put borrowers at risk of ruin. While the concept of usury reflects transcendent notions of fairness, its definition has varied over time and place: Roman law distinguished between simple and compound interest, the medieval church banned interest altogether, and even Adam Smith favored a ceiling on interest. But in spite of these limits, the advantages and temptations of lending prompted financial innovations from margin investing and adjustable-rate mortgages to credit cards and microlending.

In Beggar Thy Neighbor, financial historian Charles R. Geisst tracks the changing perceptions of usury and debt from the time of Cicero to the most recent financial crises. This comprehensive economic history looks at humanity's attempts to curb the abuse of debt while reaping the benefits of credit. Beggar Thy Neighbor examines the major debt revolutions of the past, demonstrating that extensive leverage and debt were behind most financial market crashes from the Renaissance to the present day. Geisst argues that usury prohibitions, as part of the natural law tradition in Western and Islamic societies, continue to play a key role in banking regulation despite modern advances in finance. From the Roman Empire to the recent Dodd-Frank financial reforms, usury ceilings still occupy a central place in notions of free markets and economic justice.

LanguageEnglish
Release dateApr 15, 2013
ISBN9780812207507
Beggar Thy Neighbor: A History of Usury and Debt

Read more from Charles R. Geisst

Related to Beggar Thy Neighbor

Related ebooks

Economics For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Beggar Thy Neighbor

Rating: 3 out of 5 stars
3/5

1 rating0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    Beggar Thy Neighbor - Charles R. Geisst

    Introduction

    After the discovery of America, capital was in demand, and men were ready to pay interest on it. Then the theologians were obliged to review their teachings. If it had come to this, that money must be had, and men would pay interest on it, ecclesiastical ethics must be revised.

    —Richard Henry Dana, 1867

    Seven years before the assassination of Julius Caesar, an acrimonious dispute broke out between Marcus Tullius Cicero, at the time the provincial governor of Cilicia, and Marcus Junius Brutus, a young provincial Roman administrator. The elder statesman chided the younger man for using his administrative post in Cyprus to earn ill-gotten gains at the expense of the local people. Cicero received reports that Brutus had been lending money in Cyprus at four times the maximum rate stipulated by Roman law. To make matters even worse, he did it anonymously through an agent who did not mind using strong-arm tactics to collect the debts. When Cicero brought the matter to his attention, Brutus ignored him and continued to lend money. When he finally returned to Rome, he did so a wealthy man.

    The problem caused Cicero to coin a name for the practice which became a cornerstone of Roman law. The story was told innumerable times over the next eighteen hundred years. The Roman historians dutifully recorded it and Adam Smith alluded to it in the Wealth of Nations. According to Roman law, simple interest was permitted but compound interest was anathema. Compounding had been used in many ancient civilizations, but the Romans eventually made it illegal. By doing so, they also established a tradition that would create much confusion in the centuries to follow. They did not make all interest illegal, only compound or accumulating interest.

    Prohibitions against excessive interest, or more properly usury, have been found in almost all societies since antiquity. Charging interest on loans is the oldest financial practice. It has also been decried almost from the beginning as predatory, with the lender seeking to take advantage of the borrower. Whether loans were made in cash or in kind, unscrupulous lenders were said to be practicing a beggar-thy-neighbor policy by ensuring that the borrowers were disadvantaged to the point of losing their collateral or in extreme cases even losing their freedom or families. Charging simple interest was barely condoned, but charging compound interest was unscrupulous, immoral, and rapacious. It was also practiced with near impunity.

    The problem was clear in the ancient world but became obscured over time. Over the centuries, usury prohibitions became part of civil law, and that unwritten law of nations generally referred to as the natural law. But it was still practiced widely and openly by the accursed moneylenders who quickly became part of legend and literature. This uneasy combination of theory and practice is partially responsible for the uneven patterns of economic development found in Europe from the decline of Rome to the Reformation. In the early Middle Ages especially, all interest was considered usury by the church. Compound interest became Jewish interest, suggesting that it had dark, magical, non-Christian qualities that could be used for expropriation by the lender, considered a societal outsider.

    Through its long history, interest and usury have gone from being anathema to being big business in the contemporary world, but they remain at least partially illegal in many jurisdictions. Many American states still retain laws against criminal interest, or loan-sharking. At the same time, it frequently is ignored in the same places with impunity and only becomes the center of attention in poor economic climates or in times of capital shortage or high inflation. Perhaps that is why it has remained part of the universal canon of proscribed practices. Usury prohibitions firmly are part of the natural law tradition, in that natural law specifies what cannot be done. Since the fall of Rome, there have been more centuries characterized by what is known as capital shortage than there have been of periods of sustained growth and general prosperity. It is not a coincidence that the outcry against usury has been most shrill during those difficult times.

