Sherman Antitrust Act: Difference between revisions

Content deleted Content added
m added house
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile app edit iOS app edit
ALLCAPS #article-section-source-editor
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile app edit iOS app edit
 
(33 intermediate revisions by 23 users not shown)
Line 5:
| shorttitle = Sherman Antitrust Act
| othershorttitles =
| longtitle = An Act to Protectprotect Tradetrade and Commercecommerce Againstagainst Unlawfulunlawful Restraintsrestraints and Monopoliesmonopolies
| colloquialacronym =
| nickname =
Line 11:
| effective date =
| public law url =
| cite public law = {{uspl|51|647}}<!--{{uspl}} can be used-->
| cite statutes at large = {{usstat|26|209}}
| acts amended =
| acts repealed =
| title amended = <!--US[[Title code15 titlesof changed-->the United States Code|Title 15—Commerce and Trade]]
| sections created = <!--{{USCusc|15|1|7}} can be used-->
| sections amended =
| leghisturl =
Line 25:
| committees =
| passedbody1 = Senate
| passeddate1 = April 8, 1890
| passedvote1 = 52–1
| passedbody2 = House
| passedas2 = <!-- used if the second body changes the name of the legislation -->
| passeddate2 = June 20, 1890
| passedvote2 = unanimous vote
| conferencedate =
| passedbody3 =
Line 47:
| signeddate = July 2, 1890
| amendments =
| SCOTUS cases = {{Collapsible list|framestyle=line-height:1em|''[[United States v. E.C. Knight Co.]]'', {{ussc|156|1|1894}}|''[[United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Association]]'', {{ussc|166|290|1897}}|''[[Northern Securities Co. v. United States]]'', {{ussc|193|197|1904}}|''[[Hale v. Henkel]]'', {{ussc|201|43|1906}}|''[[Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co.]]'', {{ussc|220|373|1911}}|''[[Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United States]]'', {{ussc|221|1|1911}}|''[[United States v. American Tobacco Co.]]'', {{ussc|221|106|1911}}|''[[Federal Baseball Club v. National League]]'', {{ussc|259|200|1922}}|''[[Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader]]'', {{ussc|310|469|1940}}|''[[United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc.]]'', {{ussc|334|131|1948}}|''[[United States v. National City Lines]]'', {{ussc|334|573|1948}}|''[[Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Seagram & Sons, Inc.]]'', {{ussc|340|211|1951}}|''[[Lorain Journal Co. v. United States]]'', {{ussc|342|143|1951}}|''[[Continental Television, Inc. v. GTE Sylvania, Inc.]]'', {{ussc|433|36|1977}}|''[[Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society]]'', {{ussc|457|332|1982}}|''[[Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde]]'', {{ussc|466|2|1984}}|''[[Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.]]'', {{ussc|467|752|1984}}|''[[Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan]]'', {{ussc|506|447|1993}}|''[[Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc.]]'', {{ussc|551|877|2007}}|''[[Pacific Bell Telephone Co. v. linkLine Communications, Inc.]]'', {{ussc|555|438|2009}}|''[[American Needle, Inc. v. National Football League]]'', {{ussc|560|183|2010}}|''[[North Carolina Bd. of Dental Examiners v. FTC]]'', {{ussc|574|494|2015}}|''[[Ohio v. American Express Co.]]'', {{ussc|docket=16-1454|volume=585|year=2018}}|''[[National Collegiate Athletic Assn. v. Alston]]'', {{ussc|docket=20-512|volume=594|year=2021}}}}
}}
 
[[File:John-Sherman-2.jpg|thumb|upright|[[United States Senate|Sen.]] [[John Sherman]] ([[Republican Party (United States)|R]]–[[List of United States Senators from Ohio|Ohio]]), the principal author of the Sherman Antitrust Act]]
{{Competition law}}
 
The '''Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890'''<ref>Officially re-designated as the "Sherman Act" by Congress in the [[Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act|Hart–Scott–Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976]], (Public Law 94-435, Title 3, Sec. 305(a), 90 Stat. 1383 at [[s:Page:United States Statutes at Large Volume 90 Part 1.djvu/1447|p. 1397]]).</ref> ({{USStat|26|209}}, {{usc|15|1|7}}) is a [[United States antitrust law]] which prescribes the rule of free competition among those engaged in commerce and consequently prohibits unfair [[Monopoly|monopolies]]. It was passed by [[United States Congress|Congress]] and is named for Senator [[John Sherman]], its principal author.
 
