Credit sharing is one of the main forms of cooperation between FV automakers and NEV automakers under the dual-credit policy. At present, the Chinese government stipulates that only if the shareholding ratio exceeds 25% can credits be shared between cooperative automakers. In this section, we will discuss the two main credit-sharing scenarios. One is credit sharing dominated by FV automakers, such as the relationship between GWM and Yogomo. The other is credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker, such as the relationships between BYD and Toyota and BAIC Shenbao (X35) and BAIC BJEV (EU260). In the former scenario, the credit costs and credit benefits will be borne by the FV automaker, while in the latter scenario, the NEV automaker will bear the credit costs and credit benefits. Similarly, we will discuss the equilibrium solutions, the optimal production strategies, and some important properties for both parties under these two credit-sharing scenarios.
5.1. Credit Sharing Dominated by the FV Automaker
The FV automaker will bear the credit costs and credit benefits when it dominates the credit sharing. For example, in the cooperation between GWM and Yogomo, Yogomo’s NEV credits will be transferred to GWM to meet GWM’s great demand for positive NEV credits. As a transaction, GWM will hold a 25% stake in Yogomo and provide Yogomo with advanced vehicle manufacturing technologies to enhance the competitiveness of its NEVs in the vehicle market. The profit function of both parties in this scenario can be obtained as follows.
Similar to
Section 4, according to Equations (4) and (5), the equilibrium solutions of both parties under the three production strategies can be deduced in the following proposition.
Proposition 4. The equilibrium production quantities of both parties, with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker, are as follows:
According to Proposition 4, credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker will cause the following changes in the equilibrium production quantities compared with the scenario of no credit sharing.
Under the simultaneous production strategy (S1) and the NEV priority production strategy (S3), credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker will increase the production of FVs and reduce the production of NEVs. Obviously, under these two production strategies, the FV automaker has an incentive to convert its credit advantages into production advantages. However, it is counterintuitive that under the FV priority production strategy (S2), the production of FVs will not increase but will decline. It may be that the credit advantage of the FV automaker eases the competition between the two parties, thereby weakening the motivation of the FV automaker to use its first-mover advantage to maintain its market share. In other words, credit sharing can enable the two parties to avoid price wars to a certain extent and achieve a win–win situation.
Again, the following lemmas are obtained by drawing on Proposition 4.
Lemma 6. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker, , and decrease in and increase in , and , and and increase in and decrease in .
Lemma 6 implies that a high credit price and low production cost are undoubtedly more conducive to the development of NEVs. This conclusion is consistent with the scenario of no credit sharing. Therefore, regardless of whether credits are shared, maintaining a reasonable credit price is a necessary condition for the dual-credit policy to be effective.
Lemma 7. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker,
(1) under all three production strategies S1–S3, when the FV automaker tries to reduce , the production of FVs will increase, and the production of NEVs will decrease;
(2) the production of FVs and NEVs under the simultaneous production strategy (S1) and the NEV priority production strategy (S3) will have nothing to do with ;
(3) under the FV priority production strategy (S2), when the NEV automaker tries to increase , the production of FVs will decrease, and the production of NEVs will increase.
Lemma 7 implies that credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker will not change the impact of the FV credit coefficient on both parties’ production but will change the impact of the NEV credit coefficient on both parties’ production. Especially under production strategies S1 and S3, because the NEV automaker no longer enjoys credit benefits, it loses the influence of the NEV credit coefficient on the production decisions of both parties. However, under the FV priority production strategy (S2), the FV automaker must consider NEV production to optimize its credit benefits. This instead prompts the NEV credit coefficient to become a key constraint for the development of FVs. Therefore, even if current automakers, such as GWM, generally adopt the FV priority production strategy (S2) and even take advantage of credit sharing, NEV automakers, such as Yogomo, can still gain market competitive advantages by increasing their cruising range.
Lemma 8. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker,
(1) and decrease in and and increase in , and
(2) when is high, decreases in and increases in , and when is low, increases in and decreases in .
