Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

From $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook: Micro, Macro, and International Economics
Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook: Micro, Macro, and International Economics
Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook: Micro, Macro, and International Economics
Ebook242 pages2 hours

Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook: Micro, Macro, and International Economics

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars

()

Read preview

About this ebook

The economics background investors need to interpret global economic news distilled to the essential elements: A tool of choice for investment decision-makers.  

Written by a distinguished academics and practitioners selected and guided by CFA Institute, the world’s largest association of finance professionals, Economics for Investment Decision Makers is unique in presenting microeconomics and macroeconomics with relevance to investors and investment analysts constantly in mind.   The selection of fundamental topics is comprehensive, while coverage of topics such as international trade, foreign exchange markets, and currency exchange rate forecasting reflects global perspectives of pressing investor importance. 

  • Concise, plain-English introduction useful to investors and investment analysts
  • Relevant to security analysis, industry analysis, country analysis, portfolio management, and capital market strategy
  • Understand economic news and what it means
  • All concepts defined and simply explained, no prior background in economics assumed
  • Abundant examples and illustrations
  • Global markets perspective
LanguageEnglish
PublisherWiley
Release dateMar 5, 2013
ISBN9781118416334
Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook: Micro, Macro, and International Economics

Read more from Christopher D. Piros

Related to Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook

Titles in the series (15)

View More

Related ebooks

Finance & Money Management For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook

Rating: 0 out of 5 stars
0 ratings

0 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    Economics for Investment Decision Makers Workbook - Christopher D. Piros

    CHAPTER 1

    DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS: INTRODUCTION

    LEARNING OUTCOMES

    After completing this chapter, you will be able to do the following:

    Distinguish among types of markets.

    Explain the principles of demand and supply.

    Describe causes of shifts in and movements along demand and supply curves.

    Describe the process of aggregating demand and supply curves, the concept of equilibrium, and mechanisms by which markets achieve equilibrium.

    Distinguish between stable and unstable equilibria and identify instances of such equilibria.

    Calculate and interpret individual and aggregate demand and inverse demand and supply functions, and interpret individual and aggregate demand and supply curves.

    Calculate and interpret the amount of excess demand or excess supply associated with a nonequilibrium price.

    Describe the types of auctions and calculate the winning price(s) of an auction.

    Calculate and interpret consumer surplus, producer surplus, and total surplus.

    Analyze the effects of government regulation and intervention on demand and supply.

    Forecast the effect of the introduction and the removal of a market interference (e.g., a price floor or ceiling) on price and quantity.

    Calculate and interpret price, income, and cross-price elasticities of demand, and describe factors that affect each measure.

    SUMMARY OVERVIEW

    The basic model of markets is the demand and supply model. The demand function represents buyers’ behavior and can be depicted (in its inverse demand form) as a negatively sloped demand curve. The supply function represents sellers’ behavior and can be depicted (in its inverse supply form) as a positively sloped supply curve. The interaction of buyers and sellers in a market results in equilibrium. Equilibrium exists when the highest price willingly paid by buyers is just equal to the lowest price willingly accepted by sellers.

    Goods markets are the interactions of consumers as buyers and firms as sellers of goods and services produced by firms and bought by households. Factor markets are the interactions of firms as buyers and households as sellers of land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurial risk-taking ability. Capital markets are used by firms to sell debt or equity to raise long-term capital to finance the production of goods and services.

    Demand and supply curves are drawn on the assumption that everything except the price of the good itself is held constant (an assumption known as ceteris paribus or holding all other things constant). When something other than price changes, the demand curve or the supply curve will shift relative to the other curve. This shift is referred to as a change in demand or supply, as opposed to quantity demanded or quantity supplied. A new equilibrium generally will be obtained at a different price and a different quantity than before. The market mechanism is the ability of prices to adjust to eliminate any excess demand or supply resulting from a shift in one or the other curve.

    If, at a given price, the quantity demanded exceeds the quantity supplied, there is excess demand and the price will rise. If, at a given price, the quantity supplied exceeds the quantity demanded, there is excess supply and the price will fall.

    Sometimes auctions are used to seek equilibrium prices. Common value auctions sell items that have the same value to all bidders, but bidders can only estimate that value before the auction is completed. Overly optimistic bidders overestimate the true value and end up paying a price greater than that value. This result is known as the winner’s curse. Private value auctions sell items that (generally) have a unique subjective value for each bidder. Ascending price auctions use an auctioneer to call out ever-increasing prices until the last, highest bidder ultimately pays his or her bid price and buys the item. Descending price, or Dutch, auctions begin at a very high price and then reduce that price until one bidder is willing to buy at that price. Second price sealed-bid auctions are sometimes used to induce bidders to reveal their true reservation prices in private value auctions. Treasury notes and some other financial instruments are sold using a form of Dutch auction (called a single price auction) in which competitive and noncompetitive bids are arrayed in descending price (increasing yield) order. The winning bidders all pay the same price, but marginal bidders might not be able to fill their entire order at the market-clearing price.

    Markets that work freely can optimize society’s welfare, as measured by consumer surplus and producer surplus. Consumer surplus is the difference between the total value to buyers and the total expenditure necessary to purchase a given amount. Producer surplus is the difference between the total revenue received by sellers from selling a given amount and the total variable cost of production of that amount. When equilibrium price is reached, total surplus is maximized.

