Content deleted Content added
m Repair or remove missing or deleted templates |
No edit summary |
||
(47 intermediate revisions by 29 users not shown) | |||
Line 16:
| j = tou<sup>2</sup> dei<sup>6</sup> goi<sup>2</sup> gaak<sup>3</sup> wan<sup>6</sup> dung<sup>6</sup>
}}
{{Mao Zedong series}}
{{history of the People's Republic of China}}
The '''Land Reform Movement''', also known by the Chinese abbreviation '''Tǔgǎi''' ({{lang|zh|土改}}), was a mass movement led by the [[Chinese Communist Party]] (CCP) leader [[Mao Zedong]] during the late phase of the [[Chinese Civil War]] after the [[Second Sino-Japanese War]] ended in 1945 and in the early [[People's Republic of China]],{{sfnp|Short|2001|pp=436–437}} which achieved [[Land reform|land redistribution]] to the [[peasantry]]. Landlords
By 1953, land reform had been completed in mainland China with the exception of [[Xinjiang]], [[Tibet]], [[Qinghai]], and [[Sichuan]]. From 1953 onwards, the CCP began to implement the collective ownership of expropriated land through the creation of Agricultural Production Cooperatives, transferring property rights of the seized land to the Chinese state. Farmers were compelled to join collective farms, which were grouped into [[people's communes]] with centrally controlled [[property rights]].{{sfnb|ChenDavis|1998}}
== Background ==
Land reform had historical antecedents in China. In the mid-19th century, the [[Taiping Rebellion]] had a short-lived program of [[Taiping Heavenly Kingdom#Policies|land confiscation and redistribution]] and after the [[
Numerous Communist Party cadre had also taken part in the non-Communist rural reform movement.{{sfnp|Heilmann|2018|p=61}}
Line 30 ⟶ 31:
As early as 1927, [[Mao Zedong]] believed that the countryside would be the basis of revolution.{{sfnp|Bradley|2015|pp=137–138}} Land reform was key for the CCP both to carry out its program of social equality and to extend its control to the countryside. Unlike in Russia before the revolution, peasants in imperial China were not in feudal bondage to large estates; they either owned their land or rented it. They marketed their crops for cash in village markets, but [[Chinese gentry|local elites]] used their connections with officialdom to dominate local society. When the central government began to lose control in the late 19th century and then disintegrated after 1911, the local gentry and clan organizations became even more powerful.{{sfnb|Mühlhahn|2019|p=402}} In addition to breaking the political control of traditional rural elites and pursuing Communist views of justice through land redistribution to the peasantry, the Communist Party's motivations also included an expectation that land reform would liberate the [[productive forces]] by channeling peasant labor into greater agricultural production and put surpluses to better use than rural elites' wasteful consumption.{{sfnp|Harrell|2023|p=105-107}}
Mao's 1927 ''[[Report on an Investigation of the Peasant Movement in Hunan]]'' advocated a strategy of mobilizing poor peasants to carry out
In a speech at the Second National Congress in 1934, Mao addressed the significance of land reform in the context of the struggle against the civil war against the Nationalists:<ref>{{Cite book |last=Coderre |first=Laurence |url= |title=Newborn Socialist Things: Materiality in Maoist China |date=2021 |publisher=[[Duke University Press]] |isbn=978-1-4780-2161-2 |location=Durham |pages=65 |oclc=1250021710}}</ref>
{{
=== Prior Communist Party campaigns ===
In the 1920s, the Communist Party began experimenting with land reform.{{sfn|Harrell|2023|p=104}} The CCP launched various rural campaigns as precursors to the land reform movement.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=137}} These mass campaigns adjusted rent and interest to be more favorable to tenants, returned excessive deposits to renters, and overall served to weaken the traditional rural elites.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=137}}
==== In Minxi ====
In 1928, [[Deng Zihui]] began land reform experiments in Minxi.{{sfnp|Heilmann|2018|p=48}}
By 1930, the experiments with land reform in Minxi had been widely disseminated in Communist Party publications and became an important point of reference for the [[Jiangxi–Fujian Soviet|Jiangxi Soviet]]'s land policies from 1931 to 1934.{{sfnp|Heilmann|2018|p=48}}
==== In the Chinese Soviet Republic ====
In the [[Chinese Soviet Republic]] (CSR), the CCP issued the 1931 Land Law of the Chinese Soviet Republic.{{sfnp|Opper|2020|p=37}} It required:{{sfnp|Opper|2020|p=37}}
{{Blockquote|text=All lands belonging feudal landlords, local bullies and evil gentry, warlords, bureaucrats, and other large private landlords, irrespective of whether they work the lands themselves or rent them out, shall be confiscated without compensation. The confiscated lands shall be redistributed to the poor and middle peasants through the [CSR]. The former owners of the confiscated lands shall not be entitled to receive any land allotments.}}
