Jump to content

Taxation in Norway: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
No edit summary
Carpalim (talk | contribs)
corrected 2009 tax level, ref. Taxation_in_Norway#Tax_level
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Taxation}}
{{Taxation}}
'''[[Tax]]ation in [[Norway]]''' is levied by the [[government of Norway|central government]], the [[Counties of Norway|county municipality]] (''fylkeskommune'') and the [[municipalities of Norway|municipality]] (''kommune''). The tax level in Norway is among the highest in the world. In 2010 the total tax revenue was 57.3 % of the gross domestic product (GDP). Many direct and indirect taxes exist. The most important taxes—in terms of revernue—are [[income tax]] and [[Value added tax|VAT]]. Most [[direct taxes]] are collected by the Norwegian Tax Administration (''Skatteetaten'') and most [[indirect taxes]] are collected by the Norwegian Customs and Excise Authorities (''Toll- og avgiftsetaten'').
'''[[Tax]]ation in [[Norway]]''' is levied by the [[government of Norway|central government]], the [[Counties of Norway|county municipality]] (''fylkeskommune'') and the [[municipalities of Norway|municipality]] (''kommune''). The tax level in Norway is among the highest in the world. In 2009 the total tax revenue was 41.0 % of the gross domestic product (GDP). Many direct and indirect taxes exist. The most important taxes—in terms of revernue—are [[income tax]] and [[Value added tax|VAT]]. Most [[direct taxes]] are collected by the Norwegian Tax Administration (''Skatteetaten'') and most [[indirect taxes]] are collected by the Norwegian Customs and Excise Authorities (''Toll- og avgiftsetaten'').


The Norwegian word for tax is ''skatt'' which originates from the [[Old Norse]] word ''skattr''.<ref>{{cite web
The Norwegian word for tax is ''skatt'' which originates from the [[Old Norse]] word ''skattr''.<ref>{{cite web

Revision as of 12:01, 23 September 2011

Taxation in Norway is levied by the central government, the county municipality (fylkeskommune) and the municipality (kommune). The tax level in Norway is among the highest in the world. In 2009 the total tax revenue was 41.0 % of the gross domestic product (GDP). Many direct and indirect taxes exist. The most important taxes—in terms of revernue—are income tax and VAT. Most direct taxes are collected by the Norwegian Tax Administration (Skatteetaten) and most indirect taxes are collected by the Norwegian Customs and Excise Authorities (Toll- og avgiftsetaten).

The Norwegian word for tax is skatt which originates from the Old Norse word skattr.[1]

Taxation in the Constitution

The Storting is to be the final authority in matters concerning the finances of the State, including taxes.

According to the Norwegian Constitution, the Storting is to be the final authority in matters concerning the finances of the State - expenditures as well as revenues. This follows from Article 75 a of the Norwegian Constitution:

It devolves upon the Storting (...) to impose taxes, duties, customs and other public charges, which shall not, however, remain operative beyond 31 December of the succeeding year, unless they are expressly renewed by a new Storting;[2]

The Ministry of Finance sets up the Governments tax program, which is included in the fiscal budget proposal. The Budget is submitted to the Storting as Proposition No. 1 to the Storting.[3]

Tax administration

The Ministry of Finance sets up the Government's tax program.

In order to implement the tax program decided by the Storting, the Ministry of Finance is supported by two subordinate agencies and bodies.

The Tax Administration (Skatteetaten) ensures that taxes are set and collected in the correct manner. It issues tax cards, collect advance tax and check the tax-return forms that are required to be submitted each year. The Tax Administration also determines and monitors national insurance contributions, and value-added tax and are responsible for providing professional guidance and instruction to local tax collection offices that collect direct taxes.[4]

The Customs and Excise Authorities (Toll- og avgiftsetaten) ensures that customs and excise duties are correctly levied and paid on time. In addition, they are responsible for preventing the illegal import and export of goods in Norway. The customs and excise authorities set and collect customs duties, value-added tax on imports and special duties.[5]

Tax level

Total tax revenue as percentage of GDP in Norway and OECD, 1965-2007

In 2009, the total tax revenue was 41.0 % of the gross domestic product (GDP). Of the OECD member countries Denmark, Sweden, Belgium, Italy, France, Finland and Austria had a higher tax level than Norway in 2009. The tax level in Norway has fluctuated between 40 and 45 % of GDP since the 1970s.[6]

The relatively high tax level is a result of the large Norwegian welfare state. Most of the tax revenue is spent on public services like health services, the operation of hospitals, education and transportation.[7]

The level of revenues are also influenced by the important role played by oil and gas extraction in the Norwegian economy.