The Sherman Act broadly prohibits 1) anticompetitive agreements and 2) unilateral conduct that monopolizes or attempts to monopolize the relevant market. The Act authorizes the [[United States Department of Justice|Department of Justice]] to bring [[Lawsuit|suits]] to [[enjoin]] (i.e. prohibit) conduct violating the Act, and additionally authorizes private parties injured by conduct violating the Act to bring suits for [[treble damages]] (i.e. three times as much money in damages as the violation cost them). Over time, the federal courts have developed a body of law under the Sherman Act making certain types of anticompetitive conduct per se illegal, and subjecting other types of conduct to case-by-case analysis regarding whether the conduct unreasonably restrains trade.
 
The law attempts to prevent the artificial raising of prices by restriction of trade or supply.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://butnowyouknow.net/those-who-fail-to-learn-from-history/sherman-anti-trust-act-and-analysis/|title=Sherman AntiTrust Act, and Analysis|date=12 March 2011|url-status=live|archive-url=http://archive.wikiwix.com/cache/20111118040849/http://butnowyouknow.net/those-who-fail-to-learn-from-history/sherman-anti-trust-act-and-analysis/|archive-date=18 November 2011}}</ref> "Innocent monopoly", or [[monopoly]] achieved solely by merit, is legal, but acts by a monopolist to artificially preserve that status, or nefarious dealings to create a monopoly, are not. The purpose of the Sherman Act is not to protect competitors from harm from legitimately successful businesses, nor to prevent businesses from gaining honest profits from consumers, but rather to preserve a competitive marketplace to protect consumers from abuses.<ref name="Cseres2005">"This focus of U.S. competition law, on protection of competition rather than competitors, is not necessarily the only possible focus or purpose of competition law. For example, it has also been said that competition law in the European Union (EU) tends to protect the competitors in the marketplace, even at the expense of market efficiencies and consumers."< {{cite book|title=Competition law and consumer protection|last=Cseres|first=Katalin Judit|year=2005|publisher=Kluwer Law International|isbn=9789041123800|pages=291–293|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=y3IOROCcVacC|access-date=July 15, 2009|url-status=live|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130512183804/http://books.google.com/books?id=y3IOROCcVacC&printsec=frontcover&cad=0|archive-date=May 12, 2013}}</ref>
 
==Background==
Line 148 ⟶ 149:
 
{{blockquote|Section 1:
:Every contract, combination in the form of [[Trust (19th century)|trust]] or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to be illegal.<ref>See {{usc|15|1}}.</ref>
Section 2:
:Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felonymisdemeanor [. . . ]<ref>See {{usc|15|2}}.</ref>}}
 
====Subsequent legislation expanding its scope====
{{unreferenced section|date=July 2022}}
The [[Clayton Antitrust Act]], passed in 1914, proscribes certain additional activities that had been discovered to fall outside the scope of the Sherman Antitrust Act. For example, as ''The Oxford Encyclopedia of American Business, Labor, and Economic History'' states, the Clayton Act added certain practices to the list of impermissible activities:<ref>{{Cite book |last=Mochoruk |first=James |title=The Oxford Encyclopedia of American Business, Labor, and Economic History |publisher=Oxford University Press |year=2013 |isbn=9780199738816 |editor-last=Dubofsky |editor-first=Melvyn |location=New York |chapter=Clayton Antitrust Act}}</ref>
* "price discrimination" between different purchasers, if such discrimination tends to create a monopoly
* "exclusive dealing" agreements
* " 'tying' " arrangements
* mergers and acquisitions that substantially reduce market competition.
 