The property of rich peasants was also confiscated, although rich peasants were entitled to receive land of lesser quality if they farmed it themselves.{{sfnp|Opper|2020|p=37}} By 1932, the CCP had equalized landholding and eliminated debt within the CSR.{{sfnp|Opper|2020|p=44}}
Although the 1931 Land Law remained the official policy in the CSR's territory until the Nationalists' defeat of the CSR in 1934,{{sfnp|Opper|2020|p=37}} the CCP was more radical in its class analysis after 1932, resulting in formerly middle peasants being viewed as rich peasants.{{sfnp|Opper|2020|pp=44–46}}
Line 59 ⟶ 60:
China's land reform was not only an economic or administrative process of taking and redistributing deeds or legal ownership of land.<ref name=":1">{{Cite book |last=Ching |first=Pao-Yu |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/1325647379 |title=Revolution and counterrevolution : China's continuing class struggle since liberation |date=2021 |publisher=Foreign languages press |isbn=978-2-491182-89-2 |edition=2nd |location=Paris |pages=185 |oclc=1325647379}}</ref> It was a party-led mass movement which turned peasants into active participants and which pushed for political and ideological change beyond the immediate economic question of land ownership.<ref name=":1" />{{sfnp|Short|2001|pp=436–437}} Land reform issues were also a matter of debate within the CCP, and leaders disagreed over such questions as the level of violence which was to be used; whether to woo or target middle peasants, who farmed most of the land; or to redistribute all of the land to poor peasants.{{sfnb|DeMare|2019|pp= 6–17}}
Land reform progressed unevenly by region{{sfnp|Karl|2010|pp=80–81}} and in different time periods.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|pp=166-168}} In northern China, which had been governed by Communists since 1935, the peasants were more radical.{{sfnp|Karl|2010|pp=80–81}} [[Cadre system of the Chinese Communist Party|CCP cadre]] in these regions often tried to restrain excessive violence from peasants.{{sfnp|Karl|2010|pp=80–81}} Land reform was undertaken more quickly and more violently in the north.{{sfnp|Karl|2010|pp=80–81}} In the south,
Landlords were subjected to public
Rural women had a significant impact on the movement, with the Communist Party making specific efforts to mobilize them. Party activists observed that because peasant women were less tied to old power structures, that they more readily opposed those identified as class enemies. In 1947, [[Deng Yingchao]] emphasized at a land reform policy meeting that "women function as great mobilizers when they speak bitterness."{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|pp=62–63}} The [[All-China Women's Federation]] called for Party activists to encourage peasant women to understand their "special bitterness" from a class perspective. Women activists helped peasant women prepare to speak in public, including by roleplaying as landlords to help such women practice.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=63}} Because land reform resulted in allocations of land titles on the basis of adult household members, rather than on the basis of households (which typically had male heads of household), the economic independence of peasant women increased.{{Sfn|Hammond|2023|p=40}}
From 1950 to 1952, the land reform movement was extended to all [[Han Chinese|Han]] agricultural areas and some of the [[Ethnic minorities in China|ethnic minority]] areas which had intensive agricultural production or had land ownership practices similar that of Han areas.{{Sfn|Harrell|2023}} By 1952, land redistribution was generally completed. Most landlords had been permitted to retain plots of land after admitting to historical crimes, although many had been killed. The amount of cultivated land had grown, along with related infrastructure projects and availability of fertilizers and insecticides.{{sfnp|Karl|2010|pp=80–81}} By 1952, rural agriculture had become hugely more productive in China.{{sfnp|Karl|2010|p=82}}
In certain minority group areas of China's [[Central Asia
=== Chinese civil war era campaigns (1946–1948) ===
Following Japan's surrender in the [[Second Sino-Japanese War]], land reform campaigns
Throughout the land reform campaigns of the Civil War era, trends towards violent struggle against landlords coincided with increased combat in the war; when Nationalist forces or homecoming regiments were present, land reform and Civil War violence overlapped.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=111}}
At the outbreak of the Civil War in 1946, Mao began to push for a return to radical policies to mobilize the village against the landlord class, but protected the rights of middle peasants and specified that rich peasants were not landlords.{{sfnb|DeMare|2019|p=10-11}}