Allocation of tax revenues

In 2010, 86 % of taxes were paid to the central government, 2 % were paid to regional government, while local government received 12 % of the total tax revenue.

The main revenue sources for the central government are VAT, tax on income in the petroleum sector, employers’ social security contributions and tax on "ordinary income" from individual taxpayers, while the main revenue source for local and regional authorities is tax on "ordinary income" from individual taxpayers.

The table below provides a general overview of the main groups of taxes and shows which parts of the public sector that receive revenue from each main group.

Accrued taxes distributed according to creditors. Estimate for 2010. NOK billions[8]
Central government Local government Regional government In total
Individual taxpayers 218.5 115.9 22.2 356.7
Tax on "ordinary income" 104.5 107.4 22.2 234.2
Surtax 19.0 - - 19.0
Employee’s and self-employed’s social security contributions 90.2 - - 90.2
Tax on net wealth 4.8 8.5 - 13.3
Businesses (whose taxes are payable the year after the income year) 59.2 1.3 0.2 60.8
Income tax (including power stations) 58.9 1.3 0.2 60.4
Tax on net wealth 0.3 - - 0.3
Property tax - 6.6 - 6.6
Employers’ social security contributions 132.0 - - 132.0
Indirect taxes 290.7 - - 290.7
VAT 194.4 - - 194.4
Excise duties and customs duties 96.3 - - 96.3
Petroleum 181.4 - - 181.4
Tax on income 177.6 - - 177.6
Extraction tax 3.8 - - 3.8
Other direct and indirect taxes 27.8 0.5 - 28.4
Social security and pension premiums, other central government and social security accounts 21.0 - - 21.0
Tax on dividends to foreign shareholders 1.7 - - 1.7
Inheritance and gift tax 2.2 - - 2.2
Other taxes 2.9 0.5 - 3.4
Total direct and indirect taxes 909.7 124.3 22.5 1 056.5
Of which direct taxes 619.0 124.3 22.5 765.8

Direct taxes

Personal income tax

Marginal tax rates on wage income for a person in Class 1 with only standard deductions, 2010

Norway has, like several other Nordic countries, adopted a dual income tax. Under the dual income tax, income from labour and pensions is taxed at progressive rates, while capital income is taxed at a flat rate.[9]

Employee's and self-employed's social security contributions

Social security contribution (trygdeavgift) is levied on "personal income" (personinntekt). Personal income includes wage income and business income due to active efforts, but generally not capital income, and there is no deductions in labor income and limited right to charge a deduction from business income. The tax rate is 3.0 % for pension income, 7.8 % for wage income and 11 % for other business income.[8]

No social security contribution is paid for income below the "exemption card threshold" (frikortgrense). This threshold is NOK 39 997 in 2010.[10] Then, social security contribution is paid at a levelling rate of 25 % (of the income above NOK 39 600) until this gives a higher total tax than using the standard tax rate on all personal income. Then the general rates are used.[8]

Social security contribution. Tax rates and thresholds for 2010[8]
Lower threshold for payment of employee’s social security contribution NOK 39 600
Levelling rate 25.0 %
Rate
Wage income 7.8 %
Income from self-employment in primary sector 7.8 %
Income from other self-employment 11.0 %
Pension income, etc. 3.0 %

Tax on "ordinary income"

Ordinary income (alminnelig inntekt), which consists of all taxable income (wages, pensions, business income, taxable share income and other income) minus deductions (losses, debt interest, etc.), is taxes at a flat rate of 28 %. In 2010, the tax on "ordinary income" is split in a local tax (kommunale skattøre) of 12,80 %, a regional tax (fylkeskommunale skattøre) of 2,65 % and a tax to the central government (fellesskatt) of 12,55 %.[11]

Deductions
Average tax rates on wage income for a person in Class 1 with only standard deductions, 2010

The current income tax system has two standard deductions: Basic allowance (minstefradrag) and personal allowance (personfradrag).