Line 167 ⟶ 168:
 
Notable cases filed under the act include:<ref>{{cite web|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=UcJAAAAAYAAJ|title=Sherman Anti-trust Law and List of Decisions Relating Thereto|first=United|last=States|date=26 March 2018|publisher=U.S. Government Printing Office|via=Google Books}}</ref>
* ''United States v. Workingmen's Amalgamated Council of New Orleans'' (1893), which was the first to hold that the law applied to labor unions (reversed by the [[Clayton Antitrust Act]]).
* ''Chesapeake & Ohio Fuel Co. v. United States'' (1902), in which the trust was dissolved<ref>{{cite web |url=http://repository.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1069&context=wharton_research_scholars |title=An Early Assessment of the Sherman Antitrust Act: Three Case Studies |access-date=2016-03-08 |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150926031609/http://repository.upenn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1069&context=wharton_research_scholars |archive-date=2015-09-26 }}</ref>
* ''[[Northern Securities Co. v. United States]]'' (1904), which reached the Supreme Court, dissolved the company and set many precedents for interpretation.
Line 173 ⟶ 174:
* ''[[Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United States]]'' (1911), which broke up the company based on geography, and contributed to the [[Panic of 1910–11]].
* ''[[United States v. American Tobacco Co.]]'' (1911), which split the company into four.
* ''[[United States v. General Electric Co]]'' (1911), where GE was judged to have violated the Sherman Anti-Trust Act, along with International General Electric, [[Philips]], [[Sylvania Electric Products|Sylvania]], Tungsol, and Consolidated and Chicago Miniature. Corning and Westinghouse made consent decrees.<ref name="US v GE 1911">{{cite web |title=United States v. General Electric Co., 82 F. Supp. 753 (D.N.J. 1949) |url=https://law.justia.com/cases/federal/district-courts/FSupp/82/753/1755675/ |website=Justia Law |access-date=15 September 2019 |language=en |date=4 April 1949}}</ref>
* ''[https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/USCOURTS-ca2-10-00846/pdf/USCOURTS-ca2-10-00846-0.pdf Fleischman vs Albany Medical Center]'' (2010), where nurses alleged Albany Medical Center suppressed their wages in violation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act, by sharing wage information with other area hospitals. References: (1) Casetext Fleischman vs Albany Medical Center (2) Justia Docket No. 10-0846-mv
* ''[[United States v. Motion Picture Patents Co.]]'' (19171915), which ruled that the company was abusing its monopolicmonopolistic rights, and therefore, violated the Sherman act.
* ''[[Federal Baseball Club v. National League]]'' (1922) in which the Supreme Court ruled that [[Major League Baseball]] was not [[interstate commerce]] and was not subject to the antitrust law.
* ''United States v. National City Lines'' (1953), related to the [[General Motors streetcar conspiracy]].
* ''[[United States v. AT&T (1982)|United States v. AT&T Co.]]'', which was settled in 1982 and resulted in the breakup of the company.
*''[[Wilk v. American Medical Ass'n|Wilk v. American Medical Association]]'' (1990) Judge Getzendanner issued her opinion that the AMA had violated Section 1, but not 2, of the Sherman Act, and that it had engaged in an unlawful conspiracy in [[restraint of trade]] "to contain and eliminate the chiropractic profession."
* ''[[United States v. Microsoft Corp. (2001)|United States v. Microsoft Corp.]]'' was settled in 2001 without the breakup of the company.
Line 202 ⟶ 204:
===Violations "per se" and violations of the "rule of reason"===
Violations of the Sherman Act fall (loosely<ref>The truth is that our categories of analysis of anticompetitive effect are less fixed than terms like 'per se,' 'quick look,' and 'rule of reason' tend to make them appear. We have recognized, for example, that 'there is often no bright line separating per se from rule of reason analysis,' since 'considerable inquiry into market conditions' may be required before the application of any so-called 'per se' condemnation is justified. [[Cal. Dental Association v. FTC]] at 779 (quoting NCAA, 468 U.S. at 104 n.26). "'Whether the ultimate finding is the product of a presumption or actual market analysis, the essential inquiry remains the same whether or not the challenged restraint enhances competition.'" 526 U.S. at 779–80 (quoting NCAA, 468 U.S. at 104).</ref>) into two categories:
* '''Violations "per se":''' theseThese are violations that meet the strict characterization of Section 1 ("agreements, conspiracies or trusts in restraint of trade"). A per se violation requires no further inquiry into the practice's actual effect on the market or the intentions of those individuals who engaged in the practice. Conduct characterized as unlawful per se unlawful is that which has been found to have a "'pernicious effect on competition' or 'lack[s] . . . any redeeming virtue'"<ref>{{ussc|name=Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.|link=|volume=433|page=36|pin=58|year=1977}} (quoting {{ussc|name=Northern Pac. Ry. v. United States|link=|volume=356|page=1|pin=5|year=1958}}).</ref> Such conduct "would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output."<ref>{{ussc|name=Broadcast Music, Inc. v. CBS|link=|volume=441|page=1|pin=19–20|year=1979}}.</ref> When a per se rule is applied (in contrast to a rule of reason analysis), a civil violation of the antitrust laws is found merely by proving that the conduct occurred and that it fell within a per se category.<ref>{{ussc|name=Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde|link=Jefferson Parish Hospital District No. 2 v. Hyde|volume=466|page=2|pin=|year=1984}}; ''[[Gough v. Rossmoor Corp.]]'', [https://law.justia.com/cases/federal/appellate-courts/F2/585/381/424532/ 585 F.2d 381], 386–89 (9th Cir. 1978), cert. denied, {{ussc|440|936|1979|el=no}}; see {{ussc|name=White Motor v. United States|link=|volume=372|page=253|pin=259–60|year=1963}} (a per se rule forecloses analysis of the purpose or market effect of a restraint); ''Northern Pac. Ry.'', 356 U.S. at 5 (same).</ref> (This must be contrasted with rule of reason analysis.) Conduct considered unlawful per se unlawful includes horizontal price-fixing,<ref>{{ussc|name=United States v. Trenton Potteries Co.|link=|volume=273|page=392|pin=397–98|year=1927}}.</ref> horizontal market division,<ref>''Continental T.V.'', 433 U.S. at 50 n. 16 (limiting {{ussc|name=United States v. Topco Assocs.|link=|volume=405|page=596|pin=608|year=1972}} by making vertical market division rule-of-reason analysis).</ref> and concerted refusals to deal.<ref>{{ussc|name=FTC v. Superior Court Trial Lawyers Ass'n|link=|volume=493|page=411|pin=|year=}} for collusive effects and {{ussc|name=NW Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co.|link=|volume=472|page=284|pin=|year=1985}} for exclusionary effects.</ref>
* '''Violations of the "rule of reason":''' A totality of the circumstances test, asking whether the challenged practice promotes or suppresses market competition. Unlike with per se violations, intent and motive are relevant when predicting future consequences. The rule of reason is said to be the "traditional framework of analysis" to determine whether Section 1 is violated.<ref>''Continental T.V.'', 433 U.S. at 49. The inquiry focuses on the restraint's effect on competition. {{ussc|name=National Soc'y of Professional Eng'rs v. United States|link=|volume=435|page=679|pin=691|year=1978}}.</ref> The court analyzes "facts peculiar to the business, the history of the restraining, and the reasons why it was imposed,"<ref>''National Soc'y of Professional Eng'rs'', 435 U.S. at 692.</ref> to determine the effect on competition in the relevant product market.<ref>See ''Continental T.V.'', 433 U.S. at 45 (citing {{ussc|name=United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co.|link=|volume=388|page=365|pin=382|year=1967}}), and geographic market, see {{ussc|name=United States v. Columbia Steel Co.|volume=334|page=495|pin=519|year=1948}}.</ref> A restraint violates Section 1 if it unreasonably restrains trade.<ref>''Continental T.V.'', 433 U.S. at 49; see {{ussc|name=Standard Oil Co. v. United States|link=|volume=221|page=1|pin=58|year=1911}} (Congress only intended to prohibit agreements that were "unreasonably restrictive of competitive (conditions").</ref>
::'''Quick-look:''' A "quick look" analysis under the rule of reason may be used when "an observer with even a rudimentary understanding of economics could conclude that the arrangements in question would have an anticompetitive effect on customers and markets," yet the violation is also not one considered illegalunlawful per se.<ref>''Cal. Dental Ass'n'', 526 U.S. at 770.</ref> Taking a "quick look," economic harm is presumed from the questionable nature of the conduct, and the burden is shifted to the defendant to prove harmlessness or justification. The quick-look became a popular way of disposing of cases where the conduct was in a grey area between illegality "per se" and demonstrable harmfulness under the "rule of reason".
 