    Today, usury is considered excessive interest, but that definition is relatively new in historical terms. Originally, usura was interest and its actual rate differed from place to place. The debate over it was intense. Excessive interest in many ancient societies was interest on interest, or usurae usararum, which added to the principal of an unpaid loan. In the ancient world and Middle Ages especially, this was anathema. The tribal tradition of the Hebrews prohibiting Jews from lending to each other at interest was cited by medieval churchmen as the major Old Testament source for proscribing all interest, not just simple interest. The great irony was that Jews were exempt from lending to gentiles and accepted as moneylenders by the church in the Middle Ages. That loophole allowed them to compete with the Lombards and Cahors who were allowed to lend at interest.

    In medieval Europe, these groups were the main moneylenders before the arrival of the Jews. Curiously, none was condemned for it and the Lombards were responsible for the development of the money markets in the fourteenth century. The Italian bankers in particular became financiers to monarchs and princes as far north as England. Their experiences with Edward III in particular were unpleasant, but their skills were highly sought after in countries where the treasuries were either low on cash or management skills. Despite the general ban on interest, the moneylenders were tolerated and even occasionally put the feet of monarchs to the fire when the interest bill was overdue. Jewish lenders usually were less fortunate. This apparent contradiction can be explained by a combination of tradition, religion, and law. The Lombards were the barbarian tribe that conquered Rome in the sixth century; the Cahors were the descendants of the Visigoths who settled in France. Neither group had any provisions against interest or usury in their laws because both came from societies that originally used barter or payment in kind rather than money. Natural law in the late Roman Empire assumed a commonality among civilized societies, but that did not include barbarians. Neither group had a tradition against usury; each continued to pursue its newly acquired money-lending skills without interruption. No loud objection was heard until the Lombards were conquered by Charlemagne in 800, but by that time their tradition was established.

    The barbarian invasions also relegated much of Roman law to the shadows of history until the general revival of learning in the twelfth century. When many books that had been missing for centuries reappeared, those of Aristotle became the main reference for many churchmen, including Thomas Aquinas. This complicated matters for moneylending because the Scholastics accepted Aristotle’s dictum that money was sterile, having no intrinsic qualities other than being used as a medium of exchange. It could not beget itself and therefore usury was not useful. Unknown (or ignored) was the discovery of Justinian’s Code in 1130. In it, the prohibition against anatocismus (Cicero’s term) and alterum tantum (doubling a debt by interest charges) could be found. Today those practices collectively are known as compound interest. Normal rates of interest were tolerated, but adding interest to outstanding principal was banned. But medieval church law would not even admit to ordinary interest despite the distinction between the two in Roman law.

    Compound interest would not become a math exercise until the Middle Ages when the Italian mathematician Fibonacci discussed compound interest questions and puzzles. Because of the usury prohibition, he carefully avoided discussions about loan values and instead focused on future value problems, an issue medieval philosophers were not acquainted with and did not discuss. He posed questions about the future value of a unit of currency and, most famously, how many rabbits would be the result of an original pair, assuming continuous rabbit compounding. But he avoided the usury issue, as did his equally famous countryman Luca Pacioli two centuries later when he discussed double entry bookkeeping for the first time. Fibonacci did, however, tackle the problem of debasing a currency, a politically correct topic in the thirteenth century for kings and princes.

    There is a great temptation to criticize various usury and interest ceilings as being inconsistent over the centuries. The medieval church adopted a ban on usury, similar to the one in the Muslim world, only to see it circumvented with great frequency between the twelfth and nineteenth centuries. Different commentators had sundry opinions on the subject, but all agreed that interest needed to be controlled. Even Adam Smith, considered the father of free market economic theory, favored a ceiling on interest. But as usury and interest approached the nineteenth century, it becomes more clear that there was a great deal of consistency in the way they were treated, given the differences in cultures and political motives of those opposed to them. The tendency to abuse one’s position as a lender was recognized by most commentators regardless of their political or moral position.

    The term beggar thy neighbor today is used to describe an international trade practice where one nation attempts to establish advantage over its trading partners through restrictive trade practices or policies. This derives from a mercantilist idea that owed its origins to an era when colonial powers exploited their far-flung colonies and ensured that they exported more than they imported. Before the mercantilist period, however, the term was associated more simply with borrowing and lending. The Shylocks of the world exploited the Antonios, seeking to extract their pound of flesh, when Christian principles demanded fairness and lenient lending policies. Equity and Christian charity suggested that lenders should treat borrowers as brothers, members of the same community. The idea was practiced only rarely. Shylock stood apart from that community; his religion and tradition were different; he was allowed to lend to non-Jews, a well-known, widely circulated biblical fact. Coincidentally Portia, who successfully defended Antonio against Shylock in Shakespeare’s court, was also the name of Brutus’s second wife, which was probably not a coincidence since Shakespeare was well acquainted with Roman history.