On May 4, 1946, the [[Central Committee of the Chinese Communist Party]] issued its ''Instructions on Land Issues''.{{sfnp|Huang|2020|pp=249–250}} The May 4th Instructions (also referred to as the May 4th Directive){{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=167}} required local party committees to support landlords who approved of land acquisition by the peasantry.{{sfnp|Huang|2020|p=250}} As part of an effort to address some concerns of some landowners and those connected to them, the May 4th Instructions stated that landlords who
The May 4th Instructions provided significant leeway for differing regional and local interpretations.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=84}} In villages where land reform was occurring for the first time, the East China Bureau allowed small and medium landlords to donate land; those who did were allowed to keep more than the average middle peasant.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=84}} The Northeast Bureau took a similar approach, even allowing most peasants who had served the Japanese [[Manchukuo regime]] to apologize and retain their land.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=84}} In the Shanxi-Chahar-Hebei Border Region, instructions for implementing the May 4th Directive stated that the intent was to achieve land to the tiller rather than equal redistribution.{{sfnp|Opper|2020|p=137}} In contrast to these approaches, the Central China Bureau moved more steadily towards land equalization.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|pp=84–85}}
Line 84 ⟶ 85:
The July 7 Directive of 1946 set off eighteen months of fierce conflict in which all rich peasant and landlord property of all types was to be confiscated and redistributed to poor peasants. Party work teams (''gongzuodui'') were the primary instrument of land reform{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=33}} and went from village to village and divided the population into landlords, rich, middle, poor, and landless peasants. Because the work teams did not involve villagers in the process, rich and middle peasants quickly returned to power.{{sfnb|Tanner|2015| pp = 134–135}}
From July to September 1947, the Communist Party held a National Land Conference to formulate the Outline of the Chinese Land Law.{{sfnp|Huang|2020|p=250}} Issued in October 1947, the Outline identified the goal of "[t]he abolition of feudal and semi-feudal exploitation of the land system and the implementation of the cultivator owning the field."{{sfnp|Huang|2020|p=532}} The Outline Land Law codified confiscation of land from rich peasants.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=86}} According to [[William H. Hinton]], who observed later parts of the campaign, it "played as important a role as the Emancipation Proclamation in the American Civil War
Late 1947 directives from the CCP called for more lenient treatment for allies among the rural elite in established base areas whom the party viewed as sufficiently enlightened.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=112}} The CCP instructed work teams and cadres not to dampen the enthusiasm of the peasant masses, but also to convince activists to minimize beatings and to oppose spontaneous executions.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=112}}
The CCP sent the work teams back to the villages to put poor and landless peasants in charge, mandating the elimination of land rent, which it compared to feudal exploitation, and the elimination of landlord status. In one village in southern Hebei, foreign observers recorded that four people were stoned to death,{{sfnb|CrookCrook|1979|p
Land reform movement violence surged in early 1948, prompting some CCP leaders such as [[Xi Zhongxun]] and [[Ren Bishi]] to criticize the movement.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=113}} Ren announced a policy shift in January 1948, guaranteeing that targets of the movement would nonetheless be allowed to keep a share of property.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=114}} This policy change contributed to a shift away from economic struggle and to political struggle.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=114}} Mao's January 18, 1948 directive, ''On Some Important Problems of the Party's Present Policy
In June 1948, concluding that most peasants were satisfied with the land they had received and that some were even concerned about further mass land reform campaigns because of their radical turns in the past, the Communist Party ended land reform in the Shanxi-Chahar-Hebei Border Region and