The basic allowance a set as a proportion of the income with upper and lower limits. For wage income, the rate is 36 % and the upper limit is NOK 72 800 in 2010. The lower limit is the so-called special wage income allowance (lønnsfradrag), which is NOK 31 800 in 2010. The basic allowance in pension income is slightly lower than the basic allowance in wage income. In 2010, the rate is 26 % with a lower limit of NOK 4 000 and a upper limit of NOK 60 950.[8]

The personal allowance is a standard deduction from ordinary income, meaning that it is given in all income (wages, pensions, capital and business income). Single parents and married couples where one spouse has a low income may be taxed in Class 2 and thus given double personal allowance. In 2010, the personal allowance is NOK 42 210 in Class 1 and NOK 84 420 in Class 2.[8]

Standard deductions. Tax rates and thresholds for 2010[8]
Personal allowance
Class 1 NOK 42 210
Class 2 NOK 84 420
Basic allowance in wage income
Rate 36.0 %
Lower limit NOK 4 000
Upper limit NOK 72 800
Basic allowance in pension income
Rate 26.0 %
Lower limit NOK 4 000
Upper limit NOK 60 950
Special wage income allowance NOK 31 800

Ordinary income is a net income concept, meaning that it will be deduction for costs incurred to acquire income. There is therefore a deduction for expenses related to acquisition of income if these are higher than the basic allowance. There is also several other deductions from ordinary income; special allowance for disability, special tax allowance for pensioners, the tax limitation rule for the disabled, seamen’s allowance, fishermen’s allowance, special allowance for self-employed within agriculture, special allowance for high expenses linked to illness, allowance for payments to individual pension schemes, allowance for travel between home and work, allowance for donations to voluntary organisations, allowance for paid union fees, allowance for home investment savings scheme for people under 34 years, parental allowance for documented expenses for childminding and childcare, etc.[8]

The shareholder model

The shareholder model (aksjonærmodellen) implies that dividends exceeding a risk-free return on the investment (the cost base of the shares) are taxed as "ordinary income" when distributed to personal shareholders. When added to the 28 % company taxation, this gives a total maximum marginal tax rate on dividends of 48.16 % (0.28+0.72*0.28).[12]

The part of the dividend that is not exceeding a risk-free return on the investment, is not taxed on the hand of the shareholder, and is thus subject to the 28 % company taxation only. If the dividend for one year is less than the calculated risk-free interest, the surplus tax free amount can be carried forward to be offset against dividends distributed a later year, or against any capital gain from the alienation of the same share.[12]

The shielding method for partnerships

The shielding method for partnerships (skjermingsmetoden for deltakerlignede selskaper or deltakemodellen) implies that the partners are subject to 28 % taxation upon all income irrespective of distribution, supplemented by 28 % additional taxation on distributed profits. In order to compensate for the initial 28 % taxation, only 72 % of the distributed profit will be taxable. Furthermore, only the distributed profit exceeding a risk-free interest on the capital invested in the partnership will be taxable. The maximum marginal tax rate of distributed income will be 48.16 percent (0.28+0.72*0.28).[12]

The shielding method for self-employed individuals

The shielding method for self-employed individuals (skjermingsmetoden for enkeltpersonforetak or foretaksmodellen) implies that business profits exceeding a risk-free interest on the capital invested is taxed as personal income (the tax base for social security contributions and suretax).[12]

Surtax

The personal income surtax (toppskatt) is, as the employee’s and self-employed’s social security contributions, levied on "personal income". In 2010, the surtax is 9 % for income that exceeds NOK 456 400 (the threshold for step 1) and 12 % for income that exceeds NOK 741 700 (the threshold for step 2).[8]

Surtax. Tax rates and thresholds for 2010[8]
Bracket 1
Threshold NOK 456 400
Rate 9.0 %
Bracket 2
Threshold NOK 741 700
Rate 12.0 %

Employers' social security contribution

Employers in both private and public sector is obliged to pay the employer's social security contricution on labour costs. The employers’ social security contribution are regionally differentiated, so that the tax rate depends on where the business is located. In 2010, the rates vary from 0 % to 14.1 %.[8]

When the employers' social security contribution is included, the maximum marginal tax rate on labour costs is 54,3 %.[8]