    The lending tradition became a nasty circle of recrimination and counter-recrimination that lasted for centuries. Lenders and early bankers, whether they were Jews, Lombards, Cahors, or the Templars, realized that their financial expertise and alien status in many European societies made them subjects of envy, derision, and ultimately retaliation from many hard pressed sovereigns. As a result, many of them charged compound interest to compensate for their business risk or disguised interest charges as hidden, discounted fees. The risks they faced were more than simple counterparty risk because they could be expelled from their homes, sent to the Inquisition, or expropriated. The fact that many well-known bankers in northern Europe prior to the Renaissance came from distant locales attests to the fact that foreigners were often sought as lenders precisely because borrowers could default on loans to them without much fear of reprisal.

    The history of usury usually has been divided into a general discussion surrounding borrowing and lending on the one hand and the legal treatment of usury by various societies on the other. Since the early years of the Roman monarchy, through the republic and ending with the empire, Rome always had what is known as statutory usury. Laws governing interest were embodied in the law, at first in the Twelve Tables and then later in Justinian’s Code and Digest. The latter incorporated the writings of many prominent rhetoricians and philosophers, so together they were an excellent compilation of the major ideas on usury in Rome for the previous centuries. These laws, different in scope and sophistication, actually specified the maximum rate of interest that lenders could charge borrowers. They did not ban lending rates but only sought a level of interest that was considered practical and viable. To borrow an idea from Adam Smith, the more prosperous and wealthy a society, the lower was its rate of interest.

    It has been suggested that the history of usury is nothing more than an exercise in intellectual history. Accordingly, usury is an idea with a long history, riddled with enigmas and inconsistencies, that exists mostly in the minds of economic historians. That is true but it ignores the subtext, which has proved to be one of the most powerful notions in all societies for three thousand years. As part of general natural law, it reflects societal notions of fairness and equity that have transcended ancient, medieval, and modern societies. The power of interest, and especially compound interest, cannot be understated. Usury and interest have been condemned together for centuries, although it is not always clear whether critics distinguished, or even understood, the differences between the two. Compound interest has commanded little discussion by itself until recently. John Maynard Keynes recognized the problems compound interest would cause for Germany in paying World War I reparations. Albert Einstein reputedly called it the eighth wonder of the world for its ability to produce future values far in excess of present value. The English clergyman Richard Price tried to use compound interest to retire the sizable British national debt in the eighteenth century. American lenders are now required to state the annual percentage rate they charge customers on unpaid balances, but the rates themselves have been left untouched by federal regulators. In the early 1980s, several large American banks went to great lengths and expense to establish credit card facilities in states with no functional usury laws in order to avoid potential prosecution for charging high interest rates, ratcheted even higher by daily or monthly compounding.

    There has been a clear distinction between misgivings about usury and the law of usury. The misgivings certainly have been more colorful. Dante relegated usurers to the inferno while numerous writers cited scripture to illustrate the pitfalls of lending money. In early nineteenth-century Ireland, the Reverend Jeremiah O’Callaghan refused the sacraments to a dying man until he recanted his alleged usury, an incident that eventually got the priest banished to the wilds of northern Vermont. When the Catholic Church finally reconsidered its ban on usury, it did so quietly through a letter by the pope to the Italian bishops in the eighteenth century, not through a papal encyclical as would have been expected. One hundred years later, the ban would politely be ignored. After centuries of condemnation, the lure of fixed income investment returns finally became too great to resist.

    Despite the colorful vignettes, it has always been easier to denounce the practice than actually pass a useful usury law. When the British government finally abolished its usury laws in the early nineteenth century, many of the arguments in the debate later surfaced in the United States. Banning usury was bad for business and therefore the usury laws should be abolished. No one could forcibly argue against the point, but no one could totally agree either given the abuses to which lenders often subjected borrowers. Advocates of maintaining a ban often cited the Old Testament and it became a major source of speech material for legislators in the nineteenth century. While much of it sounded like hell, fire, and brimstone, the laws that subsequently followed sounded very tame in comparison. Usury laws lived on in the United States for another one hundred years. The fact that a major credit crisis followed within a few decades did not seem to faze proponents of leverage and free market interest rates who apparently were not aware that the South Sea Bubble, the crash of 1929, and most of the American panics of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries all were caused by excessive borrowing and high leverage that spilled over into the equities markets.

    American usury laws, established during the colonial period, underwent a slow transformation. Since most of the meaningful laws were state rather than federal, they would change individually or in small groups rather than all be changed in one fell swoop. Pressure to change began before the Civil War when the economic debate shifted to competition from matters of justice or equity. The movement reached fruition in the late 1920s, and states began to raise their usury ceilings. This was another way of saying that they should be abolished. If lenders were allowed to charge higher rates, in the 30 percent range in many states, then loan sharks would be put out of business. This was particularly significant because loan sharks were a major source of consumption loans and a significant social problem because of the blatant usury they practiced. The sharks ran the gauntlet from unregistered lenders charging less than 100 percent interest to organized crime, which charged 1,000 percent or more. But the statewide movement to raise usury ceilings encountered several obstacles. The move toward higher ceilings was curtailed by the Great Depression and World War II. It also was a contributing factor to the crash of 1929 and the Depression, causing a slowdown in consumption because of the higher rates at a time when lower rates definitely were needed.