Land reform was a decisive factor in the result of the [[Chinese Civil War]].<ref name=":7">{{Cite book |last=Lin |first=Chun |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/63178961 |title=The transformation of Chinese socialism |date=2006 |publisher=[[Duke University Press]] |isbn=978-0-8223-3785-0 |location=Durham [N.C.] |pages=43 |oclc=63178961}}</ref> At the time of the CCP victory, more than half of the population living in Communist areas had participated in land reform and over 25 million hectares of land had been redistributed, largely as a result of confiscations form landlords and rich peasants.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=18}} Millions of peasants who obtained land through the movement joined the [[People's Liberation Army]] or assisted in its logistical networks.<ref name=":7" /> According to academic Brian DeMare, land redistribution was a critical factor in the CCP military success in the civil war because land reforms linked the interests of north and northeast Chinese peasants to the party's success.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=18}} The success of land reform meant that at the founding of the PRC in 1949, China could credibly claim that for the first time since the late [[Qing dynasty|Qing]] period that it had succeeded in feeding one fifth of the world's population with only 7% of the world's cultivable land.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Lin |first=Chun |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/63178961 |title=The transformation of Chinese socialism |date=2006 |publisher=[[Duke University Press]] |isbn=978-0-8223-3785-0 |location=Durham [N.C.] |pages=44 |oclc=63178961}}</ref>
=== Early People's Republic of China campaigns (1949–1953) ===
The Land Reform Movement continued during
In this period, the CCP's view was that fewer targets were necessary
However, the [[Korean War]] prompted
In the early PRC era, there were millions of war widows.<ref name=":8">{{Cite book |last=Lary |first=Diana |url= |title=China's grandmothers
During the early PRC land reform, the folk artists and culture workers were a significant medium for
== Mass killings of landlords<!--'Mass killings of landlords under Mao Zedong' redirects here--> ==
{{Infobox civilian attack
| title = Destruction of the Chinese landlord class (1949–1953)
Line 115 ⟶ 116:
| map =
| map_caption =
| location =
| date =
| type = [[Massacre]], [[classicide]]
| fatalities = 200,000 – 5,000,000
| injuries = 1.5{{sfnp|Short|2001|p=436}}–6<ref name="Valentino"/> up to 12.5<ref name="
| victims = Landlords,
| perps = [[Chinese Communist Party]] and radicalized peasants
| motive = [[Maoism]], [[economic inequality]], [[class struggle]]
}}
Victims were targeted based on
Mao's 1927 "[[Report on an Investigation of the Peasant Movement in Hunan]]" addressed CCP members who were concerned with violence by the peasants against landlords, arguing that these concerns were a tool for continuing the oppression of the peasants. In this context, Mao coined his famous comment that "[[revolution is not a dinner party]]." Mao wrote in response to objections to violence:{{sfnp|Karl|2010|p=31}}
{{Blockquote|text=It is fine. It is not "terrible" at all. It is anything but "terrible." ... "It's terrible!" is
The CCP's tolerance of, encouragement of, or efforts to restrain, violence by peasants against landlords in the course of the land reform movement varied over time and location.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|pp=105–118}} Its directions were not always followed, and as late as the final rounds of land reform in the early 1950s, the future reformer [[Hu Yaobang]] had to explain that the call to "annihilate" the landlord class meant taking landlord property not landlord lives.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=118}}
There were reports of policies that required the public execution of at least one landlord, and usually several, in virtually every village.<ref name="Teiwes" /> An official reported 180 to 190 thousand landlords were executed in the [[Guangxi]] province alone, in addition, a Catholic school teacher reported 2.5% of his village was executed.<ref name=" === Estimated number of deaths ===
Line 137 ⟶ 140:
Estimates for the number of deaths from 1949 to 1953 vary widely, with a total range of 200,000 to 5,000,000, which historian [[John King Fairbank]] called the upper end of "sober" estimates.<ref name=Mosher1992 /> It is difficult to separate killings due to land reform from killings due to the [[Campaign to Suppress Counterrevolutionaries]] (zhenfan), which occurred during the same years. As a result, most estimates below include deaths from both land reform and zhenfan:
* In 1978, historian Benedict Stavis estimated that 200,000 to 800,000 were killed during land reform, part of an estimated 400,000 to 800,000 killed during land reform and zhenfan.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Stavis |first1=Benedict |url=https://archive.org/details/politicsofagricu0000stav/page/n5/mode/2up |title=The Politics of Agricultural Mechanization in China |date=1978 |publisher=Cornell University Press
