Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium modeling (abbreviated DSGE or sometimes SDGE or DGE) is a branch of applied general equilibrium theory that is influential in contemporary macroeconomics. The DSGE methodology attempts to explain aggregate economic phenomena, such as economic growth, business cycles, and the effects of monetary and fiscal policy, on the basis of macroeconomic models derived from microeconomic principles. One of the main reasons macroeconomists seek to build microfounded models is that, unlike more traditional macroeconometric forecasting models, microfounded models should not, in principle, be vulnerable to the Lucas critique. Furthermore, since the microfoundations are based on the preferences of the decision-makers in the model, DSGE models feature a natural benchmark for evaluating the welfare effects of policy changes (for discussion of both points, see Woodford, 2003, pp. 11–12 and Tovar, 2008, pp. 15–16).
Contents |
Like other general equilibrium models, DSGE models aim to describe the behavior of the economy as a whole by analyzing the interaction of many microeconomic decisions. The decisions considered in most DSGE models correspond to some of the main quantities studied in macroeconomics, such as consumption, saving, investment, and labor supply and labor demand. The decision-makers in the model, often called 'agents', may include households, business firms, and possibly others, such as governments or central banks.
Furthermore, as their name indicates, DSGE models are dynamic, studying how the economy evolves over time. They are also stochastic, taking into account the fact that the economy is affected by random shocks such as technological change, fluctuations in the price of oil, or changes in macroeconomic policy-making. This contrasts with the static models studied in Walrasian general equilibrium theory, applied general equilibrium models and some computable general equilibrium models.
For a coherent description of the macroeconomy, DSGE models must spell out the following economic 'ingredients'.
Traditional macroeconometric forecasting models used by central banks in the 1970s, and even today, estimated the dynamic correlations between prices and quantities in different sectors of the economy, and often included thousands of variables. Since DSGE models start from microeconomic principles of constrained decision-making, instead of just taking as given observed correlations, they are technically more difficult to solve and analyze. Therefore they usually abstract from so many sectoral details, and include far fewer variables: just a few variables in theoretical DSGE papers, or on the order of a hundred variables in the experimental DSGE forecasting models now being constructed by central banks. What DSGE models give up in sectoral detail, they attempt to make up in logical consistency.
By specifying preferences (what the agents want), technology (what the agents can produce), and institutions (the way they interact), it is possible (in principle, though challenging in practice) to solve the DSGE model to predict what is actually produced, traded, and consumed, and how these variables evolve over time in response to various shocks. In principle, it is also possible to make predictions about the effects of changing the institutional framework.
In contrast, as Robert Lucas pointed out, such a prediction is unlikely to be valid in traditional macroeconometric forecasting models, since those models are based on observed past correlations between macroeconomic variables. These correlations can be expected to change when new policies are introduced, invalidating predictions based on past observations.
Given the difficulty of constructing accurate DSGE models, most central banks still rely on traditional macroeconometric models for short-term forecasting. However, the effects of alternative policies are increasingly studied using DSGE methods. Since DSGE models are constructed on the basis of assumptions about agents' preferences, it is possible to ask whether the policies considered are Pareto optimal, or how well they satisfy some other social welfare criterion derived from preferences (Woodford, 2003, p. 12).
At present two competing schools of thought form the bulk of DSGE modeling.[1]
The European Central Bank (ECB) has developed a DSGE model, often called the Smets-Wouters model, which it uses to analyze the economy of the Eurozone as a whole (in other words, the model does not analyze individual European countries separately). The model is intended as an alternative to the Area-Wide Model (AWM), a more traditional empirical forecasting model which the ECB has been using for several years. The ECB webpage that describes the Smets-Wouters model also discusses the advantages of building a DSGE model instead of relying on more traditional methods.
The equations in the Smets-Wouters model describe the choices of three types of decision makers: households, who made an optimal trade-off between consumption and worked hours, under a budget contraint; firms, who optimize theirs labor and capital to employ; and the central bank, which controls monetary policy. The parameters in the equations were estimated using Bayesian statistical techniques so that the model approximately describes the dynamics of GDP, consumption, investment, prices, wages, employment, and interest rates in the Eurozone economy. In order to accurately reproduce the sluggish behavior of some of these variables, the model incorporates several types of frictions that slow down adjustment to shocks, including sticky prices and wages, and adjustment costs in investment.