===Modern trends===
Line 221 ⟶ 223:
 
===Application of the act outside pure commerce===
TheWhile the Act was aimed at regulating businesses. However, its applicationprohibition wasof notcontracts limitedrestricting commerce was applied to the commercial sideactivities of businesslabor unions until the 1930s.<ref Itsname="Clark prohibition1948">{{cite journal |last1=Clark |first1=O. L. |date=January 1948 |title=Application of the cartelSherman wasAnti-Trust also interpretedAct to makeUnions illegalsince manythe laborApex unionCase activities|journal=SMU Law Review |volume=1 |issue=1 |pages=94–103 |url=https://scholar.smu.edu/smulr/vol2/iss1/6}}</ref> This is because unions were characterized as cartels as well (cartels of laborers).<ref>See {{ussc|name=Loewe v. Lawlor|link=|volume=208|page=274|pin=|year=1908}}.</ref> This persisted untilIn 1914, when the [[Clayton Antitrust Act|Clayton Act]] created exceptions for certain union activities, but the Supreme Court ruled in ''[[Duplex Printing Press Co. v. Deering]]'' that the actions allowed by the Act were already legal. Congress included provisions in the [[Norris–La Guardia Act]] in 1932 to more explicitly exempt organized labor from antitrust enforcement, and the Supreme Court upheld these exemptions in ''United States v. Hutcheson'' [https://supreme.justia.com/cases/federal/us/312/219/ 312 U.S. 219].<ref name="Clark 1948"></ref>
 
==Preemption by Section 1 of state statutes that restrain competition==
Line 230 ⟶ 232:
The antitrust laws allow coincident state regulation of competition.<ref>''See'' Exxon Corp. v. Governor of MD., 437 U.S. 117, 130–34 (1978) (state law with anticompetitive effect upheld to avoid destroying the ability of the states to regulate economic activity); Conant, ''supra'' note 1, at 264., Werden & Balmer, ''supra'' note 1, at 59. ''See generally'' 1 P. Areeda & D. Turner, ''Antitrust Law'' P208 (1978) (discussing the interaction of state and federal antitrust laws); ''id.'' P210 (discussing areas where federal law expressly defers to state law).</ref> The Supreme Court enunciated the test for determining when a state statute is in irreconcilable conflict with Section 1 of the Sherman Act in [[Rice v. Norman Williams Co.]] Different standards apply depending on whether a statute is attacked on its face or for its effects.
*A statute can be condemned on its face only when it mandates, authorizes or places irresistible pressure on private parties to engage in conduct constituting a per se violation of Section 1.<ref>''Rice,'' 458 U.S. at 661. If a statute does not require a per se violation, then it cannot be preempted on its face. ''Id.''</ref>
:If the statute does not mandate conduct violating a per se rule, the conduct is analyzed under the rule of reason, which requires an examination of the conduct's actual effects on competition.<ref>''See ''[''Rice,'' 458 U.S. at 661.]</ref> If unreasonable anticompetitive effects are created, the required conduct violates Section 1<ref>National Soc'y of Professional Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679, 687–90 (1978); Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36, 49 (1977)</ref> and the statute is in irreconcilable conflict with the Sherman Act.<ref>See Battipaglia v. New York State Liquor Auth., 745 F.2d 166, 175 (2d Cir. 1984) (while declining to decide whether a statute required an antitrust violation in a facial attack, the court left open the possibility of preemption based on the statute's operation), cert. denied, 105 S. Ct. 1393 (1985); Lanierland Distribs. v. Strickland, 544 F. Supp. 747, 751 (N.D. Ga. 1982) (plaintiff failed to show anticompetitive effects sufficient to violate the rule of reason); Wine & Spirits Specialty, Inc. v. Daniel, 666 S.W.2d 416, 419 (Mo.) ([[en banc]]) (declining to decide whether the rule of reason might invalidate a law on the record before them), Appeal dismissed, 105 S. Ct. 56 (1984); United States Brewers Ass'n v. Director of N.M. Dept' of Alcoholic Beverage Control, 100 N.M. 216, , 668 P.2d 1093, 1099 (1983) (rejecting a facial attack on a statute but reserving a decision on whether the actual application of the statute might violate the antitrust laws), appeal dismissed, 104 S. Ct. 1581 (1984). But see infra note 149 for a discussion on the possibility of a much more limited rule of reason preemption analysis.</ref> Then statutory arrangement is analyzed to determine whether it qualifies as "state action" and is thereby saved from preemption.<ref>See Rice, 458 U.S. at 662–63 n.9 ("because of our resolution of the pre-emption issue, it is not necessary for us to consider whether the statute may be saved from invalidation under the [state action] doctrine"); Capitol Tel. Co. v New York Tel. Co., 750 F.2d 1154, 1157, 1165 (2d Cir. 1984) (holding that the state action doctrine protected the conduct of a private party after assuming that it violated the federal antitrust laws), cert. denied, 105 S. Ct. 2325 (1985); Allied Artists Picture Corp. v. Rhodes, 679 F.2d 656, 662 (6th Cir. 1982) (even if conduct violated Sherman Act, the statute is saved by the state action doctrine); Miller v. Hedlund, 579 F. Supp. 116, 124 (D. Or. 1984) (statute violating Section 1 saved by state action); Flav-O-Rich, Inc. v. North Carolina Milk Comm'n, 593 F. Supp. 13, 17–18 (E.D.N.C. 1983) (though conduct violates Section 1, state action saves statute).</ref>
 