* In 2006, historian [[J. A. G. Roberts]] wrote that estimates range from 200,000 to 2,000,000 for those killed during land reform.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Roberts |first1=J. A. G. |author-link1=J. A. G. Roberts |date=2006 |title=A History of China |url=https://archive.org/details/historyofchina0000robe_u3x9 |publisher=[[Palgrave Macmillan]] |page=257 |isbn=978-1-4039-9275-8|quote=Estimates of the number of landlords and rural power-holders who died range from 200,000 to two million.}}</ref>
* In 1954, Xu Zirong, the Deputy Public Security Minister, published a report concluding that, during zhenfan, "712,000 counter-revolutionaries were executed, 1,290,000 were imprisoned, and 1,200,000 were subject to control at various times", for a total of 2,620,000 arrested. In 2008, historian [[Yang Kuisong]] argued that "the actual number of executions was much larger than the reported 712,000" because local officials concealed executions after Mao mildly criticized excessive killing in 1951.<ref name="
* In 1957,
* Some time before 1961, then-[[Premier of the People's Republic of China|Premier]] [[Zhou Enlai]] told sympathetic journalist [[Edgar Snow]] that 830,000 "enemies of the people" had been "destroyed" before 1954, during land reform and zhenfan.<ref>{{cite book |title=Red China Today: The Other Side of the River |page=346 |first1=Edgar |last1=Snow |authorlink1=Edgar Snow |year=1961 |publisher=New York, [[Random House]] |isbn=9780394716817 |url=https://archive.org/details/redchinatoday00edga |quote=There was Chou En-lai's [Zhou Enlai's] statement several years ago that 830,000 "enemies of the people" had been "destroyed" during the war over land confiscation, mass trials of landlords, and the subsequent roundup of counterrevolutionaries which ended, as a "campaign," in 1954. (Incidentally, the term hsiao-mieh, usually translated as "destroyed," literally means "reduced," "dispersed" or "obliterated," but not necessarily physically liquidated.)}}</ref>
* In 1987, historians [[Denis Twitchett|Twitchett]], [[John King Fairbank|Fairbank]], and [[Roderick MacFarquhar|MacFarquhar]] estimated that 1,000,000 to 2,000,000 were executed in the land reform movement.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Twitchett |first1=Denis |author-link1=Denis Twitchett |first2=John |last2=Fairbank |author-link2=John King Fairbank |first3=Roderick |last3=MacFarquhar |author-link3=Roderick MacFarquhar |title=The Cambridge History of China: Volume 14: The People's Republic, Part I: The Emergency of Revolutionary China 1949-1965 |publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]] |isbn=0-521-24336-X |page=87 |url=https://
* In 1999, historian [[Maurice Meisner]] estimated that 2,000,000 people were executed from in China from 1950 to 1952, including both land reform and zhenfan.<ref name="Mao 1999">{{cite book|author-link1=Maurice Meisner |first1=Maurice |last1=Meisner |title=Mao's China and After: A History of the People's Republic, Third Edition |publisher=Free Press |year=1999 |isbn=0-684-85635-2 |page=72 |quote=In a speech delivered in 1957, Zhou Enlai stated that among an unspecified number of counterrevolutionary cases officially handled by the government through 1952, 16.8 percent were sentenced to death, 42.3 percent to "reform through labor," 32 percent placed under
* In 1992, social scientist [[Steven W. Mosher]] estimated that
* In 2002, historian [[Lee Feigon]] wrote that "somewhere between 2,000,000 and 5,000,000 landlords had been killed".<ref name="feig">Lee Feigon. ''Mao: A Reinterpretation.'' Ivan R. Dee, 2002. {{ISBN|1-56663-522-5}} p. 96: "By 1952 they had extended land reform throughout the countryside, but in the process somewhere between two and five million landlords had been killed."</ref>
* [[Deng Zihui]], Vice Chairman of the Central South Military and Administrative Council, estimated that 15% of China's 50,000,000 landlords and rich peasants had been
* In 1952, the [[Free Trade Union Committee]] of the [[AFL-CIO]], which was funded in whole or part by the [[CIA]], released a report allegedly compiled by Wei Min of the
In addition, during this period, 1.5 million{{sfnp|Short|2001|p=436}} to 6 million<ref name="Valentino">Benjamin A. Valentino. ''[https://books.google.com/books?id=LQfeXVU_EvgC&dq=four+million+to+six+million+forced+labor&pg=PA121 Final Solutions: Mass Killing and Genocide in the Twentieth Century] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190220225307/https://books.google.com/books?id=LQfeXVU_EvgC&pg=PA121&dq=four+million+to+six+million+forced+labor#v=onepage&q=four%20million%20to%20six%20million%20forced%20labor&f=false |date=2019-02-20}}'' [[Cornell University Press]], 2004. pp. 121–122. {{ISBN|0-8014-3965-5}}</ref> people were sent to
Philip Short argues that these estimates exclude hundreds of thousands driven to suicide during
=== Retaliation by landlords ===
During the Chinese Civil War, the [[Kuomintang]] established the