Lemma 8 implies that in most cases, credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker does not change the relationship between the production quantities of both parties and NEV substitutability. The higher the NEV substitutability is, the stronger the competitiveness of NEVs. However, under the FV priority production strategy (S2), there are counterintuitive results. When the credit price is low, the production quantities of NEVs will not increase because of the increase in their substitutability but rather will decrease. The reason may be that due to the low credit price, the dual-credit policy has not effectively changed the competitive advantages of both parties. As NEV substitutability improves, FV automakers will use first-mover advantages, such as price wars, to suppress NEVs and maintain their market position. Once the credit price increases, FV automakers will have to consider the credit benefits generated by the growth of NEVs and thus tend to cooperate rather than suppress. Therefore, in the scenario of credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker, it is counterproductive to improve NEV substitutability, and increasing the credit price is more important for the development of NEVs.
Drawing on Proposition 4, the conditions of vehicle market size that make FVs and NEVs coexist in the vehicle market (i.e., , ) under these three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by FV automakers are derived in Proposition 5.
Proposition 5. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker, FVs and NEVs can coexist in the market only when the vehicle market size meets the following conditions:
(1) ,
(2) , ;
(3) , .
Compared with the scenario without credit sharing, the critical market size of each production strategy with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker also changes as follows. Obviously, under production strategies S1 and S3, credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker reduces the critical market size of FVs and increases the critical market size of NEVs. Thus, under these two production strategies, NEVs will have more difficulty surviving in the vehicle market, and FVs will survive more easily. Interestingly, under the FV priority production strategy (S2), the critical market size of FVs also becomes larger. In other words, it is more difficult for both parties to coexist in the vehicle market.
Similarly, let
and
; then, we can obtain the critical lines
,
, and
, respectively, and
. The market size threshold for each production strategy with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker is summarized in
Table 2. For example, when
, if
, production strategies S1–S3 are all applicable, and if
, NEVs will be expelled from the vehicle market under the FV priority production strategy (S2). Therefore, only production strategies S1 and S3 will be applicable under this condition. Then, if
, these three production strategies will no longer be applicable and will degenerate into a monopoly setting with only FVs. Similar conclusions apply to other intervals of
and
. Therefore, only when the credit price or market size is large enough will both parties have enough options to improve production strategies and credit benefits.
Considering the effect of changes in credit prices and NEV production cost on production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker leads to the following proposition.
Proposition 6. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker, as shown in Figure 2, (1) the critical lines for production quantities under production strategies S1–S3 intersect at points , , and , respectively;
(2) the applicable intervals of the three production strategies S1–S3 are , , and , respectively; otherwise, FVs and NEVs will not coexist in the vehicle market;
(3) the optimal production strategy for each applicable interval is shown in Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5.
For example, in interval , the simultaneous production strategy (S1) will be the optimal strategy; in interval , the NEV priority production strategy (S3) will be the optimal strategy; and in interval , the FV priority production strategy (S2) will be the optimal strategy.
Figure 2.
Optimal production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker.
Figure 2.
Optimal production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker.
There is no doubt that credit sharing has a significant impact on the applicable interval of the production strategy and the selection of the optimal strategy. Comparing
Figure 1 and
Figure 2, we find that the applicable interval of the three production strategies has been greatly reduced on the horizontal axis. This means that credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker has higher requirements for the NEV production cost. Only when the NEV production cost is reduced to a certain level may the two parties consider credit-sharing cooperation dominated by the FV automaker. At the same time, the critical lines of the credit price of each production strategy have been raised, indicating that credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker also requires a higher credit price. In addition, the applicable interval in this scenario has become more complicated.
In interval
of
Figure 2, the applicable interval of all production strategies can be subdivided into nine intervals
. In interval
, only the simultaneous production strategy (S1) is applicable, so it is also the optimal production strategy. In interval
, production strategies S1 and S3 are applicable. However, the total profit of production strategy S3 is higher than that of production strategy S1, so production strategy S3 is the optimal strategy. Similarly, in interval
, all three production strategies are applicable, and the optimal strategy is production strategy S2. The applicable production strategy for each interval is represented by a black circle, and the optimal production strategy is represented by a red circle, as shown in
Table 3. Obviously, in intervals
,
,
,
and
, the FV or NEV priority production strategy can be adopted to realize the Pareto optimization of both parties’ total profit.