    The twentieth century in particular proved a watershed for interest. Most of the mysteries of compound interest have become more clearly understandable since Isaac Newton demonstrated the first interest rate calculation, showing a formula for effective compound rates in the early eighteenth century. Credit card companies and other consumer lenders then discovered continuous interest, the most frequent method of compounding a nominal rate. While the calculations are now understood by a larger segment of the population than ever before, the basic facts about compound interest that distressed previous generations remain the same. Loans made for consumption quickly become onerous when interest is added to the existing principal amount, the original and timeless practice of accumulating interest. For that reason, many European societies enacted sumptuary laws for over a thousand years. People were willing to borrow in order to purchase items that allowed them to aspire above their station in life, a practice those in power deemed inimical to the common good, so consumption was often banned. Laws prohibiting the wearing of fur collars or fancy ribbons may seem quaint and repressive today, but by banning them many governments were attempting to dissuade those in the lower classes from consuming by borrowing. Unlike contemporary societies, they were intent upon removing the means of becoming overextended through loans, not simply extending lending facilities to as many as possible and then letting the market decide who was successful and who was not. The users of credit were targeted, not the producers. The usury laws already on the books were not working well enough to protect the populace at large, according to this reasoning.

    Despite the long and arduous opinions about interest, borrowing, and usury over the years, interest has made most of modern life manageable for vast portions of the populace in the developed world, a statement that could not have been made three hundred years ago. Early, speculative instruments called tontines were first proposed in the seventeenth century and annuities and life insurance resulted, having developed along with the government bond markets. Long-term investment planning became possible for the first time on a large scale. Real property became more scarce as European populations grew larger, so passing financial assets from generation to generation and ensuring income in later years became crucial to overall economic growth. By the end of the Napoleonic Wars, it was possible to live comfortably in England without having wealth tied to land, as had been the case for centuries. Fixed income investments and life insurance provided the means to living better than one’s ancestors.

    The number of financial debacles and panics also increased as a result, many of them caused by excessive leverage and inflated asset prices. Recent financial crises have demonstrated that the credit markets are central to understanding the asset markets. Despite the techniques and ingenuity of modern finance, when centuries-old maxims concerning debt, repayment, and the dangers of excessive consumption are violated, the same happens in the twenty-first century as did in the first: borrowers are impoverished and lenders become reluctant to make other types of productive loans that contribute to economic growth.

    Brutus found it lucrative to become a lender in Cyprus because Roman law allowed higher interest rates in lending in the provinces than in Rome itself. When Citibank moved its credit card operations out of New York in the early 1980s to avoid the local usury laws, it sought the same sort of flexibility from a state that would tolerate its activities in return for creating local jobs. This practice recently became known as regulatory arbitrage: the process of dumping one regulator in favor of another that is more lenient and accommodating. The catchy phrase obscures the fact that it is the lending activities that should be under scrutiny. Less known about Brutus is that his agent locked the recalcitrant borrowers in a closed room and denied them food and drink until several of them died of hunger. Today, hard-put borrowers are extended more credit to tide them over until they face personal bankruptcy, an idea that has only been in existence since the nineteenth century. Before that, bankruptcy meant prison for the defaulted borrower and even his entire family.

    A notable dissent to Western finance has emerged from the Islamic world within the last thirty-five years. Building on the general ban on interest found in its holy writings, Islamic law (sharia) has joined forces with modern structured finance to develop what has become known as Islamic finance: the design and implementation of financial instruments that are compliant with the Koran and fatwas of Islamic scholars. All financial instruments and investments must comply with a strict code of ethical behavior that assiduously avoids interest or even the hint of it. This new market runs parallel to the development of microlending, a worldwide movement to extend working capital and very small business loans to the poor that began in Bangladesh. In its original form, microlending also embodied Islamic principles although at the opposite end of the financial and social spectrum from the model oriented on the City of London. No one ever considered lending to the poor on a massive scale before. The closest attempt was in the city-states of northern Italy in the late Middle Ages through institutions called montes. The only surviving monte is today one of Italy’s larger banks. Twenty years after being founded it almost collapsed after making a loan outside its original lending model. The loan made to Christopher Columbus was written off as unpaid, making it the most memorable loan default in history.

    Charging interest, usury, and excessive leverage are common today, but in the twentieth century new financial techniques were developed that helped produce great prosperity while posing enormous risks at the same time. When securitization became popular in the mid-1970s, it led to a revolution in lending practices that helped democratize credit. Being able to pool loans and get them off a balance sheet allowed lenders to relax banking standards that had been in place for generations. Looser standards meant that more people were able to obtain mortgages than in the past, leading to the inevitable housing bubble that burst in 2007 and 2008. The idea of lending became decoupled from the responsibility of behaving as a prudent lender. Loans were understood as fungible and marketable. Extending credit and then off-loading it to investors in a securitized bond was easier than simply saying no to a poorly rated borrower in the first place.