The Homecoming
==Land redistribution==
Land seized from
{| class="wikitable" style="text-align:right"
|+ Ownership of cultivable land before reform in mainland China<ref name="建国三十年全国农业统计资料">
! Classification !! Number of households<br>(10,000) !! Proportion of households
|-
! Poor
| 6062 || 57.44 || 24123 || 52.37 || 21503 || 14.28 || 3.55 || 0.89
|-
! Middle
| 3081 || 29.20 || 15260 || 33.13 || 46577 || 30.94 || 15.12 || 3.05
|-
! Rich
| 325 || 3.08 || 2144 || 4.66 || 20566 || 13.66 || 63.24 || 9.59
|-
! Landlords
| 400 || 3.79 || 2188 || 4.75 || 57588 || 38.26 || 144.11 || 26.32
|-
! Other
| 686 || 6.49 || 2344 || 5.09 || 4300 || 2.86 || 6.27 || 1.83
|-
! Total
| 10554 || 100.00 || 46059 || 100.00 || 150534 || 100.00 || 14.26 || 3.27
|}
{| class="wikitable" style="text-align:right"
|+ Ownership of cultivable land after reform in mainland China<ref name="建国三十年全国农业统计资料"/>{{efn|1=The number of households was calculated based on the survey data of
! Classification !! Number of households<br>(%) !! Population<br>(%) !! Cultivated land<br>(%) !! Per capita cultivated land<br>(mu) !! Large livestock<br>(
|-
! Poor
| 54.5 || 52.2 || 47.1 || 12.5 || 46.73
|-
! Middle
| 39.3 || 39.9 || 44.3 || 19.0 || 90.93
|-
! Rich
| 3.1 || 5.3 || 6.4 || 25.1 || 114.86
|-
! Landlords
| 2.4 || 2.6 || 2.2 || 12.2 || 23.19
|-
! Other
| 0.7 ||
|-
! Total
| 100.00 || 100.00 || 100.00 || 15.3 || 64.01
|}
=== Economic effects ===
[[
Although land reform is an important social revolution, it has come at a great cost, causing significant rifts and internal strife within rural communities. According to surveys<ref>{{Cite web |title=两种思路的碰撞与历史的沉思——1950-1952年关于农业合作化目标模式的选择 |url=https://ccrs.ccnu.edu.cn/List/H5Details.aspx?tid=4874 |access-date=2024-06-03 |website=ccrs.ccnu.edu.cn}}</ref> conducted in 23 villages in [[Hebei]] and [[Chahar Province|Chahar]], the speed of transition from poor tenant farmers to middle farmers was rapid after land reform. However, the transition from middle farmers to wealthy middle farmers was slower, and the number of those who became wealthy farmers remains limited. In a survey of five villages in [[Shanxi]], 34% of households that experienced a decline still had concerns and were hesitant to engage in active production due to the heavy burden of land reform. Additionally, 56% cited reasons such as illness, laziness, livestock deaths, and lack of labor, while 10% lacked the skills to manage their land. As a result, nearly half of the poor farmers who had risen in status later regressed, indicating that even after acquiring land, they still felt empty and lacked the means of production, making them vulnerable to any setbacks. The main issue remains the concerns of the masses and the lack of funds to expand reproduction. In the Northeast region, land reform did not lead to an expansion of productivity; instead, there was a shrinkage.<ref>{{Cite web |title=高王凌:土地改革──"改天换地"的社会变动_爱思想 |url=https://www.aisixiang.com/data/16705.html |access-date=2024-06-03 |website=www.aisixiang.com}}</ref> Reasons for this included the large number of landlords and wealthy farmers, as well as the fragmented distribution of land leading to a lack of experience in organizing and managing farms.
As an economic reform program, the land reform succeeded in redistributing about 43% of China's cultivated land to approximately 60% of the rural population. Poor peasants increased their holdings, while middle peasants benefitted most because of their strong initial position.<ref name="Teiwes"/> The movement expropriated land from over ten million landlords.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=141}} Historian [[Walter Scheidel]] writes that the violence of the land reform campaign had a significant impact in reducing [[economic inequality]]. He gives as an example the 1940s campaigns in [[Lucheng District, Changzhi|Zhangzhuangcun]], a village made famous as "Long Bow" by William Hinton's book ''[[Fanshen]]''. Although poor and middle peasants had already owned 70% of the land: <blockquote>In Zhangzhuangcun, in the more thoroughly reformed north of the country, most "landlords" and "rich peasants" had lost all their land and often their lives or had fled. All formerly landless workers had received land, which eliminated this category altogether. As a result, "middling peasants," who now accounted for 90 percent of the village population, owned 90.8 percent of the land, as close to perfect equality as one could possibly hope for.<ref name=Scheidel226>{{cite book | last1 =Scheidel | first1 =Walter | author-link =Walter Scheidel | title =The Great Leveler: Violence and the History of Inequality from the Stone Age to the Twenty-First Century | publisher =[[Princeton University Press]] | year =2017 | isbn =978-0-691-16502-8 | pages =223, 226 | access-date =|url =https://books.google.com/books?id=CD1hDwAAQBAJ&q=Zhangzhuangcun| archive-date =| url-status =}}</ref>▼