In intervals II and III, the applicable interval of each production strategy will become simpler. In these intervals, the Pareto optimization of total profit can also be achieved by selecting one of the three production strategies.
For a relatively stable NEV production cost
in a certain period, we can also obtain the length of these three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker as follows.
Lemma 9. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker,
(1) ; i.e., the simultaneous production strategy (S1) is the longest, and the FV priority production strategy (S2) is the shortest;
(2) under all the production strategies, when the FV automaker tries to reduce , the length of all production strategies will increase, and when the NEV automaker tries to increase , it has no impact on the length of production strategies S1 and S3 but will shorten the length of production strategy S2;
(3) as NEV substitutability increases, the length of all production strategies will decrease.
Lemma 9 is basically consistent with Lemma 4 without credit sharing. The difference is that under the simultaneous production strategy (S1) and the FV priority production strategy (S3), the NEV automaker will not be able to influence the strategy length for both parties by increasing its cruising range. This implies that in the scenario of credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker, the selection of a production strategy will be more beneficial to the FV automaker than to the NEV automaker.
Similarly, we discuss the total credits of each production strategy with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker in the following lemma.
Lemma 10. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker,
(1) in the high credit interval , ; in the moderate credit interval , ; in the low credit interval , ;
(2) the NEV priority production strategy (S3) most easily achieves credit equilibrium, and the FV priority production strategy (S2) has the greatest difficulty achieving credit equilibrium.
Interestingly, in the scenario of credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker, when the credit price is high, production strategy S1 instead of production strategy S3 maximizes the total credits of both parties. The reason is that because the NEV automaker no longer bears credit benefits, regardless of how high the credit price is, its first-mover advantage will not take into account the credit benefits. However, under the simultaneous production strategy (S1), as the FV automaker bears credit benefits, a high credit price will prompt it to reduce certain FV production quantities to obtain higher credit benefits.
5.2. Credit Sharing Dominated by the NEV Automaker
For cooperative companies such as BYD, Toyota, BAIC Shenbao (X35), and BAIC BJEV (EU260), the credit benefits and credit costs are borne by the NEV automaker. In their cooperative relationship, the NEVs are relatively mature and have sufficient positive NEV credits. The profit function of both parties in this scenario can be obtained as follows.
According to Equations (6) and (7), the equilibrium outcomes of both parties under the three production strategies can be deduced in the following proposition.
Proposition 7. The equilibrium production quantities of both parties, with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker, are as follows:
Credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker will cause the following changes in the equilibrium production quantities compared with the scenario of no credit sharing.
Regardless of the production strategy, credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker will increase the production quantities of FVs and reduce the production quantities of NEVs. Interestingly, this conclusion is basically consistent with the scenario of credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker. Therefore, even if the NEV automaker dominates credit sharing, it is not conducive to the development of NEVs. In this scenario, NEV automakers share the credit costs of FV automakers, thereby increasing production costs in disguise.
Proposition 8. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker, FVs and NEVs can coexist in the market only when the vehicle market size meets the following conditions:
(1) ,
(2) , ,
(3) , .
Compared with the scenario without credit sharing, the critical market size of each production strategy under credit sharing dominated by the FV automaker has also changed. Obviously, regardless of the production strategy, credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker reduces the critical market size of FVs and increases the critical market size of NEVs. This means that credit sharing makes the threshold for NEV automakers to survive in the vehicle market even higher.
Similarly, when
and
, we can obtain the critical lines
,
, and
, respectively, and
. The market size threshold for each production strategy with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker is summarized in
Table 6. For example, when
, if
, production strategies S1–S3 are all applicable; however, if
, NEVs will be expelled from the vehicle market under the FV priority production strategy (S2). Therefore, only production strategies S1 and S3 will be applicable under this condition. Again, if
, NEVs will be expelled from the vehicle market under the simultaneous production strategy (S1), and only production strategy S3 will be applicable under this condition. Then, if
, the three production strategies will no longer be applicable, and the situation will degenerate into a monopoly setting with only FVs. Similar conclusions can be drawn for other intervals of
and
.