    The same technique also led to the widespread use of credit cards, distributed without much regard for the ability to repay, which naturally suited the card lenders. Applying diversification principles normally associated with securities investing, credit card lenders were able to justify extending credit to marginal borrowers and even the poor on the assumption that the higher rates charged to those borrowers would enhance the returns on the pools of loans they sold through securitization. Like other lenders employing techniques relying on heavy leverage, their defense ultimately was that only a cataclysmic event would undo their financial structuring, something that had only a 1 percent chance of happening in any event. Forgotten was the point that excessive reliance on these techniques increased those chances exponentially.

    Looking back on the history of interest and usury, it is tempting to think that recent lenders and financial engineers either forgot or never knew the tradition preceding them and were destined to make the same mistakes repeatedly. When Mexico required a massive financial restructuring in the late 1980s, however, it was accomplished using a financial practice that originated under the Tudors four hundred years before. The term defeasance was not even found in the dictionaries when it was used again recently. Cicero’s term for compound interest (anatocismus) disappeared from English usage in the nineteenth century, although it still survives in other places that use elements of Roman law. As debt crises become more common, the debate about interest and usury will continue because the predatory element in lending still exists. The more onerous term debt has been used less in marketing financial products, suggesting that credit was a reward for the borrower rather than a caveat. The packaging is different, but the results are much the same when limits are exceeded.

    No one today will agree with the Scholastics that interest is inherently unjust and should be banned, except those in the Islamic world. Without credit facilities, modern capitalism would not have developed. But the temptations that finance presents have always been present, regardless of time and place. Charging high rates of interest was easier than productive work, as generations of Italian bankers and English merchants, including Shakespeare’s father, discovered. The arch opponents of usury recognized the fact. In the sixteenth century, Thomas Wilson, a prominent writer and opponent of usury in Tudor England, tried to affect the outcome of a debate in Parliament about usury ceilings. He admitted, I have been a doer in this world these 30 winters, and as fresh an occupier as another, and yet never found I better or more assured gain than by putting out my money for gain, the same being always the best and easiest trade in the world.

    The most recent twist on lending and interest rates came in the years preceding the credit market crisis of 2007. For generations, borrowing for consumption had been strictly separated from borrowing for residential real estate or for productive purposes. New financial developments obscured the differences when the home equity loan was introduced. This second mortgage allowed homeowners to unlock the equity in their homes, to borrow a catchphrase from the real estate industry, and use the cash in any way they saw fit. Often, the money was used for consumption because the interest rates were low when compared to credit card interest. When the mortgage crisis began, home values declined and consumer spending dropped sharply, leading to a severe drop in real estate assets values and forcing many borrowers into foreclosure and personal bankruptcy.

    In many ways, the home equity loan, a simple financial product, helped underscore the developments that had been made in lending. It also helped underscore the weaknesses in lending procedures that ignored consumer debt in favor of real estate. Once the two became intertwined, the debt revolution that began eighty years before turned full circle. Homeowners were increasing consumption to almost 80 percent of the gross domestic product from the 67 percent that had been in place since the 1920s. Once consumers used their homes as collateral for their spending habits, they began engaging in a form of cannibal consumption, devouring what equity they held in their homes in favor of increased spending. The results demonstrated that axioms about borrowing in excess of the ability to repay were not simply old fashioned rules that could be violated willy-nilly.

    Usury prohibitions were part of the natural law tradition in Europe until the Enlightenment, when they were assumed to have faded from view because of the writings of Hugo Grotius and other jurists who demonstrated the finality of reason over moral sanctions and the vestiges of canon law. That judgment was premature because the usury laws persisted for several more centuries and still can be found in discussions of interest and unfair lending practices. Theories about free markets and competition have relegated them to a backseat in public policy positions, but the idea of usury still is alive and well. Discussions about limiting maximum rates of interest are still discussed. The notion proves as powerful as ever despite attempts to ignore it. Excessive interest still is a thorny problem. Paraphrasing Justice Potter Stewart, usury can be difficult to define, but one usually knows it when one sees it.

    Chapter 1

    Saints and Sinners

    God, nature, reason, all scripture, all law, all authors, all doctors, yea all councils are against usury. Philosophers, Greeks, Latins, Lawyers, Divines, Catholics, Heretics, all tongues, all nations, have thought usury as bad as a thief.

    —Roger Fenton, 1612

    Collecting interest traditionally was considered the world’s second oldest profession until the Industrial Revolution. It was lumped together with other socially unacceptable practices as inimical to the common good and a perversion of the idea that man should help his fellow man. Along with prostitution, arson, and murder, it was considered an execrable crime under religious law, although it was more gingerly tolerated in the secular world. In the Middle Ages, usurers were often relegated to the seedier sections of towns, segregated much as prostitutes were in red light districts. Theory and practice concerning interest often diverged widely, but generally the more religious the society, the stronger the prohibition against it.