</blockquote>Academic Brian DeMare states, "In the aftermath of land reform and the redistribution of village fields, many peasants indeed prospered. The turn from rural revolution to regular agricultural production generally resulted in increasing harvests and rising incomes. Besides the obvious benefit of the end of decades of warfare and chaos, the enthusiasm of new land owners drove production."{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=146}}▼
Land reform not only altered the basic relationships in rural areas but also influenced subsequent political and economic developments, prompting China to face a new round of social restructuring and grassroots reorganization. The core of land reform lies in implementing equal land rights, whereby land and property are forcibly pooled and evenly distributed, aiming to optimize the integration of labor and land, thus enhancing economic efficiency. However, after equal land rights were implemented, although land circulation achieved optimal allocation of land and labor, there was soon a phenomenon of land concentration in the hands of expert farmers, leading to a change in the initial equal status. To ensure that this equal status is not altered, the only solution is to restrict land transactions and strip land ownership, thereby preventing land from concentrating in the hands of a few. Additionally, to promote improved economic efficiency, it is necessary to promote scale-oriented operations through mutual aid groups and [[people's commune]], reducing the problem of individual farmers' limited risk-bearing capacity. However, despite farmers gaining land ownership after land reform, there is a free-rider phenomenon in collective labor, lacking incentive mechanisms, resulting in a lack of production enthusiasm among farmers. Therefore, land reform needs to comprehensively consider factors such as land ownership, collective labor, and production enthusiasm to promote the sustainable development of rural economy.<ref>{{Cite web |title=龙登高:百年中国土地制度变革及其启示-清华大学华商研究中心 |url=http://www.cces.tsinghua.edu.cn/info/1027/1090.htm |access-date=2024-06-03 |website=www.cces.tsinghua.edu.cn}}</ref>
▲As an economic reform program, the land reform succeeded in redistributing about 43% of China's cultivated land to approximately 60% of the rural population. Poor peasants increased their holdings, while middle peasants benefitted most because of their strong initial position.<ref name="Teiwes" /> The movement expropriated land from over ten million landlords.{{sfnp|DeMare|2019|p=141}} Historian [[Walter Scheidel]] writes that the violence of the land reform campaign had a significant impact in reducing [[economic inequality]]. He gives as an example the 1940s campaigns in [[Lucheng District, Changzhi|Zhangzhuangcun]], a village
</blockquote>
▲
In the [[Second Kuomintang-Communist Civil War]], especially during the [[Liaoshen campaign|Liaoshen]], [[Huaihai campaign|Huaihai]], and [[Pingjin campaign|Pingjin Campaigns]], farmers actively supported the war effort by providing a large amount of resources. They supplied numerous stretchers, carts, livestock, and grain, offering solid support for the [[People's Liberation Army|Chinese People's Liberation Army]]'s operations. In addition to collecting grain and taxes, the Communist Party's grassroots rural governance demonstrated strong mobilization capabilities. During the War, farmers in some areas were mobilized to participate in wartime tasks such as dismantling railways and transporting wounded soldiers. Both laborers and militia actively engaged in tasks such as transporting grain, military supplies, rescuing wounded soldiers, and guarding prisoners, meeting the needs of the troops. During the three major campaigns, 8.57 million laborers performed various logistical tasks, while militia from farmer organizations participated in numerous battles, effectively striking at the enemy. These abundant human resources provided essential conditions for the rapid advancement and victory of the Liberation War.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=凯峰 |first=张 |date=2004-09-30 |title=土地改革與中國農村政權 |url=https://www.cuhk.edu.hk/ics/21c/media/online/0406062.pdf |journal=二十一世紀}}</ref>
Generally, agricultural production increased the most in areas and time periods when landlord wealth was redistributed but the rich peasant economy had been allowed to remain.{{sfnp|Harrell|2023|p=109}}
== See also ==
* [[History of agriculture in China]]
* [[Agriculture in Taiwan]]
* [[Land reform in Taiwan]]
* [[Criticism of communist party rule]]
* [[Dekulakization]]
* [[History of the Chinese Communist Party]]
* [[History of the People's Republic of China]]
* [[Land reform by country]]
* [[List of
* [[List of massacres in China]]
* [[Mass killings under communist regimes]]
Line 229 ⟶ 244:
{{reflist}}
== Bibliography ==
* {{Cite book |last=Bradley |first=James |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/870199580 |title=The China mirage