Corporate taxation

Corporate taxable profits (ordinary income) are taxes at a flat rate of 28 %. The tax base is the sum of operating profit/loss, financial revenues and net capital gains minus tax depreciation. In addition, the profit is taxed on the owner's hand through dividend and capital gain taxation.[12]

The exemption method

The exemption method (Norwegian: fritaksmetoden) implies that limited companies are exempted from tax on dividends and on capital gains from the alienation of shares, correspondingly the right to deduct losses on shares was abolished. Combined with the proposal of a model for taxation of individual shareholders (the shareholders model), dividends and gains on shares will be taxed on extraction from the company sector, and only to the extent such income exceeds a risk-free rate of return.[13]

Taxation of petroleum activities

The taxation of petroleum activities is based on the rules governing ordinary business taxation. There is considerable excess return (resource rent) associated with the extraction of oil and gas. Therefore a special tax of 50 % on income from petroleum extraction has been introduced, in addition to the ordinary income tax of 28 %. Consequently, the marginal tax rate on the excess return within the petroleum sector is 78 %.[14]

Taxation of power plants

The taxation of power plants is based on the rules governing ordinary business taxation. There is considerable excess return (resource rent) associated with the production of hydro power. Therefore a special tax of 30 % on income from hydro power plants has been introduced, in addition to the ordinary income tax of 28 %. Consequently, the marginal tax rate on the excess return within the power sector is 58 %.[15][16]

Taxation of shipping income

Shipping companies shipping income is exempted from income taxation, but they pay a tonnage tax of vessels they own, and in some cases the vessel they hire. The tax is based on vessels net tonnage (tons). This tonnage tax must be paid regardless of whether the vessel has been in operation or not.[17][18]

Tax on net wealth

Wealth tax is levied at both municipal and central government level. The tax base is net wealth less a basic deduction. In 2010, the basic deduction is NOK 700 000 (NOK 1 400 000 for married couples). As a consequence of basic deduction in combination with gentle assessment rules, especially of housing, the wealth tax is of little importance to most tax-paying households. The municipal tax rate is 0.7 %, while the national tax rate is 0.4 %.[8]

Inheritance and gift tax

There is an inheritance and gift tax, with a zero rate up to taxable amounts of NOK 470 000. From this level, the rates range from 6 % to 15 % depending on the status of the beneficiary and the size of the taxable amount.[8]

Inheritance and gift tax. Tax rates and thresholds for 2010[8]
Treshold
Level 1 NOK 470 000
Level 2 NOK 800 000
Rates
Children and parents
Level 1 6.0 %
Level 2 10.0 %
Other beneficiaries
Level 1 8.0 %
Level 2 15.0 %

Property tax

The municipal councils may choose to impose property taxes in accordance with the Property Tax Law. All property owners may be obliged to pay this tax. The tax is calculated as being between 0.2 % and 0.7 % of a property's value.[19] In 2009, 299 municipalities had chosen to tax property and 131 municipalities had chosen not to impose property tax.[20]

Indirect taxes

Value added tax

Value added tax (Norwegian: merverdiavgift) is a tax on consumption that must be paid on domestic sales of goods and services liable for tax in all links in the chain of distribution and on imports. The rates for VAT for 2010 are as follows:

  • 25% general rate
  • 14% on foodstuffs
  • 8% on the supply of passenger transport services and the procurement of such services, on the letting of hotel rooms and holiday homes, and on transport services regarding the ferrying of vehicles as part of the domestic road network. The same rate applies to cinema tickets and to the television license.[8]

In principle, all sales of goods and services are liable to VAT. However, some supplies are exempt (without a credit for input tax), which means that such supplies fall entirely outside the scope of the VAT Act. Businesses that only have such supplies cannot register for VAT, and are not entitled to deduct VAT. Financial services, health services, social services and educational services are all outside the scope of the VAT Act.[21]

Some supplies are zero-rated (exempt with a credit for input tax). When a supply is zero-rated, it means that the supply falls within the scope of the VAT Act, but output VAT shall not be calculated as the rate is zero. Newspapers, books and periodicals are zero-rated.[22]

Excise duties

Excise duties (Norwegian: særavgifter) are taxes levied on particular goods and services, of foreign or domestic origin. In addition there are excise duties connected to ownership or change of ownership of certain goods and real property. Revenues mostly derive from the former category.