    Sometimes, government policies interfere with the free working of markets. Examples include price ceilings, price floors, and specific taxes. Whenever the imposition of such a policy alters the free market equilibrium quantity (the quantity that maximizes total surplus), there is a redistribution of surplus between buyers and sellers; but there is also a reduction of total surplus, called deadweight loss. Other influences can result in an imbalance between demand and supply. Search costs are impediments in the ability of willing buyers and willing sellers to meet in a transaction. Brokers can add value if they reduce search costs and match buyers and sellers. In general, anything that improves information about the willingness of buyers and sellers to engage will reduce search costs and add value.

    Economists use a quantitative measure of sensitivity called elasticity. In general, elasticity is the ratio of the percentage change in the dependent variable to the percentage change in the independent variable of interest. Important specific elasticities include own-price elasticity of demand, income elasticity of demand, and cross-price elasticity of demand.

    Based on algebraic sign and magnitude of the various elasticities, goods can be classified into groups. If own-price elasticity of demand is less than 1 in absolute value, demand is called inelastic; it is called elastic if own-price elasticity of demand is greater than 1 in absolute value. Goods with positive income elasticity of demand are called normal goods, and those with negative income elasticity of demand are called inferior goods. Two goods with negative cross-price elasticity of demand—a drop in the price of one good causes an increase in demand for the other good—are called complements. Goods with positive cross-price elasticity of demand—a drop in the price of one good causes a decrease in demand for the other—are called substitutes.

    The relationship among own-price elasticity of demand, changes in price, and changes in total expenditure is as follows: If demand is elastic, a reduction in price results in an increase in total expenditure; if demand is inelastic, a reduction in price results in a decrease in total expenditure; if demand is unitary elastic, a change in price leaves total expenditure unchanged.

    PRACTICE PROBLEMS

    ¹

    1. Which of the following markets is most accurately characterized as a goods market? The market for:

    A. coats.

    B. sales clerks.

    C. cotton farmland.

    2. The observation As a price of a good falls, buyers buy more of it is best known as:

    A. consumer surplus.

    B. the law of demand.

    C. the market mechanism.

    3. Two-dimensional demand and supply curves are drawn under which of the following assumptions?

    A. Own price is held constant.

    B. All variables but quantity are held constant.

    C. All variables but own price and quantity are held constant.

    4. The slope of a supply curve is most often:

    A. zero.

    B. positive.

    C. negative.

    5. Assume the following equation:

    where is the quantity of good X supplied, Px is the price of good X, and W is the wage rate paid to laborers. If the wage rate is 11, the vertical intercept on a graph depicting the supply curve is closest to:

    A. −26.

    B. −4.

    C. 52.

    6. Movement along the demand curve for good X occurs due to a change in:

    A. income.

    B. the price of good X.

    C. the price of a substitute for good X.

    The following information relates to Questions 7 through 9.

    A producer’s supply function is given by the equation:

    where is the quantity of steel supplied by the market, Ps is the per-unit price of steel, and Pa is the per-unit price of aluminum.

    7. If the price of aluminum rises, what happens to the steel producer’s supply curve? The supply curve:

    A. shifts to the left.

    B. shifts to the right.

    C. remains unchanged.

    8. If the unit price of aluminum is 10, the slope of the supply curve is closest to:

    A. 0.04.

    B. 1.30.

    C. 26.00.

    9. Assume the supply side of the market consists of exactly five identical sellers. If the unit price of aluminum is 20, which equation is closest to the expression for the market inverse supply function?

    A.

    B.

    C.

    10. Which of the following statements about market equilibrium is most accurate?

    A. The difference between quantity demanded and quantity supplied is zero.

    B. The demand curve is negatively sloped and the supply curve is positively sloped.

    C. For any given pair of market demand and supply curves, only one equilibrium point can exist.

    11. Which of the following statements best characterizes the market mechanism for attaining equilibrium?

    A. Excess supply causes prices to fall.

    B. Excess demand causes prices to fall.

    C. The demand and supply curves shift to reach equilibrium.

    12. An auction in which the auctioneer starts at a high price and then lowers the price in increments until there is a willing buyer is best called a:

    A. Dutch auction.

    B. Vickery auction.

    C. private value auction.

    13. Which statement is most likely to be true in a single price U.S. Treasury bill auction?

    A. Only some noncompetitive bids would be filled.

    B. Bidders at the highest winning yield may get only a portion of their orders filled.

    C. All bidders at a yield higher than the winning bid would get their entire orders filled.

    14. The winner’s curse in common value auctions is best described as the winning bidder paying:

    A. more than the value of the asset.

    B. a price not equal to one’s own bid.

    C. more than intended prior to bidding.

    15. A wireless phone manufacturer introduced a next-generation phone that received a high level of positive publicity. Despite running several high-speed production assembly lines, the manufacturer is still falling short in meeting demand for the phone nine months after introduction. Which of the following statements is the most plausible explanation for the demand/supply imbalance?

    A. The phone price is low relative to the equilibrium price.

    B. Competitors introduced next-generation phones at a similar price.

    C. Consumer incomes grew faster than the manufacturer anticipated.

    16. A per-unit tax on items sold that is paid by the seller will most likely result in the:

    A. supply curve shifting vertically upward.

    B. demand curve shifting vertically upward.

    C. demand curve shifting vertically downward.

    17. Which of the following most accurately and completely describes a deadweight loss?

    A. A transfer of surplus from one party to another

    B. A reduction in either the buyer’s or the seller’s surplus

    C. A reduction in total surplus resulting from market interference

    18. If an excise tax is paid by the buyer instead of the seller, which of the following statements is most likely to be true?

    A. The price paid will be higher than if the seller had paid the tax.

    B. The price received will be lower than if the seller had paid the tax.

    C. The price received will be the same as if the seller had paid the tax.

    19. A quota on an imported good below the market-clearing quantity will most likely lead to which of the following effects?

    A. The supply curve shifts

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1