Rice sets out guidelines to aid in preemption analysis. Preemption should not occur "simply because in a hypothetical situation a private party's compliance with the statute might cause him to violate the antitrust laws."<ref>Rice v. Norman Williams Co., 458 U.S. 654, 659 (1982).</ref> This language suggests that preemption occurs only if economic analysis determines that the statutory requirements create "an unacceptable and unnecessary risk of anticompetitive effect,"<ref>Id. at 668 (Stevens, J., concurring in the judgment).</ref> and does not occur simply because it is possible to use the statute in an anticompetitive manner.<ref>See Grendel's Den, Inc. v. Goodwin, 662 F.2d 88, 100 n.15 (1st Cir.) (power to control others not sufficient for facial preemption where party had no institutional reason to make anticompetitive decisions especially likely), aff'd on other grounds, 662 F.2d 102 (1st Cir. 1981) ([[en banc]]), aff'd sub nom. Larkin v. Grendel's Den, Inc., 459 U.S. 116 (1982); Flav-O-Rich, Inc. v. North Carolina Milk Comm'n, 593 F. Supp. 13, 15 (E.D.N.C. 1983) (in an oligopolistic market, price posting would result in an antitrust violation).</ref> It should not mean that preemption is impossible whenever both procompetitive and anticompetitive results are conceivable.<ref>But cf. Allied Artists Pictures Corp. v. Rhodes, 496 F. Supp. 408, 449 (S.D. Ohio 1980) (indicating that a statute neither requiring nor permitting an anticompetitive collaboration gives the private party enough freedom of choice to preclude preemption), aff'd in part and remanded in part, 679 F.2d 656 (6th Cir. 1982)</ref> The per se rule "reflects the judgment that such cases are not sufficiently common or important to justify the time and expense necessary to identify them."
 
Another important, yet, in the context of Rice, ambiguous guideline regarding preemption by Section 1 is the Court's statement that a "state statute is not preempted by the federal antitrust laws simply because the state scheme might have an anticompetitive effect."<ref>Rice, 458 U.S. at 659.</ref> The meaning of this statement is clarified by examining the three cases cited in Rice to support the statement.<ref>Id. (citing [[New Motor Vehicle Bd. v. Orrin W. Fox Co.]], 439 U.S. 96, 110–11 (1978); [[Exxon Corp. v. Governor of MD.]], 437 U.S. 117, 129–34 (1978); [[Joseph E. Seagram & Sons v. Hostetter]], 384 U.S. 35, 45–46 (1966)).</ref>
Line 270 ⟶ 272:
In 1890, Representative [[William E. Mason (American politician)|William E. Mason]] said "trusts have made products cheaper, have reduced prices; but if the price of oil, for instance, were reduced to one cent a barrel, it would not right the wrong done to people of this country by the trusts which have destroyed legitimate competition and driven honest men from legitimate business enterprise."<ref>Congressional Record, 51st Congress, 1st session, House, June 20, 1890, p. 4100.</ref> Consequently, if the primary goal of the act is to protect consumers, and consumers are protected by lower prices, the act may be harmful if it reduces [[economy of scale]], a price-lowering mechanism, by breaking up big businesses. Mason put small business survival, a justice interest, on a level concomitant with the pure economic rationale of consumer interest.{{citation needed|date=December 2020}}
 