Excise duties can be on purely fiscal grounds, i.e. that they only intend to raise the state income, but excise duties can also be used as an instrument to correct for external effects, such as related to the use of health and environmentally damaging products.

The most important excise duties in Norway, in terms of revenue, are tax on alcoholic beverages, tax on tobacco goods, motor vehicle registration tax, annual tax on motor vehicles, road use tax on petrol, road use tax on diesel, electricity consumption tax, CO2 tax and stamp duty.[8]

Customs duties

Customs duties (Norwegian: toll) shall be paid upon importation of goods. The "ordinary" rate of the Customs Tariffs applies for goods imported from countries with whom Norway has not entered into a free trade agreement (FTA), and for goods imported from a FTA-party, but not satisfying by the conditions for preferential tariff treatment as set out in these agreements. All products originating in the Least Developed Countries are granted duty-free treatment[23]

The customs duties on agricultural products is an important part of the overall support for Norwegian agriculture. Of manufacturing goods only some clothing and textiles are currently subject to customs duties.

History

Middle Ages

Magnus Lagabøte's Landslov
National Archival Services of Norway

Taxation in Norway can be traced back to the petty kingdoms before the unification of Norway. The kings of the petty kingdoms were not permanent residents of one singel royal estate, but were moving around in their kingdom, staying for a while at royal estates in each part of it. The peasants in the area where the king stayed, were obliged to provide payment in kind to the king and his entourage. This obligation is called veitsle. This performance of the peasants to their king, has most likely been an important and necessary source of income for the petty kingdoms and made it possible for the king and his entourage to live off the profits from the farming society.[24]: 297  Veitsle was continued when the unified Norwegian kingdom arose. The early national kingdom had in addition other casual tax revenues like finnskatt (and possibly tax revenues from the Shetlands, Orkneys, Faroes and Hebrides) and trade and travel fees (landaurar).[24]: 294 

The second important tax that emerged during the unification was the leidang. This was originally a defensive scheme where all armed men would meet and fight for their king when peace was threatened, but in Norway the leidang evolved to primarily be a naval defence. The agreement between the king and his people must from the beginning have included a crew arrangement and an outfitting and provisioning system. The most important regular, often annual burden for the population, must have been the dietary performance to the crew of the leidang fleet. The provisioning system soon developed into a regular tax, the leidang tax. The leidang was codified in the provincial laws (Gulating law and Frostating law) and later in Magnus Lagabøte’s landslov.[24]: 262–73 

It was not just the king who demanded taxes. The church had significant tax revenues in the form of tithe which became law over most of the country in Magnus Erlingson’s days (1163-1184).[25]

The Kalmar Union and the union with Denmark

In the 1500s, the leidang tax was supplemented by additional taxes imposed when the government needed extra revenue, as in wartimes. From 1600 the additional taxes was imposed more frequently and around 1620 the tax became annual. The leilending (tenant farmer) tax was a property tax where farms were divided into three groups depending on the size of the farms (full farms, half farms and “ødegård”). The tax was from 1640's dependent on the land rent. In 1665, Norway got its first land register (Norwegian: matrikkel) with a land rent that reflected the value of the production of the farm. The leilending tax was therefore a tax on the expected returns in agriculture.[26]

In the 17th century customs increased in importance as a revenue source and became the governments’ main source of income in Norway. Both the rates and the number of commodities tariffs were imposed on increased. Until about 1670 the main objective of the customs duty was to provide government revenue, but customs gradually became a trade policy instrument used to protect domestic production against competition from imported goods.[26]

In the 17th century excises were introduced. The oldest excise duty still existing in Norway is the stamp duty which originates from the regulation regarding det stemplede papiir of 16 December 1676.[27]

In 1762 a new personal tax was introduced, the additional tax (ekstraskatten’’), a lump sum tax of one riksdaler’’ for each person above 12 years. The tax triggered a storm of indignation, and after a series complains to the king and regular riots, the Stril War, the tax was reduced and finally abolished in 1772.[28]