Willem Buiter of the London School of Economics has argued that DSGE models rely excessively on an assumption of complete markets, and are unable to describe the highly nonlinear dynamics of economic fluctuations, making training in 'state-of-the-art' macroeconomic modeling "a privately and socially costly waste of time and resources".[3]
N. Gregory Mankiw, regarded as one of the founders of New Keynesian DSGE modeling, has also argued that
Michael Woodford, replying to Mankiw, argues that DSGE models are commonly used by central banks today, and have strongly influenced policy makers like Ben Bernanke. However, he argues that what is learned from DSGE models is not so different from traditional Keynesian analysis:
Narayana Kocherlakota, President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, acknowledges that DSGE models were not very useful for analyzing the financial crisis of 2007-2010.[6] Nonetheless, he argues that the applicability of these models is improving, and that there is growing consensus among macroeconomists that DSGE models need to incorporate both price stickiness and financial market frictions.
The United States Congress hosted hearings on macroeconomic modeling methods on July 20, 2010, to investigate why macroeconomists failed to foresee the Financial crisis of 2007-2010. Robert Solow blasted DSGE models currently in use:
V.V. Chari pointed out, however, that state-of-the-art DSGE models are more sophisticated than their critics suppose:
Chari also argued that current DSGE models frequently incorporate frictional unemployment, financial market imperfections, and sticky prices and wages, and therefore imply that the macroeconomy behaves in a suboptimal way which monetary and fiscal policy may be able to improve.[8]
Commenting on the Congressional session, The Economist asked whether agent-based models might better predict financial crises than DSGE models.[9]
Woah, stay, stay, stay
Daisy, daisy
I love daisies, I love daisies
I love pushin' up your favorite daisies
Daisy
This is Posdnuos
The president of a paragraph
Paragraph, president
President preachin' 'bout the on-tech
Known for the new step
Stop and take a bow
Amityville resident
Resident supported by the speaker view
Want to feel it in your shoe
Let me show you how
Platform, witnesses
Witnesses, show you to my show-lab
Fill you with my vocab
Hope you have a spoon
Discuss contracts
You like the way I vocalize
And bring it to a compromise
My P.A. won't set up till noon
It's a D.A.I.S.Y. age
Sun, ceilin'
Ceilin' connects to the sun
Burnin' inside everyone
On a side, plug-a-fied sire
One million
Demonstrations have been heard
My hair burns when I'm referred
Kid shouts, my roof is on fire
Go dancin'
Dancin' like a bandit
Psychics try to stand it
Keep it up until they burn a cell
Romancin'
Romancin' dialect in shows
Posdnuos creatin' flow
You say you didn't know
Oh well, it's a D.A.I.S.Y. age
Pedal, promenade
Promenade people to the providence
Dove will show dominance
Inside of every phrase
Rebel, renegade
Renegade reachin' only topflight
Can't find your new height
Think you need a raise
Dialect, ultimate
Ultimate strings from the soul stuff
Copies always stayin' rough
Before they go to plate
Try a pack, it'll stick
Stick to you but won't deflate
Keepin' all the levels straight
I tell you, mate that we're top rate
'Cause it's a D.A.I.S.Y. age
The speak, motor
Motor is the heartbeat
Sleepin' in your car seat
Kept alive to every mile discovered
Complete quota
Quota sharp at 12 noon
Risen to a new tune
Positive is greater than the others
Image, mirror
Mirror image don't contend
Vocals should be comprehended
Silver audience'll say what's said
Scrimmage, nearer
Nearer to the goal line
Forget about the Rose Wine
The Soul will let you know it's time
And it's a D.A.I.S.Y. age
La la la la, lah
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
La la la la, lah
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
La la la la, lah
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
La la la la, lah
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
La la la la, lah
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
La la la la, lah
This is a D.A.I.S.Y. age
Sing about the D.A.I.S.Y. age
Sing about the D.A.I.S.Y. age
Sing about the D.A.I.S.Y. age
Let it rain, let it rain
Let it rain, rain on a daisy
Let it rain on a daisy
Let it rain on a daisy
Rain on, rain on