Economist [[Thomas DiLorenzo]] notes that Senator Sherman sponsored the 1890 [[William McKinley]] tariff just three months after the Sherman Act, and agrees with ''[[The New York Times]]'' which wrote on October 1, 1890: "That so-called Anti-Trust law was passed to deceive the people and to clear the way for the enactment of this Pro-Trust law relating to the tariff." The ''Times'' went on to assert that Sherman merely supported this "humbug" of a law "in order that party organs might say...'Behold! We have attacked the trusts. The Republican Party is the enemy of all such rings.'"<ref name=NYT>{{cite news|url=https://timesmachine.nytimes.com/timesmachine/1890/10/01/103268337.pdf |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190524101419/https://timesmachine.nytimes.com/timesmachine/1890/10/01/103268337.pdf |archive-date=2019-05-24 |url-status=live|title=Mr. Sherman's Hopes and Fears|date=1890-10-01|access-date=2008-04-21|newspaper=[[The New York Times]]}}</ref> Dilorenzo writes: "Protectionists did not want prices paid by consumers to fall. But they also understood that to gain political support for high tariffs they would have to assure the public that industries would not combine to increase prices to politically prohibitive levels. Support for both an antitrust law and tariff hikes would maintain high prices while avoiding the more obvious bilking of consumers."<ref>DiLorenzo, Thomas, ''Cato Handbook for Congress'', Antitrust.</ref>
 
[[Robert Bork]] was well known for his outspoken criticism of the antitrust regime. Another conservative legal scholar and judge, [[Richard Posner]] of the [[United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit|Seventh Circuit]], does not condemn the entire regime, but expresses concern with the potential that it could be applied to create inefficiency, rather than to avoid inefficiency.<ref name=posner>Richard Posner, ''Economic Analysis of Law'', p. 295 et seq. (explaining the optimal antitrust regime from an economic point of view)</ref> Posner further believes, along with a number of others, including Bork, that genuinely inefficient cartels and coercive monopolies, the target of the act, would be self-corrected by market forces, making the strict penalties of antitrust legislation unnecessary.<ref name=posner /> Conversely, liberal [[U.S. Supreme Court]] Justice [[William O. Douglas]] criticized the judiciary for interpreting and enforcing the antitrust law unequally: "From the beginning it [the Sherman Act] has been applied by judges hostile to its purposes, friendly to the empire builders who wanted it emasculated... trusts that were dissolved reintegrated in new forms... It is ironic that the Sherman Act was truly effective in only one respect, and that was when it was applied to labor unions. Then the courts read it with a literalness that never appeared in their other decisions."<ref>Douglas, William O., ''An Almanac of Liberty'', Doubleday & Company, 1954, p. 189</ref>
Line 309 ⟶ 311:
==External links==
{{Wikisource|Sherman Act|Sherman Anti-Trust Act}}
* [https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/COMPS-3055/uslm/COMPS-3055.xml Sherman Act] as amended ([https://www.govinfo.gov/content/pkg/COMPS-3055/pdf/COMPS-3055.pdf PDF]/[https://www.govinfo.gov/app/details/COMPS-3055/ details]) in the [[United States Government Publishing Office|GPO]] [https://www.govinfo.gov/help/comps Statute Compilations collection]
 
; Official websites
* [http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/ U.S. Department of Justice: Antitrust Division]
* [https://www.justice.gov/atr/file/761131/download U.S. Department of Justice: Antitrust Division – text of SHERMANthe ANTITRUSTSherman ACTAntitrust Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1–7]
 
;Additional information
* Antitrust Division's [http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/lencorp.htm "Corporate Leniency Policy"]
* [http://www.polyconomics.com/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1605:antitrust-by-alan-greenspan&catid=47:1998&Itemid=31 ''Antitrust''] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20140511002404/http://www.polyconomics.com/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1605:antitrust-by-alan-greenspan&catid=47:1998&Itemid=31 |date=May 11, 2014 }} by [[Alan Greenspan]]
* "Labor and the Sherman Act" (1940). ''[[Yale Law Journal]]'' 49(3) p.&nbsp;518. {{jstorJSTOR|792668}}.
* Dr. Edward W. Younkins (February 19, 2000). [http://www.quebecoislibre.org/000219-13.htm "Antitrust Laws Should Be Abolished"].
 
{{USArticleI}}
{{Benjamin Harrison}}
{{US history}}
{{authority control}}