    Originally, usury and interest were considered the same practice and were not differentiated in a systematic way. Biblical references were to usury alone, meaning interest, but later distinctions were made between interest and excessive interest. As will be seen, however, usury has always been considered excessive interest, whatever the basic rate of interest may have been. Until the Enlightenment, the two terms were interchangeable, with usury being the operative—and pejorative—term. As the use of Latin declined in Western Europe, the term interest evolved in the vernacular but was never able to shake its medieval connotation. For almost a thousand years it was understood to be something not conducive to economic well-being.

    Interest became known by its Latin name, usury, or usura, meaning to charge a high or exorbitant rate of interest. In the Middle Ages, the term became usuria, from which the modern spelling derives. This negative connotation of the practice of usury is the one that has survived the ages because charging interest at a reasonable rate has always been considered standard business practice despite church prohibitions against it in the medieval world. But as in all commercial practice, the question of how much interest was considered fair versus usurious was never settled in a satisfactory sense because of the fragmented nature of ancient societies, characterized by different religious traditions. The absence of a uniform marketplace for credit also meant that interest rates varied widely, and wildly, from place to place.

    Mixed with the straightforward definitions of interest and usury were ideas of fairness or justice, which gave moneylending strong political connotations as well. Ordinary interest was as common as it is today, although when economies began using money as a medium of exchange the debate quickly began over what was normal and what was excessive. Calculating it was difficult under barter economies because interest was usually paid in kind. If a merchant lent a farmer a sack of seed, what was considered normal interest? How much had to be paid back and in what commodity? Was the crop harvested from the seed more or less valuable than the seed? These questions were solved on the local level. In general, interest charges on non-monetary items were not considered usury in the strict sense of the word. But when money became more widely used, ethics entered the discussion. Usury was any amount paid on money loans above the principal amount originally lent. Since moneylending was considered the product of idleness, high rates were frowned upon. Again, the same problem persisted. What was considered high?

    In its simplest form, interest charged on a loan for consumption purposes was considered unjust, presumably because the person borrowing the money did not have the means to live without borrowing. Any usury in this case was considered exploitative. This notion is the oldest and can be found in the Old Testament. Most ancient and medieval commentators and writers used Deuteronomy as their main source for condemnations of usury. It stated, Thou shalt not lend upon usury to thy brother; usury of money, usury of victuals, usury of anything that is lent upon usury (23:19). Continuing, it stated, Unto a stranger thou mayest lend upon usury; but unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon usury, that the Lord thy God may bless thee in all that thou settest thine hand to in the land whither thou goest to possess it (23:20). Brother was not meant to be a general term, however; it was much more specific. A brother was a member of one’s own tribe. In other words, Jews could lend to gentiles and collect usury but could not do the same to fellow Jews. This has been referred to as the Deuteronomic double standard.¹

    Other biblical references stated the same principle. Leviticus 25:36 said, Take thou no usury of him, or increase: but fear thy God; that thy brother may live with thee. But the passage in Deuteronomy became the standard that would be cited for generations as the biblical prohibition of usury of any kind. The standard was indeed a double standard only because there was evidence that Jews did in fact lend to other Jews. Josephus claimed that a lender should be satisfied with the gratitude of a needy borrower rather than expect usury in return for a loan. Early loan contracts demonstrate that, admonitions aside, lending at usury occurred despite the warnings of the prophets. Interest was set at 12 percent among the Hebrews. A similar rate structure was found in many ancient cultures. When Nehemiah was the provincial governor of Judea between 444 and 432 B.C., he declared the 12 percent rate to be used to settle disputes, a practice that would endure for over two thousand years.²

    A similar admonition can be found in Psalms. He that putteth not out his money to usury, nor taketh reward against the innocent. He that doeth these things shall never be moved (25:5). These statements, especially the one concerning lending to members of one’s own tribe, were perhaps the earliest foundation of a cottage industry that would be known throughout the ancient and medieval worlds. In order to conform to Deuteronomy, Jews could only lend to gentiles and a tradition began that survived for centuries. They became associated with lending and suffered both the fruits and the consequences of their activity. As they later discovered, rulers in Europe often required their services desperately but often cited church law forbidding usury when it was time to repay. Citing religion was a powerful reason for not repaying a loan since secular law traditionally did not condemn usury.

    A distinction between usury and interest was made very early. Generally, loans were made to someone in distress, a member of one’s own clan in need. If interest was charged at all, it had to be minimal, simply in order to cover the costs of the lending in today’s language. What the minimum rate of interest should have been was almost never stated, however. Usury entered when the lender was thought to be trying to take advantage of the borrower’s situation, forcing him to ruin or some other compromising position. Thus, usury was equated with conduct unbecoming a member of one’s own tribe or clan and was roundly condemned. The punishments could vary but ostracism and banishment were common. In the ancient and medieval worlds, they were applied to lenders and borrowers alike. Punishments for borrowers reneging on debts were also harsh, if they could be proved to have done harm to the lenders. Lenders carried the onus of having to prove that injury had been incurred and that they were not practicing excessive interest.