Considering the effect of changes in credit prices and NEV production cost on production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker leads to the following proposition.
Proposition 9. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker, as shown in Figure 3, (1) the applicable intervals of the three production strategies S1–S3 are , , and , respectively; otherwise, FVs and NEVs will not coexist in the vehicle market;
(2) the optimal production strategy for each applicable interval is shown in Table 7, Table 8 and Table 9.
For example, in interval , the simultaneous production strategy (S1) will be the optimal strategy; in interval , the NEV priority production strategy (S3) will be the optimal strategy; in intervals and the simultaneous production strategy (S1) will be the optimal strategy; in interval , the FV priority production strategy (S2) will be the optimal strategy.
Figure 3.
Optimal production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker.
Figure 3.
Optimal production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker.
Credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker also has a significant impact on the applicable interval of both parties’ production strategies and the selection of optimal strategies. Comparing
Figure 1 and
Figure 3, we find that not only is the applicable interval extended on the horizontal axis but also all the critical lines have dropped. This means that in this scenario, all production strategies have lower requirements for the NEV production cost and credit price. In other words, it will be easier for both parties to coexist in the vehicle market. Similarly, the applicable interval in this scenario also becomes more complicated.
In interval I, the applicable interval of all production strategies can be subdivided into five intervals . In interval , the simultaneous production strategy (S1) and the FV priority production strategy (S2) will be applicable, and the production strategy S1 is the optimal production strategy. In interval , all three production strategies, S1–S3, are applicable, and the NEV priority production strategy will maximize both parties’ total profits. When the credit price is relatively moderate, i.e., in intervals and , the simultaneous production strategy (S1) will be the optimal strategy. However, when the credit price is low, i.e., in interval , the FV priority production strategy becomes the optimal production strategy. Only in intervals and can the FV or NEV priority production strategy be adopted to realize the Pareto optimization of both parties’ total profit.
Similarly, in intervals II and III, the applicable interval of all production strategies can be subdivided into six intervals and seven intervals , respectively. In these intervals, the Pareto optimization of total profit can also be achieved by selecting one of the three production strategies.
For a relatively stable NEV production cost
in a certain period, we can also obtain the length of the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker as follows. Interestingly, in this scenario, the length of all production strategies is fixed and has nothing to do with NEV production cost.
Lemma 11. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker,
(1) , i.e., the strategy length of the simultaneous production strategy (S1) is the longest, and the strategy length of the NEV priority production strategy (S3) is the shortest;
(2) when FV automakers try to reduce , it has no impact on the strategy length of production strategies S1 and S2 but will extend the strategy length of production strategy S3; and when NEV automakers try to increase , the strategy length of all production strategies will be shortened;
(3) as NEV substitutability increases, the strategy length of all production strategies will decrease.
Lemma 11 implies that if NEV automakers have both the first-mover advantage and the credit-sharing advantage, it will not be conducive to the coexistence of both parties in the vehicle market. FV automakers can expand their coexistence room by actively reducing fuel consumption. However, the way to reduce fuel consumption does not apply to production strategies S1 and S2. Moreover, with the increase in the cruising range of NEVs, the living room of FVs in the vehicle market will be further occupied by NEVs, and FV automakers will lose part of their production decision-making power.
Similarly, we can also discuss the total credits of each production strategy with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker in the following lemma.
Lemma 12. For the three production strategies with credit sharing dominated by the NEV automaker,
(1) when
and credit price is low (), ; when , ;
(2) the NEV priority production strategy (S3) most easily achieves credit equilibrium, and the FV priority production strategy (S2) has the greatest difficulty achieving credit equilibrium.
In the early stage of the implementation of the dual-credit policy, the credit price is relatively low, and the NEV production cost is relatively high. During this period, if NEV automakers dominate credit sharing, then adopting the simultaneous production strategy (S1) can maximize the two parties’ total credits. However, with the rapid development of NEV technologies, once the NEV production cost is reduced to a certain extent, the NEV priority production strategy will be most conducive to maximizing both parties’ total credits. Moreover, regardless of which party dominates credit sharing, production strategy S3 is the production strategy that most easily achieves credit equilibrium. This is a revelation for FV automakers that have a large demand for positive NEV credits.