* {{cite journal| url =http://www.fao.org/3/x1372t/x1372t10.htm |title = Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s| author1-first = Fu |author1-last = Chen|author2-first = John |author2-last = Davis|publisher = Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations| year = 1998|journal = Land Reform}}
* {{cite book|last1 = Crook|first1 = Isabel|first2 = David|last2 = Crook|year = 1979|title = Ten Mile Inn: Mass Movement in a Chinese Village|publisher = Pantheon Books|location = New York|isbn = 0-394-41178-1|url-access = registration|url = https://archive.org/details/tenmileinnmassmo0000croo}}
* {{cite book |last1 = DeMare |first1=Brian James |year = 2019 |title = Land Wars: The Story of China's Agrarian Revolution |publisher = Stanford University Press| location = Palo Alto, CA |isbn = 978-1-5036-0952-5}}
* {{cite book |last=Harrell |first=Stevan |title=An Ecological History of Modern China |publisher=[[University of Washington Press]] |year=2023 |isbn=9780295751719}}
* {{cite book |last=Hammond |first=Ken |date=2023 |title=China's Revolution and the Quest for a Socialist Future |publisher=1804 Books |isbn=9781736850084}}
* {{cite book |last=Heilmann |first=Sebastian |author-link=Sebastian Heilmann |year=2018 |title=Red Swan: How Unorthodox Policy-Making Facilitated China's Rise |location=Hong Kong |publisher=[[Chinese University Press of Hong Kong]] |isbn=978-962-996-827-4}} * {{cite book |last1=Hinton |first1=William |year=1966 |title=Fanshen: A Documentary of Revolution in a Chinese Village |url=https://archive.org/details/fanshendocumentahintrich|url-access=registration |publisher=Monthly Review Press |location=New York}}
* {{Cite book |last=Huang |first=Yibing |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/1165409653 |title=An ideological history of the Communist Party of China |date=2020 |others=Qian Zheng, Guoyou Wu, Xuemei Ding, Li Sun, Shelly Bryant |isbn=978-1-4878-0425-1 |edition= |volume=I |location=Montreal, Quebec |publisher=Royal Collins Publishing Group |oclc=1165409653}}
* {{Cite book |last=Karl |first=Rebecca E. |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/503828045 |title=Mao Zedong and China in the twentieth-century world : a concise history |date=2010 |publisher=[[Duke University Press]] |isbn=978-0-8223-4780-4 |location=Durham [NC] |oclc=503828045}}
* {{cite book |last1 = Li |first1 = Huaiyin |year = 2011 |title = Village China under Socialism and Reform : A Micro History, 1948-2008 |publisher = Stanford University Press| location = Stanford, Calif.|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=Re4YLsESWjoC |isbn = 978-0-8047-7657-8}}
* {{cite book |last=Margolin |first=Jean-Louis |editor-last1=Stone |editor-first1=Dan |title=The Historiography of Genocide |date=13 February 2008 |publisher=Springer |isbn=978-0-230-29778-4 |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=NzIWDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA438 |language=en |chapter=Mao's China: The Worst Non-Genocidal Regime?}}
* {{cite book |last1 = Moise |first1 = Edwin E. |year = 1983 |title = Land Reform in China and North Vietnam : Consolidating the Revolution at the Village Level |publisher = University of North Carolina Press| location = Chapel Hill |isbn = 9780807874455 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=lAg1DgAAQBAJ&q=moise+land+reform}}
* {{cite book |last1 = Mühlhahn |first1 = Klaus|year = 2019 |title = Making China Modern: From the Great Qing to Xi Jinping |publisher = Harvard University Press| location = Cambridge, Massachusetts|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=uxN-DwAAQBAJ&pg=PP1 |isbn = 978-0-674-73735-8}}
* {{Cite book |last=Opper |first=Marc |title=People's Wars in China, Malaya, and Vietnam |date=2020 |publisher=[[University of Michigan Press]] |isbn=978-0-472-90125-8 |location=Ann Arbor |pages= |doi=10.3998/mpub.11413902 |jstor=10.3998/mpub.11413902|hdl=20.500.12657/23824 |s2cid=211359950 |url=http://library.oapen.org/handle/20.500.12657/23824 }}
* {{cite book|last1=Short|first1=Philip|title=Mao: A Life|publisher=Owl Books|year=2001|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=HQwoTtJ43_AC&pg=PA436|isbn=0-8050-6638-1}}
* {{cite book |last1 = Shue |first1=Vivienne |year = 1980 |title = Peasant China in Transition: The Dynamics of Development toward Socialism, 1949-1956 |publisher = University of California Press| location = Berkeley, CA|url=https://archive.org/details/peasantchinaintr0000shue |url-access = registration |isbn = 978-0-520-03734-2|ref = none}}
Line 268 ⟶ 284:
[[Category:Mass murder in 1951]]
[[Category:1950s murders in China]]
[[Category:1940s murders in China]]
[[Category:1947 murders in China]]
[[Category:1951 murders in China]]
Line 274 ⟶ 290:
[[Category:Mao Zedong]]
[[Category:Land reform]]
[[Category:
[[Category:Massacres committed by the People's Republic of China]]
|