    A major problem in discussing interest and usury, especially in the period before the Roman Empire, was determining exactly how interest was calculated. Reading present practice backward suggests that the concept and calculations of interest rates have not been constant and have indeed changed over time. Some of the extant material strongly suggests that interest was calculated on a monthly, and simple, basis. The annual rate, or the total interest bill, was simply the amount charged per month times the number of months the loan was extended. Loans (mutuum in Latin) that appeared to have high rates attached to them were medium-term loans for periods longer than a year. The exact repayment terms were not standard due to the absence of an organized banking system in the ancient world and varied from lender to lender. In contemporary language, the sources for loans were private, meaning that funds came from wealthy individuals and merchants.

    In Roman law, the code known as the Twelve Tables (Duodicem Tabularum) was the most noteworthy attempt to codify usury for both patricians and plebeians. Patricians were the usual lenders to plebeians, who often objected vehemently to the rates charged. Roman history was replete with attempts to ban or control lending rates. Drawn by a council known as the Decemviri in 450 B.C., the law stated, No person shall practice usury at a rate of more than one twelfths.³ This meant that the legal rate of interest was set at 8.33 percent per annum, conforming to the Roman calendar of twelve months established by King Numa in 695 B.C. It has also been understood as a rate of 1 percent per month, as Montesquieu later interpreted it in the eighteenth century. But that may be overstating the case slightly since most loans were meant to be for one month on average. The rate of one-twelfth was derived from agriculture. It represented one ounce in a pound of crop, with payment due on the first of each month. Interest was stated on an annual basis, with no compounding.⁴ If it was compounded, it was called anatocismus anniversarius (annual compounding). A subsequent change raised the lending rate to 12 percent (usurae centesimae) in the later years of the republic and first years of the empire and it remained the same for about a century before being revised several times, finally being reaffirmed by Constantine in the fourth century A.D. But while the rate of interest was relatively low, the penalties for not repaying a loan remained harsh. The code continued: When debt has been acknowledged, or judgment about the matter had been pronounced in court, thirty days must be the legitimate time of grace. After that, then arrest of debtor may be made by laying on hands. Bring him into court. If he does not satisfy the judgment, or no one in court offers himself as surety on his behalf, the creditor may take the defaulter with him. He may bind him either in stocks or in chains; he may bind him with weight not less than fifteen pounds or with more if he shall so desire.⁵ Other interpretations of the law suggested that creditors could have insolvent debtors tied and then carved into pieces to satisfy the lenders. Other accounts had creditors selling debtors’ children into slavery.

    Although lending rates were set and remedies provided for violations, the laws were not universally followed by any means. Cicero, while provincial governor of Cilicia, related that Marcus Junius Brutus did a tidy moneylending business in Cyprus, lending at 48 percent rather than the 12 percent official rate, using an intermediary to hide his identity from the Roman Senate. Roman law forbade lending money in the provinces at high rates, but the law was harder to enforce than it was at home. Even at home, disputes over usury were not settled amicably. The historian Appian recalled a case in Rome in 89 B.C. where a dispute between debtors and their creditors was taken to a praetor (magistrate). The debtors claimed that an old law, preceding the Twelve Tables, forbid taking usury of any sort and they refused to pay their creditors. Unable to reach an amicable agreement, the praetor allowed the parties to pursue the case in court. The lenders became exasperated at the thought that they could lose due to an older law and killed the praetor in the Roman Forum. The Senate offered a reward for the identity of the killers, to no avail.

    Simple interest presented social and moral problems, but compound interest was roundly condemned. Usura was simple interest, but usurae usurarum (usury on usury) was compound interest. In Roman law it was also known as anatocismus, a term Cicero introduced into Latin from the Greek (meaning interest again) around 51 B.C., and it found its way into legal usage and judicial practice before being officially banned several centuries later under Justinian. But simply being interest on interest was not enough to get it banned; the consequences were unpalatable. Anatocismus created additional interest that was added to the principal of a loan. Therefore, the addition of the extra interest put the borrower more deeply in debt than had been the case before compounding.

    Anatocismus was the general word used for compound interest. Its deleterious effect was known as alterum tantum, or twice as much. Interest was considered excessive when the rate applied doubled the principal amount to be repaid at the end of the loan term. This was the most precise term used to denote a rate beyond which practical everyday usury should not venture, despite the official 12 percent rate. If a borrower was charged at the official 12 percent rate and he paid no interest monthly as usually stipulated, the loan amount would double in six years. If 48 percent was charged, the amount would double in one and a half years under the same conditions. Adding unpaid interest to principal was not unique to the Romans; it was also found in ancient Hindu society. The general assumption is that alterum tantum and anatocismus were both generally disregarded by the time of Ulpian in the third century and only Justinian’s Code made them legally operative again.