19th Century

In 1816, a number of old taxes to the state were merged and replaced by a direct land and township tax (Norwegian: repartisjonsskatt). The tax amount was divided by 4/5 on villages and 1/5 on the cities. The tax was levied on the land register in the villages and mainly on income and economic activity in cities. The tax was very unpopular among farmers, and it was abolished when the farmer's representatives won a majority in the 1836 election. From 1836 to 1892 there existed no direct taxes to the state.[29]

Before 1882, municipal expenditures were covered with several types of taxes. Taxes were paid directly to the various funds that were responsible for financing and operating various types of municipal services. In the cities there were two main taxes: the city tax and the poor tax. The City Tax was originally imposed on real estate and businesses, but during the 19th Century it evolved into a property tax. In the countryside there were more funds than in cities. The most important was the poor relief fund and the school fund. The taxes to these funds were determined, respectively by the poor commission and the school commission and were assessed on income, wealth and the value of the property. After the municipal self-government was introduced in 1837, the influence of elected representatives in the commissions and the commissions increased, and the taxes were soon under the control of the municipal council.[29]

In the tax reform of 1882 the system of earmarking the revenue for certain purposes or funds was abolished. Income and wealth tax became mandatory tax bases in addition to the property tax. Income and wealth was estimated discretionary basis by the tax authorities. The gross income was less the costs of acquiring the income was called expected income. It was then given an allowance depending on family responsibilities in order to arrive at taxable income.[30]

There were no state taxes in the period 1836-1892. The state got its revenue from customs and excise duties. These tax bases, however, was too narrow to cover the growth in government expenditure at the end of the 19th Century. Therefore a progressive income and property taxes to the state was introduced in 1892.[31]

20th Century

The tax reform in 1911 did not lead to significant changes in the tax system. The main change was that the tax return was introduced. Prior to the 1911 tax reform tax authorities had estimated taxable income and property. This system was now replaced by the taxpayers themselves reporting data on income and wealth.[32]

Throughout the 19th Century and until World War I, customs were the main source of income for the government. In most of this period customs duties contributed to more than 80% of the governments revenue. Throughout the 20 Century, tariffs had less and less financial importance. Excices was also an important source of revenue for the government. In the 19th Century alcohol tax and stamp duty were important sources of revenue. Excices became even more important during the World War I when taxes on tobacco and motor vehicles were introduced. A sales tax was introduced in 1935. This was a cumulative tax as originally constituted 1% of the market value of each commercial level. The rate was subsequently increased several times. In 1970, the GST replaced by value added tax (VAT).[33]

1992 tax reform

In recent times there have been two major tax reforms in Norway. The first, the tax reform of 1992, was a pervasive and principle based reform, inline with the international trend of broader tax base and lower rates. Corporate taxation was designed so that the taxable profit should correspond to the actual budget surplus. This meant, among other things that different industries, forms of ownership, financing methods and investment were treated equally (neutrality) and that revenues and related expenditures were subject to the same tax rate. In the personal income tax, a clearer distinction between labour income and investment income was introduced (split - a dual income tax system). Ordinary income, income less standard deductions and deductible expenses, was taxes at a flat rate of 28%. On personal income, income from work and pensions, there were in addition levied social security contributions and surtax. To avoid that income that was taxed at the corporate level also were taxed at the individual level (double taxation), the imputation tax credit for dividends and treasury system gains was introduced.

2006 tax reform

After the 1992 tax reform the marginal tax rate on labour income was much higher than the marginal tax rate on capital income. For self-employed, it was profitable to convert labour income to capital income (income shifting). In the 2006 tax reform, the income shifting problem was solved by reducing the top marginal tax rate on labour income and introducing a dividend and capital gains tax on return above the normal return of the capital invested (shareholder model). Company shareholders was exempt from dividend and capital gains tax (exemption method), while proprietorships and partnerships were taxes at similar principles as the shareholder model.

See also

Notes

  1. ^ "Bokmålsordboka" (in Norwegian). Dokumentasjonsprosjektet/EDD. 28 July 2008.
  2. ^ "The Constitution". Stortinget. 11 September 2008.
  3. ^ "About the Storting: Budget". Stortinget. 27 May 2008.
  4. ^ "The Tax Administration (Skatteetaten)". Ministry of Finance. Retrieved 24 November 2010.
  5. ^ "The Customs and Excise Authorities (Toll- og avgiftsetaten/Tollvesenet)". Ministry of Finance. Retrieved 24 November 2010.
  6. ^ "OECD.Stat Extracts Revenue Statistics - Comparative tables". OECD. Retrieved 24 June 2011.
  7. ^ "Selected Topics: Direct and indirect taxes". Ministry of Finance. Retrieved 24 November 2010.
  8. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n o p q "Main features of the Government's tax programme for 2011". Ministry of Finance. 5 October 2010.
  9. ^ Kleinbard, Edward D. (2010). "An American Dual Income Tax: Nordic Precedents". Northwestern Journal of Law and Social Policy. 5 (1). Northwestern University School of Law: 41–86. SSRN 1595079.
  10. ^ "Frikort". Skatteetaten (in Norwegian). Retrieved 25 November 2010.
  11. ^ "Prop. 1 LS (2010–2011) Skatter og avgifter 2011, 3.5 Endringer i kommunale og fylkeskommunale skattører og fellesskatt for 2011". Ministry of Finance (in Norwegian). 5 October 2010.
  12. ^ a b c d e Ministry of Finance. "The corporate tax system and taxation of capital income". Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  13. ^ "Press Release 81/2004 Tax Exemption for Companies' Income from Shares". Ministry of Finance. Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  14. ^ "Taxation of petroleum activities". Ministry of Finance. Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  15. ^ "Skatteloven §§ 18-1 to 18-8". Government.no (in Norwegian). Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  16. ^ "Stortingets skattevedtak 2010 § 3-4" (in Norwegian). www.lovdata.no. Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  17. ^ "Skatteloven §§ 8-10 til 8-20" (in Norwegian). www.lovdata.no. Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  18. ^ "Stortingets skattevedtak 2010 § 5-1" (in Norwegian). www.lovdata.no. Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  19. ^ "Eigedomsskattelova" (in Norwegian). www.lovdata.no. Retrieved 27 November 2010.
  20. ^ "Extended use of property tax in municipalities". Statistics Norway. www.ssb.no. 24 June 2010.
  21. ^ "Merverdiavgiftsloven §§ 6-21 to 6-33" (in Norwegian). www.lovdata.no. Retrieved 28 November 2010.
  22. ^ "Merverdiavgiftsloven §§ 6-1 to 6-20" (in Norwegian). www.lovdata.no. Retrieved 28 November 2010'. {{cite web}}: Check date values in: |accessdate= (help)
  23. ^ "Norwegian Customs Tariff: Information". www.toll.no. Retrieved 28 November 2010.
  24. ^ a b c Andersen, Per Sveaas (1977). Samlingen av Norge og kristningen av landet (in Norwegian). Oslo: Universitetsforlaget. ISBN 8200024121.
  25. ^ Danielsen, Rolf (1991). Grunntrekk i norsk historie (in Norwegian). Oslo: Universitetsforlaget. ISBN 8200212734.[page needed]
  26. ^ a b Dyrvik, Ståle (1990). Norsk økonomisk historie 1500-1970, Bind 1 1500–1850 (in Norwegian). Oslo: Universitetsforlaget. ISBN 8200019217.[page needed]
  27. ^ "NOU 2007: 8 En vurdering av særavgifter, kapittel 3". Government.no (in Norwegian).
  28. ^ Bagge, Sverre; Mykland, Knut (1996). Norge i dansketiden (in Norwegian). Cappelen. ISBN 8202123690.[page needed]
  29. ^ a b Gerdrup 1998, p. 11–3.
  30. ^ Gerdrup 1998, p. 16–7.
  31. ^ Gerdrup 1998, p. 17.
  32. ^ Gerdrup 1998, p. 18.
  33. ^ Gabrielsen 1992.

References

Further reading

"International Tax 2011 - Norway Highlights" (PDF). Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu. 2011.

"International Tax 2010 - Norway Highlights" (PDF). Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu. 2010.

"Tax Facts Norway 2010 - A survey of the Norwegian Tax System" (PDF). KPMG Law Advokatfirma DA. 2010.

"International Tax and Business Guide - Norway 2009" (PDF). Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu. 2009.

"Tax Facts Norway 2009 - A survey of the Norwegian Tax System" (PDF). KPMG Law Advokatfirma DA. 2009.