    The two terms demonstrate that the Romans developed an early range of lending rates, similar to those that would be used centuries later. Twelve percent was the official rate below which no one would lend while the upper end of the band was capped by alterum tantum, literally the rate that would double the principal amount. While the upper limit was high, it nevertheless attempted to define a usurious rate that clearly would prove disastrous for the borrower. It also demonstrated that the official rate was routinely violated. If understood in this manner, it also gives some insight into the origin of the well-known mathematical rule called the Rule of 72, which clearly shows how many years it will take to double an amount. All a borrower or lender needed to do was to divide 72 by the interest rate charged. The answer was the number of years necessary to double the amount of money involved.

    If that amount occurred within a brief time, from one to two years, it would clearly be in violation of the spirit of lending. But even under anatocismus it was not considered improper for the lender to take the additional interest received from a borrower and lend it to another; the prohibition extended only to adding it to the original borrower’s principal. Using compound interest meant that a borrower could owe more interest than principal on a loan through compounding if the rate was high enough and the repayment period long and this was why anatocismus was frowned upon and eventually banned. The ban did not, however, do away with the practice. Compound interest, especially semi-annual compound interest, clearly existed and was first mathematically implied in the work of Fibonacci in the early thirteenth century, but the actual calculations were not clear.

    Regardless of how interest was calculated, the fact that it was always used in business transactions runs somewhat counter to the general religious prohibitions. But a clear distinction had to be made between interest charged on money loans and other forms of payment in kind. Money interest was usually considered the most odious. It was the result of idleness on the part of the lender and desperation on the part of the borrower. A moneylender lent a sum to a borrower and demanded to be paid in money or in kind, quite often the latter. Regardless, usury was considered a wasteful practice according to most ancient and medieval writers. No value was created and nothing useful accomplished except to enrich the lender. The notion was characteristic of a hand-to-mouth economy where farmers and city-dwellers existed on a day-to-day basis with little savings or accumulated working capital. The idea remained static while commerce developed over the centuries, slowly demanding larger and larger amounts of capital to be invested in business enterprises.

    Other than biblical and Roman sources, Aristotle was considered the philosophic authority on interest, especially among ancient and medieval churchmen. Plato mentioned usury rarely, stating that, No money is … to be lent on interest. The law will not protect a man in recovering either interest or principal.⁹ But there is a sizable time gap because Aristotle’s writings were lost in Europe after the fall of Rome and only were reintroduced by Arab scholars in the eleventh century. After the reintroduction, Aristotelian thought became widely used by the Scholastic philosophers in the thirteenth century, the most notable being Thomas Aquinas, who, along with other medieval writers and canonists, considered Aristotle to be the Philosopher. Aristotle explored usury in a different vein. Rather than expressing his dislike of the practice in tribal or commandment form as the Old Testament sources did, he approached it philosophically. Usury was considered a practice that was inequitable to the borrower because it had the ability to beggar him. Usury was the most unnatural form of acquisition: the art of the petty usurer is hated most, and with most reason; it makes a profit from currency itself, instead of making it from the process which currency was meant to serve.¹⁰ To Aristotle, money was barren and intended only to be a medium of exchange, not something that could be deployed to earn its own rate of return. If it were used to facilitate exchange of goods and services, its use was valid. If it were lent to earn usury, it was unjust and barren and the lender was nothing more than a thief. When a loan was made, no usury was to be expected. This is not to say that money was not lent at interest in ancient Athens but only suggests that the opinion makers of the day, whose influence would extend for centuries, considered it a banal practice that would impoverish the borrower while enriching the lender.

    There was also a moral and socioeconomic framework that accompanied usury laws in many ancient societies, including Greece and Rome. These were the sumptuary (consumption) laws, aimed at controlling the consumption of the lower classes who wanted to emulate the nobles or ruling class. The laws stipulated the amount of certain luxury items an individual could own. The first Roman sumptuary law was the Lex Oppia, enacted in 215 B.C. It dictated, among other things, the amount of ornamental gold a woman could own as well as the materials that could be used in dressing gowns and the like. The traditional view of sumptuary laws was that they were used to keep the non-noble classes from assuming ideas above their station. Only noblemen could dress like noblemen; tradesmen or the masses were prohibited from doing so. But consumption of fine goods also had a great deal to do with borrowing money since many of those seeking to emulate rich public figures often needed to borrow in order to do so. While the sumptuary laws were no more effective than usury laws in many cases, they did demonstrate that there was a concern about indebtedness for consumption purposes that many feared would divert valuable resources from productive purposes, especially during times of financial crisis. The Lex Oppia was passed during the Second Punic War with Carthage, although it was relaxed after the eventual Roman victory. As the usury laws, the sumptuary laws often faded from view only to reappear at a later date.

    Origins in Canon Law

    Since Aristotle was not translated into Latin until the thirteenth century, it is difficult to say how

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1